The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Where are Global and U.S. Trade Heading in the Aftermath of the Trade Collapse: Issues and Alternative Scenarios

Joseph W. Gruber+, Filippo di Mauro++, Bernd Schnatz++, and Nico Zorell++**

NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.


Abstract:

Global and U.S. trade declined dramatically in the wake of the global financial crisis in late 2008 and early 2009. The subsequent recovery in trade, while vigorous at first, gradually lost momentum in 2010. Against this backdrop, this paper explores the prospects for global and U.S. trade in the medium term. We develop a unified empirical framework � an error correction model � that exploits the cointegrating relationship between trade and economic activity. The model allows us to juxtapose several scenarios with different assumptions about the strength of GDP growth going forward and the relationship between trade and economic activity. Our analysis suggests that during the crisis both world trade and U.S. exports declined significantly more than would have been expected on the basis of historical relationships with economic activity. Moreover, this gap between actual and equilibrium trade is closing only slowly and could persist for some time to come.

Keywords: International trade, error correction model, great recession

JEL classification: E66, F17


1.  Introduction

The severity and the synchronization of the collapse in world trade during the global financial crisis surprised most forecasters. All standard reference models for trade, which performed reasonably well in explaining trends in international trade prior to the crisis, clearly missed the magnitude of this downturn. After reaching a trough in the first half of 2009, trade also staged a forceful recovery, surprising again forecasters, though this time on the upside. Going forward, the medium-term trajectory for trade crucially depends on plausible assumptions about the long-term implications of the crisis; particularly to what extent the observed trade collapse is having transitory or permanent repercussions for future trends.

This paper provides a structured discussion on where global and U.S. trade may be heading in the aftermath of the most severe financial crisis in post-war history. Crucially, we use a unified empirical framework for both global and U.S. tradethroughout the paper. Setting the scene, we present a stable long-run relationship between trade and GDP, accounting for globalization trends and - in the model for the U.S. - the real exchange rate. In contrast to other studies, we find that world trade responds proportionally to movements in global GDP once globalization trends have been accounted for. Although our models fail to account for the full impact of the global crisis on trade, they can still be used as a framework for assessing trade prospects. Conditioning on IMF projections for global economic activity, we provide a range of scenarios for world trade and U.S. exports. In the most optimistic (baseline) case we assume that the global crisis constitutes only a transitory shock and trade returns to its pre-crisis trend over the medium term. To some extent, this would be consistent with the strong trade recovery recorded in the second half of 2009 and in early 2010.

However, in light of the deceleration in world trade growth in the second half of 2010, our baseline scenario appears to be too optimistic in the short and medium term. We therefore contrast this profile with several plausible scenarios. Starting with world trade, we first explore the consequences of a lower global GDP profile (Section 4.2), assuming that the global crisis might have longer-term repercussions on the world economy, e.g. in the form of prolonged balance-sheet restructuring. In the second set of scenarios (Section 4.3), we assume that the global financial crisis will have persistent effects on the relationship between trade and GDP, e.g. due to an increase in protectionism or other trade-specific frictions, including those related to impaired credit or higher uncertainty. The resulting profile of world trade is fairly close to that projected by most professional forecasters, including the IMF. We also try to disentangle how financial distress alone could impact world trade.

Clearly, some of the factors shaping the future path of world trade will also affect U.S. trade, and vice versa. Therefore, we also examine how U.S. exports would be affected by a crisis-induced change in the relationship between trade and foreign demand (Section 5.1), analogous to our analysis on global trade. Looking at U.S. exports also allows us assess the recent performance of trade across disaggregated regions and commodities. The results for the U.S. imply that U.S. exports remain (as of the third quarter of 2010) depressed relative to their long-run equilibrium, with weakness most apparent in exports to the advanced economies and in the capital goods and automotive product categories. The results also highlight the importance of any assumption regarding the persistence of the residual weakness of U.S. exports to projecting the path of exports in the short to medium run.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: The next section presents some stylized facts reviewing developments in global and U.S. trade over the past years and their relationship to economic activity. Thereafter, we provide our benchmark econometric specification for global trade and discuss several plausible scenarios. The last section turns to U.S. trade, presenting an export equation for the U.S. and discussing the implications of the scenarios for U.S. exports.


2.  Where We Stand: Stylized Facts on the Great Trade Collapse and the Subsequent Recovery

Historically, declines in global trade have been rather exceptional events.1 All the more striking is the severity of the contraction in global trade during the period 2008-09: From peak to trough, world merchandize trade volumes contracted by 19 percent, thereby returning to their 2005 levels (see Chart 1). Moreover, the decline in international trade was truly global in scope and highly synchronized across countries.2 Having expanded in the overwhelming majority of countries up to September 2008, exports declined precipitously worldwide as the turmoil on the global financial markets intensified. By January 2009 nine in ten countries recorded a contraction in exports.

As regards the geographical dispersion of the trade collapse in 2008-09, the contraction was of comparable magnitude in the advanced and emerging economies on the import side, whereas, on the export side, the advanced economies were more severely hit than the emerging economies (see Table A.1 in the appendix). The subsequent recovery that started in mid-2009 was significantly faster in the emerging economies on both the import and the export side. In September 2010, the latest available observation, the imports of the emerging economies stood 35 percent above the trough levels of early 2009 and 7 percent above the pre-crisis peak. Particularly striking import growth was recorded in placeAsia and placeLatin America. Similarly, the exports of the emerging economies were 27 percent and 6 percent higher in September 2010 than the trough and peak levels, respectively. Thus, the recovery has so far clearly been driven by the emerging economies. Imports and exports of the advanced economies, by contrast, were still well below the respective pre-crisis peak.

The collapse in world trade significantly exceeded the contraction in global GDP, resulting in a decrease in the trade-to-GDP ratio of about 15 percentage points. While it is well known that trade flows are generally more volatile than overall economic activity (and positively correlated with it), the decline in global trade in the fourth quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009 are clear outliers (see Chart 2). Therefore, it is not surprising that standard quantitative trade models considerably underestimated the downturn in world trade in 2008-09. Interestingly, though, the observations from the second quarter of 2009 onwards were again roughly in line with historical relationships.

Chart 1. World GDP, World Merchandize Trade and U.S. Exports of Goods (indicies, 2008Q3=100, log scale)

Data for Chart 1 immediately follows

Sources: BEA and own calculations.
Note: U.S. exports are defined as total U.S. exports less enduse code 213 (computers).

Data for Chart 1

 World GDPWorld tradeU.S. exports
Mar-80  83.64720611
Jun-8080.94402088 83.82828805
Sep-8081.05260977 83.45651591
Dec-8081.26684603 83.3136008
Mar-8181.4726468566.7031216483.44231644
Jun-8181.5607170866.9975236783.37605111
Sep-8181.7000047467.1588355182.85238339
Dec-8181.7258464167.3148325583.06177398
Mar-8281.7580559167.4238316782.11780056
Jun-8281.8649162267.3967543882.19822664
Sep-8281.8942181567.5160144681.36272792
Dec-8281.9826909967.451086180.37747273
Mar-8382.1443461867.6393619580.42981837
Jun-8382.3682147168.0293415880.36617351
Sep-8382.5826964968.4040423880.44761274
Dec-8382.8290242568.8163921180.89888587
Mar-8483.0746983969.4141128780.71364945
Jun-8483.2539652769.673148280.90724749
Sep-8483.4454575569.9817169881.19687834
Dec-8483.5922489770.1535595881.57705148
Mar-8583.7771524270.2816519681.30851675
Jun-8583.9722383570.5070379681.22285932
Sep-8584.191120370.7255680781.0112981
Dec-8584.357128370.9738168181.38432576
Mar-8684.470521671.1113863981.34932713
Jun-8684.6365963871.5671923681.42172143
Sep-8684.7895206371.9007262881.53853843
Dec-8684.908070272.0452983482.06065618
Mar-8784.997581572.247096681.77984074
Jun-8785.243270772.6229882882.27129549
Sep-8785.4429846273.0846412483.02622072
Dec-8785.7068271273.4943864983.65618859
Mar-8885.8710233773.5495219884.52620545
Jun-8886.0356223873.8699548884.89804316
Sep-8886.2324007174.3380550985.01441606
Dec-8886.4504539574.7516870485.61409667
Mar-8986.6896662475.1026026985.94001194
Jun-8986.8394571975.4957048686.66017026
Sep-8987.026079375.5982370286.57650999
Dec-8987.2184371776.0421116686.65232896
Mar-9087.4102414576.4773987187.17639411
Jun-9087.5469682476.6765120187.27072881
Sep-9087.7082542476.9384952387.26472446
Dec-9087.749361277.3171934487.31291997
Mar-9187.798926877.5045393487.58981624
Jun-9187.970610477.8443094587.84888735
Sep-9188.0845440578.2218573688.20077478
Dec-9188.2228481978.3742707288.37601395
Mar-9288.4212815778.7630839788.65146195
Jun-9288.4977949378.9124031288.49801813
Sep-9288.5989449379.0215529288.8541406
Dec-9288.674267779.2334930188.95602596
Mar-9388.753912579.2009318388.81667783
Jun-9388.8535590279.4020200688.87210574
Sep-9388.9580630879.6874603588.6661212
Dec-9389.1047540779.9815011889.28380899
Mar-9489.2759542180.3949761389.14257648
Jun-9489.4251473280.9329815789.58454457
Sep-9489.5947309781.3658867290.26723686
Dec-9489.7695141581.9511898790.45925622
Mar-9589.9118553782.3138060790.63745556
Jun-9590.0309070382.7735521590.72861304
Sep-9590.2039533183.0557932891.100145
Dec-9590.3536897583.3667414191.11420266
Mar-9690.5395128983.7561449691.29319121
Jun-9690.7805844483.9974450291.37479677
Sep-9690.9609289684.4043234891.5958482
Dec-9691.1779039684.9340366892.20745622
Mar-9791.3703895585.4194565792.53274492
Jun-9791.6017212286.0261306393.1201605
Sep-9791.7879796186.5030228493.49657144
Dec-9791.9719592386.7988899193.56437678
Mar-9892.0176982987.0405967393.61280174
Jun-9892.1117421187.1508882593.24461125
Sep-9892.2450075987.160655293.18539657
Dec-9892.4075069787.2207611293.66713945
Mar-9992.589910187.4914380593.56589403
Jun-9992.7787621188.000671493.64688835
Sep-9992.9950660188.5157058593.98793737
Dec-9993.2862127589.1049527894.43295423
Mar-0093.5668123189.8551911394.64428998
Jun-0093.806158490.3727830994.95283348
Sep-0093.9514312890.930875895.36325584
Dec-0094.0921783191.2860326895.18620243
Mar-0194.1721704791.076044395.0635347
Jun-0194.2689858490.7933827594.74831337
Sep-0194.3175677890.5357216694.05653819
Dec-0194.4053903490.3774531593.68263513
Mar-0294.5796933290.7117790393.60735609
Jun-0294.7759838391.2843449594.06691716
Sep-0294.9442518191.5990877694.15237531
Dec-0295.0625677791.8306125593.82370157
Mar-0395.2038372992.049533693.85054035
Jun-0395.3631070492.0678309793.80733823
Sep-0395.6553850392.4638028194.01443828
Dec-0395.9396789893.1689336794.56114452
Mar-0496.1740141393.6953928794.82575321
Jun-0496.3990601894.2743074895.15641057
Sep-0496.5942777994.6795320895.36940964
Dec-0496.7914866995.1401195495.62435655
Mar-0597.0151198895.2250129895.87814749
Jun-0597.2551433495.7999523596.31687607
Sep-0597.4890274596.1645124396.22091987
Dec-0597.7236172596.6505293696.61361053
Mar-0698.0002479997.2074417497.22591664
Jun-0698.2447021997.5954694497.4921089
Sep-0698.464223897.7829100697.58218214
Dec-0698.7255786698.1808821798.04032372
Mar-0798.9990283698.585491998.18875399
Jun-0799.2644211698.8740523698.45736404
Sep-0799.4822953299.2584957798.93551606
Dec-0799.739108199.5338679899.2465911
Mar-0899.92327399.9541733299.59795208
Jun-08100.0121865100.030237100.0676267
Sep-08100100100
Dec-0899.7268856898.741175998.93024592
Mar-0999.4612041196.8593055497.4217102
Jun-0999.6191251996.8441261197.28967525
Sep-0999.8256826197.5596002597.90486289
Dec-09100.082628798.0980169198.8299134
Mar-10100.364494998.7021209199.26415459
Jun-10100.601717999.2332055499.57734811
Sep-10100.838940899.7642901699.83356193
Dec-10   
Mar-11   
Jun-11   
Sep-11   
Dec-11   
Mar-12   
Jun-12   
Sep-12   
Dec-12   
Mar-13   
Jun-13   
Sep-13   
Dec-13   
Mar-14   
Jun-14   
Sep-14   
Dec-14   
Mar-15   
Jun-15   
Sep-15   
Dec-15   

Chart 2. World GDP, World Merchandize Trade and U.S. Exports of Goods (quarterly percentage changes)

Data for Chart 2 immediately follows

Source: Own calculations.

Data for Chart 2

 World GDP GrowthWorld trade GrowthWorld GDPWorld trade
Mar-80    
Jun-80    
Sep-800.534233129   
Dec-801.056733673   
Mar-811.014914952   
Jun-810.4330677111.507374991  
Sep-810.6857810690.823142898  
Dec-810.1268772680.795914834  
Mar-820.1581667770.555461613  
Jun-820.5257066-0.137509956  
Sep-820.1438786680.607910272  
Dec-820.435051716-0.329416841  
Mar-830.7963447990.961394432  
Jun-831.1045068812.001613402  
Sep-831.0579510881.922444262  
Dec-831.2159858392.117637848  
Mar-841.2127397153.084172693  
Jun-840.8834855531.325098962  
Sep-840.9440198181.580480758  
Dec-840.7228589890.877114287  
Mar-850.9113905830.653078282  
Jun-850.9618207521.151977913  
Sep-851.0797720811.116741654  
Dec-850.8178750421.26957124  
Mar-860.5579355670.70156685  
Jun-860.8182053852.343404736  
Sep-860.7531729121.709438519  
Dec-860.5833801460.737408908  
Mar-870.4401694131.030798701  
Jun-871.2128145161.92861273  
Sep-870.9847498752.373819485  
Dec-871.303007442.104122708  
Mar-880.8089130230.28058696  
Jun-880.8109052271.641744665  
Sep-880.9702049962.407367115  
Dec-881.0756620922.124292236  
Mar-891.1806540691.799320714  
Jun-890.7376841942.017800826  
Sep-890.9199007450.522419904  
Dec-890.9483071752.281368642  
Mar-900.9455651552.236741265  
Jun-900.6731303311.017014246  
Sep-900.7945188581.340279561  
Dec-900.2019023821.943151374  
Mar-910.2434986070.956623166  
Jun-910.8459550411.741677183  
Sep-910.5606017731.937192208  
Dec-910.680922270.777559637  
Mar-920.9784049681.9955675  
Jun-920.3761323650.761714065  
Sep-920.4975445980.556231613  
Dec-920.3702687081.082883361  
Mar-930.391556333-0.165336439  
Jun-930.4901310141.027153268  
Sep-930.5140851571.461156179  
Dec-930.722362631.505511727  
Mar-940.8435628272.123477433  
Jun-940.7347291792.77181899  
Sep-940.8355646362.224366687  
Dec-940.8612935063.019141613  
Mar-950.7008678231.85986986  
Jun-950.5858581432.363899332  
Sep-950.8526980671.444662099  
Dec-950.7374147631.592764316  
Mar-960.9159444621.998627256  
Jun-961.1898850191.233816612  
Sep-960.8888200442.089248472  
Dec-961.0703146942.728519572  
Mar-970.9489398042.497542918  
Jun-971.1415374283.131086584  
Sep-970.9180996862.453133205  
Dec-970.9068164151.5149327  
Mar-980.2246791011.235909241  
Jun-980.4625094130.562066161  
Sep-980.6560339320.049647201  
Dec-980.8005199880.305920324  
Mar-990.8990112851.385062293  
Jun-990.9309434232.621658514  
Sep-991.0669866412.65191662  
Dec-991.438817333.039790757  
Mar-001.386334613.886263812  
Jun-001.1813183812.665259188  
Sep-000.7153543872.876784001  
Dec-000.6929911161.821264478  
Mar-010.393267405-1.061469963  
Jun-010.476172354-1.42619491  
Sep-010.238660504-1.300877031  
Dec-010.431847184-0.801081696  
Mar-020.8589170891.713532098  
Jun-020.9677882522.952479386  
Sep-020.8290553131.612357593  
Dec-020.5822272481.183539027  
Mar-030.6955726151.118750568  
Jun-030.7845476020.093029007  
Sep-031.4444480582.032679559  
Dec-031.4047148143.648395436  
Mar-041.1564438342.711533239  
Jun-041.1103486212.98570082  
Sep-040.9624730622.080668481  
Dec-040.9723382122.368276323  
Mar-051.1033394060.432353428  
Jun-051.1846813242.964897937  
Sep-051.1542051511.869932752  
Dec-051.1577077942.500652864  
Mar-061.3665928342.870613245  
Jun-061.2066814951.991495811  
Sep-061.0829446790.957109127  
Dec-061.2906430662.043051989  
Mar-071.3507724582.07747874  
Jun-071.3107137031.477245603  
Sep-071.074773941.972919688  
Dec-071.268071411.409256688  
Mar-080.9077338482.158932134  
Jun-080.4372233750.387297461  
Sep-08-0.059777462-0.153543961  
Dec-08-1.331146049-6.196911926  
Mar-09-1.295154839-9.120443289  
Jun-090.777878448-0.077110866  
Sep-091.0186651253.702891217  
Dec-091.2687337792.77396674  
Mar-101.3926361663.117617641  
Jun-10    
Sep-10    
Dec-10    
Mar-11    
Jun-11    
Sep-11    
Dec-11    
Mar-12    
Jun-12    
Sep-12    
Dec-12    
Mar-13    
Jun-13    
Sep-13    
Dec-13    
Mar-14    
Jun-14    
Sep-14    
Dec-14    
Mar-15    
Jun-15    
Sep-15    
Dec-15    

The United States was not an outlier in regard to the worldwide collapse in trade flows that occurred over 2008-09 (see Chart 1). The declines in U.S. exports and imports were neither exceptionally large nor exceptionally small relative to global trends. Real exports of goods and services fell 15 percent from mid-2008 to mid-2009, while real imports contracted 18 percent over the same time period. The declines in both exports and imports were widespread across both categories of goods and trading partners.

As with global volumes more generally, U.S. trade has rebounded sharply since mid-2009. By the third quarter of 2010, real exports and imports had returned to within a hair of their second quarter 2008 levels. The rebound in imports has coincided with relatively weak U.S. GDP growth and the U.S. import-to-GDP ratio has roughly returned to its pre-crisis trend. In contrast to the modest pace of U.S. GDP growth, foreign growth weighted by share of U.S. exports has been fairly robust and the level of foreign GDP has surpassed its pre-crisis peak. Thus, for exports, the comparison to the previous peak understates the degree to which exports remain below their pre-crisis trend.


3.  Forecasting World Trade: An Error Correction Model

Against the backdrop of the recent developments in global and U.S. trade we now move on to develop a model that allows us to assess the medium-term outlook for global trade. Historical patterns over the past 30 years suggest that global trade and global economic activity follow a common upward trend but trade has increased faster than GDP (see Chart 1). While activity rose at an average rate of just above 3 percent over this period, global trade grew at an average rate of about 6 percent per year. This reflects the globalization process in the wake of technological advances and falling transportation costs, the rising importance of vertical specialization (Hummels et al. 2001, Kleinert and Zorell 2010) and, since the early 1990s, the rapid integration of formerly Communist countries - such as China, Russia and the Central and Eastern European countries - into the global economy (see Bussière and Schnatz 2009).

At the same time, global trade was also more cyclical than global GDP as evidenced by the standard deviation of global trade growth, which has been almost four times higher than that of global GDP growth. This partly reflects the fact that business cycles are commonly associated with large swings in private investment, durable goods consumption and inventories, which are relatively trade-intensive.3

Against this background, we estimate a dynamic standard global trade equation which relates world trade (m) to global economic activity (y) and accounts for globalization trends (t). This trend is included to proxy for several factors, which are difficult to measure in a transparent and more direct way. These comprise, for instance, the decline in trade costs recorded in recent decades as global logistics became more efficient and trade barriers were progressively removed. Moreover, the outsourcing of production processes through global supply chains also led to an increase in international trade.

In order to verify that there is a long-term relationship between global economic activity and global trade, we first conduct a standard Johansen (1995) cointegration test, which confirms the presence of one cointegration vector. In the second step, we run an error-correction model of the following form:

$\displaystyle \Delta m_{t} =ect(m_{t-1} -\beta y_{t-1} -\delta t)+\gamma_{1} \Delta y_{t} +\gamma_{2} \Delta m_{t-1} +\varepsilon_{t} $

Two coefficients are particularly noteworthy: First, $ \beta$determines the long-term relationship between (the log of) trade (m) and (the log of) economic activity (y) at time t. If this coefficient would be (well) above one, as occasionally suggested in the literature,4 this would imply that trade would grow without bound as a proportion of GDP, which appears unreasonable, at least as a very long-term representation. Secondly, ect is the error-correction coefficient, or "speed of adjustment", which determines how fast trade reverts to its long-term equilibrium path after a disturbance. As regards the short-term dynamics, we include contemporaneous growth in global economic activity ($ \Delta$yt) and lagged world trade growth ($ \Delta$mt-1).5 $ \varepsilon$t represents the white noise residuals. We estimate this relationship over the period 1981Q1-2008Q3, excluding the actual crisis period to avoid that these observations (outliers) may steer the results.6

Table 1: Estimation Results From the Global Error Correction Model

Dependent Variable: Quarterly Growth in World Trade(1) Benchmark(2) Stock-Watson(3) Short Sample(4) Industrial Production
Sample1981Q1-2008Q31981Q1-2008Q31995Q1-2008Q31985Q1-2008Q3
MethodologyEngle-GrangerStock-WatsonEngle-GrangerEngle-Granger
Activity VariableGDPGDPGDPIP
Long-Term Relationship (a): Global Activity0.9780.967***0.9811.013
Long-Term Relationship (a): Globalization Trend0.0080.008***0.0070.008
Speed of Adjustment-0.085***-0.081***-0.154***-0.133***
Short-Term Dynamics: Global activity growth1.229***1.506***1.060***0.887***
Short-Term Dynamics: Global trade growth (lagged)0.354***0.375***0.442***0.474***
Test for Autocorrelation: LM(1); p-value0.580.150.750.40
Test for Autocorrelation: LM(2); p-value0.230.270.460.26
Test for Heteroscedasticity: ARCH(1); p-value0.630.430.940.93
Test for Heteroscedasticity: ARCH(4); p-value0.720.700.860.49
Quandt-Andrews Breakpoint TestNo breakNo breakNo breakNo break
Adj. R20.540.540.610.52

(a) Significance of the long-term coefficients can only be reported for the Stock-Watson approach.

Statistical tests confirm that there is a stable long-term relationship between global economic activity and global trade in this equation. Both the ADF and KPSS-tests confirm that the residuals of the long-run relationship in Table 1 are stationary. Moreover, after accounting for globalization trends, our specification (based on the Engle-Granger methodology) suggests that, in the long run, a one percent increase in economic activity raises world trade by about the same amount (see Table 1). The stronger trade growth over this period is captured by the significant linear trend, which suggests that there is an (autonomous) increase in global trade of about 0.8 percent per quarter, which can be attributed to the ongoing globalization process. Moreover, the error-correction coefficient suggests that shocks to global trade are rather persistent and mean reversion is rather slow. Columns (2) - (4) show that our main results are robust to the econometric method, the sample period chosen and the use of the activity variable (GDP or industrial production). In fact, while the short-run coefficient of the GDP-based models is above one, reflecting the higher volatility of trade as compared with GDP, the short-run coefficient in the specification including industrial production is less than one as industrial production is more cyclical than GDP. Lagrange-Multiplier tests reject the presence of autocorrelated residuals and tests for ARCH-effects cannot reject the absence of heteroscedasticity. Finally, we performed Quandt-Andrews breakpoint tests for one or more unknown structural breakpoints in the sample for a specified equation (trimming 15 percent of the data). Again, we cannot find evidence in favor of structural breaks.

The overall fit of the relationship is also good, explaining around 50-60 percent of the variation in global trade. Chart 3 suggests that - based on the results reported in the first column of Table 1 - actual global trade growth follows quite closely the growth rates projected by the model within the sample period. However, in periods of large swings in global trade the model does not fully account for the peaks and troughs in growth. For instance, in the early 2000s, vigorous global trade growth is only partly captured by the model and the decline in trade in the context of the burst of the dotcom bubbles is also only partly projected. The standard error of the regression indicates, however, that the margin of uncertainty is non-trivial.

Chart 3. One-Step-Ahead In-Sample Forecast of World Trade (Quarter-On-Quarter Percentage Change)

Data for Chart 3 immediately follows

Note: The reference period is 1981-2008. The shaded area shows the two-standard error band.

Data for Chart 3

 Actual importsProjected importsSE Band TopSE Band Bottom
1980Q1    
1980Q2    
1980Q3    
1980Q4    
1981Q1    
1981Q20.01496127   
1981Q30.0081977360.008773626  
1981Q40.0079276418.78E-05100.014132199.98604343
1982Q10.0055392460.000484969100.014514699.98645532
1982Q2-0.0013760460.004478007100.018522499.99043364
1982Q30.0060607-0.001419294100.012482799.98467871
1982Q4-0.0032996060.005059428100.018940999.99117801
1983Q10.0095680240.00747434100.021574399.99337439
1983Q20.0198184450.01629778100.0302615100.002334
1983Q30.0190419880.019263704100.0331349100.0053925
1983Q40.0209552750.020843343100.0347525100.0069342
1984Q10.0303756790.021382123100.0352864100.0074778
1984Q20.0131639630.019811715100.0338297100.0057937
1984Q30.0156812120.014749912100.0286451100.0008547
1984Q40.00873290.013070151100.026915599.99922477
1985Q10.006509550.013442229100.027344399.99954018
1985Q20.0114539320.014144255100.0280795100.0002091
1985Q30.0111055210.017825173100.0317377100.0039127
1985Q40.0126157980.015137422100.0289872100.0012876
1986Q10.0069911730.012780275100.026616199.99894444
1986Q20.0231636860.014510778100.02842100.0006015
1986Q30.016949920.01882666100.0327543100.004899
1986Q40.0073470330.014417623100.0282792100.000556
1987Q10.0102552220.009804655100.023636899.99597251
1987Q20.0191025070.020420205100.0344352100.0064052
1987Q30.0234608250.020832927100.0347392100.0069266
1987Q40.0208229170.025741274100.0396751100.0118074
1988Q10.002801940.018783961100.0326777100.0048902
1988Q20.0162841370.013538661100.027529399.99954804
1988Q30.0237884690.020212268100.034144100.0062805
1988Q40.0210204370.023609817100.0375507100.0096689
1989Q10.0178332450.023687809100.037611100.0097647
1989Q20.019977130.017305712100.0311972100.0034143
1989Q30.00521060.019877087100.0337618100.0059924
1989Q40.0225573460.015991603100.0299965100.0019867
1990Q10.0221209310.021640305100.0355751100.0077055
1990Q20.0101187750.017746633100.0316856100.0038076
1990Q30.0133137730.015355991100.0292386100.0014734
1990Q40.0192451320.009442712100.023383199.99550228
1991Q10.0095207650.011263707100.025261999.99726556
1991Q20.0172668380.015257742100.0291336100.0013819
1991Q30.0191866750.014425957100.0283016100.0005503
1991Q40.0077455220.016088112100.0299534100.0022229
1992Q10.019759170.016247771100.0301849100.0023107
1992Q20.0075882770.01295394100.026909699.99899824
1992Q30.0055469040.010477982100.024308699.9966474
1992Q40.0107706220.008814663100.022670399.99495907
1993Q1-0.0016547330.010991885100.02487499.9971098
1993Q20.0102191390.008941237100.022948999.99493361
1993Q30.0145058420.01364817100.027635699.99966069
1993Q40.0149429140.017579446100.0315745100.0035843
1994Q10.0210124580.01921757100.0332187100.0052164
1994Q20.0273409950.019629052100.0336519100.0056062
1994Q30.0219998850.022063688100.0360944100.0080329
1994Q40.0297446260.019989744100.0339100.0060795
1995Q10.0184278580.019640251100.0336888100.0055917
1995Q20.0233639190.013926748100.027778100.0000755
1995Q30.0143432630.018109192100.031992100.0042264
1995Q40.0158021290.013676792100.027498199.9998555
1996Q10.0197891690.016314031100.0301599100.0024682
1996Q20.0122626710.020809916100.0347087100.0069111
1996Q30.020677230.01510208100.0289503100.0012539
1996Q40.026919590.019943953100.0338138100.0060741
1997Q10.0246686410.019952882100.0338838100.0060219
1997Q20.0308306780.020867729100.0348024100.0069331
1997Q30.0242352710.019334509100.0334088100.0052602
1997Q40.0150357220.016244591100.0302775100.0022117
1998Q10.0122833420.004805012100.018791599.9908185
1998Q20.0056049250.006565088100.020526199.99260407
1998Q30.0004963490.00715008100.021126499.99317372
1998Q40.0030545330.008279531100.022319699.99423944
1999Q10.013755580.011460222100.025444899.99747561
1999Q20.0258788210.015884997100.0297386100.0020314
1999Q30.0261736290.021079562100.0349917100.0071675
1999Q40.0299450460.025034546100.0390225100.0110466
2000Q10.0381264980.025055277100.0390819100.0110286
2000Q20.0263035990.024049278100.0383055100.0097931
2000Q30.0283618140.013616278100.027792999.99943966
2000Q40.0180487810.012935976100.027292699.99857935
2001Q1-0.0106714370.005344124100.0196499.99104824
2001Q2-0.014364628-0.001897027100.012471499.98373455
2001Q3-0.013094125-0.003828398100.010287299.98205603
2001Q4-0.0080430760.000966719100.015082299.98685122
2002Q10.0169901670.009679155100.023933199.99542525
2002Q20.0290973310.019803283100.0336981100.0059084
2002Q30.0159949720.021405229100.0354112100.0073992
2002Q40.01176590.013763684100.027604999.99992251
2003Q10.0111253880.013811322100.027638999.99998378
2003Q20.0009298580.014976869100.0288277100.001126
2003Q30.0201229640.02063307100.0350587100.0062075
2003Q40.0358341720.027098339100.0411313100.0130654
2004Q10.0267542250.028439533100.0425462100.0143328
2004Q20.0294199660.024030217100.0379539100.0101066
2004Q30.0205931820.022273453100.0362338100.0083131
2004Q40.0234066770.018996329100.032853100.0051396
2005Q10.0043142150.021079352100.0349658100.0071929
2005Q20.0292179470.016532357100.0306284100.0024363
2005Q30.0185266440.024146947100.0380807100.0102132
2005Q40.0246989820.020464667100.0343505100.0065789
2006Q10.028301830.024719637100.03865100.0107893
2006Q20.0197192490.023456727100.0373988100.0095147
2006Q30.0095255790.01891641100.0328107100.0050221
2006Q40.0202246170.018593189100.032653100.0045334
2007Q10.0205619340.023130799100.0370683100.0091933
2007Q20.0146644060.022809183100.0367313100.008887
2007Q30.0195370990.018369386100.0322509100.0044879
2007Q40.013994190.022346544100.0362554100.0084377
2008Q10.0213595730.016538893100.0303831100.0026947
2008Q20.0038654940.013015705100.026945699.99908578
2008Q3-0.001536620.001441123100.015247999.98763438
2008Q4-0.063972409-0.01544681699.99893199.97017537
2009Q1-0.095635109-0.03210216499.9833324999.95246318
2009Q2-0.000771406-0.010071711100.011853899.96800279
2009Q30.0363598090.027793187100.0446598100.0109266
2009Q40.0273618930.04240061100.0590512100.0257501
2010Q10.030700070.040123303100.0563507100.0238959
2010Q20.0269892850.037833441100.0539249100.021742
2010Q30.0269892850.035875008100.0516924100.0200576
2010Q40.0269892850.035229006100.0508589100.0195991
2011Q10.0169146620.032977777100.0484579100.0174977
2011Q20.0169146620.029512933100.044877100.0141488
2011Q30.0169146620.029611286100.0450019100.0142207
2011Q40.0169146620.029709639100.045127100.0142923
2012Q10.0169146620.030752741100.046197100.0153084
2012Q20.0169146620.030914696100.0464035100.0154259
2012Q30.0169146620.031076651100.0466104100.0155429
2012Q40.0169146620.031238606100.0468179100.0156593
 0.0169146620.03153277100.0471583100.0159072
 0.0169146620.031703625100.0473783100.016029
 0.0169146620.031874481100.0475988100.0161502
 0.0169146620.032045336100.0478199100.0162708
 0.0169146620.032327791100.0481532100.0165024
 0.0169146620.032506159100.0483851100.0166272
 0.0169146620.032684528100.0486176100.0167514
 0.0169146620.032862896100.0488508100.016875
 0.0169146620.033041265100.0490845100.0169981
 0.0169146620.033219633100.0493188100.0171205
 0.0169146620.033398002100.0495536100.0172424
 0.0169146620.03357637100.049789100.0173637

Chart 4. One-Step-Ahead Forecast of World Trade and Actual Outcomes in the Midst of the Crisis (Quarter-on-Quarter Percentage Change)

Data for Chart 4 immediately follows

Note: Based on the Engle-Granger model estimated up to 2008Q3, including actual GDP realizations in the projections.

Data for Chart 4

DATEActual TradeModel Forecast
1980-01#N/A#N/A
1980-04#N/A#N/A
1980-07#N/A#N/A
1980-10#N/A#N/A
1981-01#N/A#N/A
1981-041.50%1.50%
1981-070.82%0.82%
1981-100.79%0.79%
1982-010.55%0.55%
1982-04-0.14%-0.14%
1982-070.61%0.61%
1982-10-0.33%-0.33%
1983-010.96%0.96%
1983-041.98%1.98%
1983-071.90%1.90%
1983-102.10%2.10%
1984-013.04%3.04%
1984-041.32%1.32%
1984-071.57%1.57%
1984-100.87%0.87%
1985-010.65%0.65%
1985-041.15%1.15%
1985-071.11%1.11%
1985-101.26%1.26%
1986-010.70%0.70%
1986-042.32%2.32%
1986-071.69%1.69%
1986-100.73%0.73%
1987-011.03%1.03%
1987-041.91%1.91%
1987-072.35%2.35%
1987-102.08%2.08%
1988-010.28%0.28%
1988-041.63%1.63%
1988-072.38%2.38%
1988-102.10%2.10%
1989-011.78%1.78%
1989-042.00%2.00%
1989-070.52%0.52%
1989-102.26%2.26%
1990-012.21%2.21%
1990-041.01%1.01%
1990-071.33%1.33%
1990-101.92%1.92%
1991-010.95%0.95%
1991-041.73%1.73%
1991-071.92%1.92%
1991-100.77%0.77%
1992-011.98%1.98%
1992-040.76%0.76%
1992-070.55%0.55%
1992-101.08%1.08%
1993-01-0.17%-0.17%
1993-041.02%1.02%
1993-071.45%1.45%
1993-101.49%1.49%
1994-012.10%2.10%
1994-042.73%2.73%
1994-072.20%2.20%
1994-102.97%2.97%
1995-011.84%1.84%
1995-042.34%2.34%
1995-071.43%1.43%
1995-101.58%1.58%
1996-011.98%1.98%
1996-041.23%1.23%
1996-072.07%2.07%
1996-102.69%2.69%
1997-012.47%2.47%
1997-043.08%3.08%
1997-072.42%2.42%
1997-101.50%1.50%
1998-011.23%1.23%
1998-040.56%0.56%
1998-070.05%0.05%
1998-100.31%0.31%
1999-011.38%1.38%
1999-042.59%2.59%
1999-072.62%2.62%
1999-102.99%2.99%
2000-013.81%3.81%
2000-042.63%2.63%
2000-072.84%2.84%
2000-101.80%1.80%
2001-01-1.07%-1.07%
2001-04-1.44%-1.44%
2001-07-1.31%-1.31%
2001-10-0.80%-0.80%
2002-011.70%1.70%
2002-042.91%2.91%
2002-071.60%1.60%
2002-101.18%1.18%
2003-011.11%1.11%
2003-040.09%0.09%
2003-072.01%2.01%
2003-103.58%3.58%
2004-012.68%2.68%
2004-042.94%2.94%
2004-072.06%2.06%
2004-102.34%2.34%
2005-010.43%0.43%
2005-042.92%2.92%
2005-071.85%1.85%
2005-102.47%2.47%
2006-012.83%2.83%
2006-041.97%1.97%
2006-070.95%0.95%
2006-102.02%2.02%
2007-012.06%2.06%
2007-041.47%1.47%
2007-071.95%1.95%
2007-101.40%1.40%
2008Q12.14%1.65%
2008Q20.39%1.30%
2008Q3-0.15%0.14%
2008Q4-6.40%-1.54%
2009Q1-9.56%-3.21%
2009Q2-0.08%-1.01%
2009Q33.64%2.78%
2009Q42.74%4.24%
2010Q13.07%4.01%

Given the strength of the collapse in global trade in 2008-09 compared with the contraction in GDP, it is hardly surprising that the model did not foresee the magnitude of the downturn in trade. Even if we assume that we had perfect foresight of developments in global GDP, the model would have predicted less than half of the actual contraction in global trade in the last quarter of 2008 and in the first quarter of 2009 (see Chart 4), a failure shared with most standard trade models.


4.  World Trade at a Crossroads: A Scenario Analysis

The Great Trade Collapse of 2008-09 was not only hard to anticipate on the basis of standard trade models but also poses major challenges for forecasters in the assessment of world trade going forward. In particular, it is an open question whether the crisis will have transitory or persistent impacts on world trade. Given that only a short period of time has gone by since the end of the downturn in global trade, it is arguably too early to reliably detect possible structural breaks in the data associated with the global financial crisis. Therefore, we take a different approach and use our model of world trade (see Section 3) as a starting point for a comprehensive scenario analysis. More specifically, we analyze in greater detail how the shape of the recovery will look like under alternative assumptions on (i) the future profile of world GDP, (ii) the relationship between global trade and GDP as well as (iii) the impact of renewed financial distress.7 Before discussing each of these channels in turn, we briefly describe our baseline scenario.

4.1  A "Mechanistic" Baseline Scenario

In our "mechanistic" baseline scenario, we assume that the coefficients in our benchmark error-correction model in Table 1 remain unchanged and feed the model with a plausible global GDP profile. In more detail, we assume - for the sake of comparability - that world GDP growth will evolve in line with the latest IMF projections (World Economic Outlook, October 2010). Following the 0.6 percent contraction in world GDP in 2009, the IMF expects global economic activity to grow by 4.8 percent in 2010, 4.2 percent in 2011 and 4.5 percent in 2012 in annual terms. Since we are mostly interested in the overall shape of the trade recovery in the medium term, we assume that the quarterly profile of world GDP for any given year is flat: 1.2 percent quarter-on-quarter throughout 2010, 1.0 percent in 2011 and 1.1 percent in 2012. Notably, these quarterly growth rates are considerably above the average rate of 0.8 percent in our reference sample, which implies that the excess capacity in the global economy is gradually (and partially) absorbed over this period (see Table A.2 in the appendix).

Chart 5. Contributions to the One-Step-Ahead Out-of-Sample Projections of the Global Trade Model (Quarter-on-Quarter Growth)

Data for Chart 5 immediately follows

Note: The last observation is 2010Q1.

Data for Chart 5

  obsTradeContribution of Short-Run DynamicsContribution of Error CorrectionContribution of Residuals
198011980Q1    
198021980Q2    
198031980Q3    
198041980Q4    
198111981Q1    
198121981Q20.01496127 -0.004682442 
198131981Q30.0081977360.013689798-0.004916172-0.000575891
198141981Q40.0079276410.004457491-0.0043697380.007839889
198211982Q10.0055392460.00474591-0.0042609410.005054277
198221982Q2-0.0013760460.00840222-0.003924213-0.005854053
198231982Q30.00606070.001280067-0.0026993610.007479993
198241982Q4-0.0032996060.007477983-0.002418555-0.008359034
198311983Q10.0095680240.008579926-0.0011055860.002093685
198321983Q20.0198184450.016882081-0.00058430.003520664
198331983Q30.0190419880.019941484-0.000677779-0.000221717
198341983Q40.0209552750.021587007-0.0007436640.000111932
198411984Q10.0303756790.022224288-0.0008421660.008993557
198421984Q20.0131639630.021552104-0.001740388-0.006647752
198431984Q30.0156812120.016201782-0.001451870.0009313
198441984Q40.00873290.014396864-0.001326714-0.004337251
198511985Q10.006509550.014237331-0.000795101-0.00693268
198521985Q20.0114539320.0140649247.93E-05-0.002690323
198531985Q30.0111055210.0172484250.000576747-0.006719652
198541985Q40.0126157980.0139371880.001200234-0.002521625
198611986Q10.0069911730.0112989610.001481314-0.005789102
198621986Q20.0231636860.012486050.0020247280.008652908
198631986Q30.016949920.0174130450.001413614-0.001876739
198641986Q40.0073470330.0131427510.001274873-0.00707059
198711987Q10.0102552220.0079955480.0018091070.000450567
198721987Q20.0191025070.0184407970.001979408-0.001317698
198731987Q30.0234608250.018797850.0020350770.002627898
198741987Q40.0208229170.0242059060.001535368-0.004918357
198811988Q10.002801940.0172648020.001519159-0.01598202
198821988Q20.0162841370.0109154190.0026232420.002745477
198831988Q30.0237884690.0176240460.0025882210.003576201
198841988Q40.0210204370.0215609440.002048874-0.002589381
198911989Q10.0178332450.0218577210.001830089-0.005854564
198921989Q20.019977130.0153388520.0019668610.002671417
198931989Q30.00521060.0183178210.001559266-0.014666487
198941989Q40.0225573460.0134410240.002550580.006565742
199011990Q10.0221209310.0195428490.0020974550.000480626
199021990Q20.0101187750.0160676240.001679009-0.007627858
199031990Q30.0133137730.0133034840.002052508-0.002042219
199041990Q40.0192451320.0071873480.0022553640.00980242
199111991Q10.0095207650.0097951630.001468544-0.001742942
199121991Q20.0172668380.0137188980.0015388440.002009096
199131991Q30.0191866750.0129765240.0014494330.004760718
199141991Q40.0077455220.0151249410.000963171-0.008342589
199211992Q10.019759170.0147038960.0015438750.003511399
199221992Q20.0075882770.0116017720.001352167-0.005365663
199231992Q30.0055469040.0087826220.00169536-0.004931078
199241992Q40.0107706220.0065033860.0023112780.001955958
199311993Q1-0.0016547330.0086115080.002380378-0.012646618
199321993Q20.0102191390.0054228980.0035183390.001277902
199331993Q30.0145058420.0099153380.0037328330.000857671
199341993Q40.0149429140.0139751030.003604343-0.002636532
199411994Q10.0210124580.0156074560.0036101140.001794888
199421994Q20.0273409950.016427230.0032018220.007711943
199431994Q30.0219998850.0198949490.002168739-6.38E-05
199441994Q40.0297446260.0183194060.0016703380.009754882
199511995Q10.0184278580.0191024950.000537755-0.001212393
199521995Q20.0233639190.0136957420.0002310060.009437171
199531995Q30.0143432630.018697113-0.000587921-0.003765929
199541995Q40.0158021290.014101227-0.0004244350.002125337
199611996Q10.0197891690.016793031-0.0004790010.003475138
199621996Q20.0122626710.021534349-0.000724433-0.008547245
199631996Q30.020677230.015210863-0.0001087840.00557515
199641996Q40.026919590.020395547-0.0004515940.006975637
199711997Q10.0246686410.021126769-0.0011738870.004715759
199721997Q20.0308306780.022672861-0.0018051310.009962949
199731997Q30.0242352710.022134578-0.0028000690.004900762
199741997Q40.0150357220.019664514-0.003419923-0.001208869
199811998Q10.0122833420.008075658-0.0032706460.00747833
199821998Q20.0056049250.01001471-0.003449622-0.000960163
199831998Q30.0004963490.010017538-0.002867458-0.006653731
199841998Q40.0030545330.00997338-0.001693849-0.005224997
199911999Q10.013755580.012078248-0.0006180260.002295357
199921999Q20.0258788210.016251831-0.0003668340.009993824
199931999Q30.0261736290.022194784-0.0011152220.005094067
199941999Q40.0299450460.02681167-0.0017771230.004910499
200012000Q10.0381264980.027509608-0.0024543310.013071221
200022000Q20.0263035990.027915867-0.0038665890.002254321
200032000Q30.0283618140.018062235-0.0044459570.014745536
200042000Q40.0180487810.018517301-0.0055813250.005112805
200112001Q1-0.0106714370.011206594-0.00586247-0.016015561
200122001Q2-0.0143646280.002063163-0.00396019-0.012467601
200132001Q3-0.013094125-0.00215126-0.001677138-0.009265727
200142001Q4-0.0080430760.0006640880.000302631-0.009009795
200212002Q10.0169901670.0076648460.0020143090.007311012
200222002Q20.0290973310.0178443430.001958940.009294048
200232002Q30.0159949720.0204368030.000968426-0.005410257
200242002Q40.01176590.0127909190.000972765-0.001997784
200312003Q10.0111253880.0126791540.001132168-0.002685934
200322003Q20.0009298580.0135379340.001438936-0.014047012
200332003Q30.0201229640.017951650.00268142-0.000510106
200342003Q40.0358341720.0242584820.0028398570.008735833
200412004Q10.0267542250.0268029840.00163655-0.001685308
200422004Q20.0294199660.0230315020.0009987150.005389749
200432004Q30.0205931820.0221758299.76E-05-0.001680271
200442004Q40.0234066770.019174032-0.0001777030.004410348
200512005Q10.0043142150.021762352-0.000682999-0.016765138
200522005Q20.0292179470.0159979670.000534390.012685591
200532005Q30.0185266440.024435759-0.000288812-0.005620302
200542005Q40.0246989820.020697004-0.0002323370.004234315
200612006Q10.028301830.02541488-0.0006952430.003582193
200622006Q20.0197192490.024749066-0.001292339-0.003737478
200632006Q30.0095255790.020210275-0.001293865-0.009390831
200642006Q40.0202246170.019127291-0.0005341020.001631428
2007 2007Q10.0205619340.023640585-0.000509786-0.002568865
  2007Q20.0146644060.0232741-0.000464917-0.008144777
  2007Q30.0195370990.0183231444.62E-050.001167712
  2007Q40.013994190.022394307-4.78E-05-0.008352354
2008 2008Q10.0213595730.0160536160.0004852770.00482068
  2008Q20.0038654940.0129154650.000100241-0.009150211
  2008Q3-0.001536620.0006323690.000808754-0.002977743
  2008Q4-0.063972409-0.0170107850.001563968-0.048525592
200912009Q1-0.095635109-0.0386449470.006542783-0.063532945
  2009Q2-0.000771406-0.0243024810.014230770.009300304
  2009Q30.0363598090.0121814620.0156117250.008566623
  2009Q40.0273618930.0283522080.014048402-0.015038717
2010 2010Q10.030700070.0266723710.013450932-0.009423234
  2010Q20.0378334410.0251612710.0126721716.04E-16
  2010Q30.0387928420.0276842050.011108637-5.76E-16
  2010Q40.0374874540.0280235260.0094639295.07E-16
2011 2011Q10.0338862770.0259566080.007929669-1.25E-16
  2011Q20.0312749840.0246829420.006592042-1.32E-16
  2011Q30.0292347370.0237593790.005475359-2.78E-17
  2011Q40.0275690850.0230377830.004531302-1.84E-16
2012 2012Q10.02712160.0233934230.003728177-2.67E-16
  2012Q20.0262616720.0232351570.0030265158.47E-16
  2012Q30.025328630.0229310170.002397613-2.22E-16
  2012Q40.0244486750.0226010180.001847656-3.85E-16
201312013Q10.0237941580.0224220050.001372153-1.46E-16
201322013Q20.0231514450.0221905150.000960939.16E-16
201332013Q30.0225672870.02196320.000604087-2.78E-16
201342013Q40.0220532640.0217565950.000296669-2.78E-16
201412014Q10.0217191380.0216863943.27E-055.41E-16
201422014Q20.0213728230.021568221-0.000195397-3.92E-16
201432014Q30.0210514980.021445736-0.000394237-4.06E-16
201442014Q40.02076620.021332089-0.0005658896.59E-16
201512015Q10.0205177830.021231185-0.000713402-4.09E-16
201522015Q20.0203034280.021143325-0.0008398965.86E-16
201532015Q30.0201192580.021067512-0.000948254-4.41E-16
201542015Q40.0199613460.021002374-0.001041028-5.27E-16

Taking our assumptions on the future path of world GDP as given, our benchmark model suggests a strong recovery of world trade over the entire forecast horizon (see Table 2). In terms of annual growth rates, world trade would expand 12.6 percent in 2010, 13.6 percent in 2011 and 10.9 percent in 2012. To a notable extent, these strong growth rates are driven by the equilibrium correction mechanism in the model. The benchmark model interprets the huge deviation of world trade growth from its equilibrium level in late 2008 and early 2009 as an event that will be corrected by above-average growth in world trade - also compared to GDP - going forward. Since the estimated speed of adjustment to disturbances is relatively low, the adjustment process takes several years (see Chart 5).

We should emphasize that the world trade growth rates implied by this mechanistic baseline scenario are well above those in the IMF October 2010 World Economic Outlook, particularly beyond 2010In line with the IMF, we also acknowledge the possibility that the recovery in world trade could be more sluggish going forward, either due to a crisis-induced change in the relationship between trade and GDP or lower-than-anticipated GDP growth. In fact, the main contribution of this paper is a structured discussion and quantification of these considerations within a unified model framework. More specifically, we will present several alternative scenarios with different assumptions about the medium term profile of world GDP and the relationship between trade and GDP and lay out the consequences for the future path of world trade.

Table 2. Baseline Scenario (Annual Percentage Changes)

  Full Sample 2009 2010 2011 2012
World GDP 3.4% -0.8% 4.8% 4.3% 4.3%
World Trade 6.3% -11.9% 12.6% 13.6% 10.9%
Memo: IMF - -11.0% 11.4%    

Note: The last observation is 2010Q1. The IMF forecast refers to the WEO October 2010.

4.2  How Anemic Global GDP Growth Could Derail the Recovery in Trade

As already indicated, the baseline scenario rests on our assumption for the future path of world GDP. Given the unprecedented nature of the recent financial crisis, the shape of the ongoing recovery in the world economy is subject to considerable uncertainty. There is a possibility that future GDP growth at the global level will be significantly lower than currently anticipated. Such a scenario could materialize, for instance, if the adverse repercussions of the ongoing balance sheet restructuring in some of the advanced economies turn out be larger than anticipated, while the emerging economies are not able to take up the slack. Moreover, the precarious fiscal situation and the lingering sovereign debt crises in some developed countries could derail the fragile global economic recovery there. In fact, Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) provide evidence that recoveries from financial crises tend to be more sluggish than "normal" recoveries. Similarly, looking at past recessions associated with financial crises in advanced economies, IMF (2009) finds that, on average, output reached its pre-crisis peak after about 5 1/2 quarters, compared with around three quarters for "normal" recoveries.8 This profile is also consistent with the present recovery in advanced economies, which remains rather subdued. Making use of cross-industry variation in external financial dependence, Dell'Ariccia et al. (2008) show that banking crises have indeed independent negative effects on real economic activity, rather than merely occurring during economic downturns.

To explore how world trade would respond to a lower GDP growth profile, we consider three alternative scenarios in which quarterly world GDP growth is, respectively, 0.3, 0.5 and 0.8p.p. lower than in the baseline scenario over the entire forecast horizon. As Table 3 shows, the corresponding annual growth rates in world trade are indeed well below the baseline scenario. However, even under the extreme assumption of anemic global GDP growth of less than 1/2 percent over the next two years (i.e. the third scenario), our simple model predicts that annual world trade growth is significantly above its long-term average of 6.3 percent throughout 2010 and 2011 and close to this average rate in 2012. Again, this reflects the strong impact of the error-correction mechanism implemented in the model. In the following, we explore this issue in greater detail.

Table 3. World Trade Growth Under Alternative Assumptions on World GDP Growth (Annual Percentage Growth)

 
2010
2011
2012
baseline
12.6%
13.6%
10.9%
Δy 0.3p.p. lower
12.0%
11.7%
9.2%
Δy 0.5p.p. lower
11.6%
10.4%
8.1%
Δy 0.8p.p. lower
10.9%
8.4%
6.4%
Memo: IMF
11.4%
7.0%
-

Note: The last observation is 2010Q1. The IMF forecast refers to the WEO October 2010.

4.3  Impacts of changes in the relationship between world trade and world GDP

So far, we have implicitly assumed that, in the absence of renewed disturbances, world trade will gradually return to levels consistent with its long-run equilibrium relationship with global GDP. In other words, we assumed that the crisis had only transitory effects that are unwinding over the horizon. Moreover, we have taken for granted that the post-crisis equilibrium relationship will be the same as that observed before the crisis. In the following, we relax these assumptions and analyze the consequences for the future path of world trade.

The recovery in global trade observed in the second half of 2009 and the first half of 2010 indeed suggests that a significant part of the trade downturn in the crisis was transitory and has been unwinding.9 In particular, the inventory dynamics magnified both the downturn and the subsequent upturn in global trade (see Alessandria et al. 2010). This is also in line with the argument that the global financial crisis led to a drop in demand for intermediate inputs, which explains the sharp fall in global trade (see Bems et al. 2010). In mid-2010, however, inventories have been approaching levels in line with historical averages, which implies that the restocking is likely to have a less pronounced effect in the period ahead. The same argument holds for the possible disruption of global supply chains.10 Moreover, the strength of the trade recovery in this period was also supported by factors that were themselves transitory. Most notably, fiscal stimulus measures such as the car scrapping schemes provided strong support to global trade.11 Given the need to retrain public finances, however, support from these measures is also receding.

Chart 6. Impacts of Changes in the Relationship Between Global Trade and GDP

Data for Chart 6 immediately follows

Note: The last observation is 2010Q1. Projectionsup to 2012Q4.

Data for Chart 6

DATEWorld TradeBaselineDownward ShiftNew Normal
1980-01#N/A#N/A#N/A#N/A
1980-04#N/A#N/A#N/A#N/A
1980-07#N/A#N/A#N/A#N/A
1980-10#N/A#N/A#N/A#N/A
1981-0166.703123.389803.389803.38980
1981-0466.997523.404763.404763.40476
1981-0767.158843.412963.412963.41296
1981-1067.314833.420883.420883.42088
1982-0167.423833.426423.426423.42642
1982-0467.396753.425053.425053.42505
1982-0767.516013.431113.431113.43111
1982-1067.451093.427813.427813.42781
1983-0167.639363.437383.437383.43738
1983-0468.029343.457203.457203.45720
1983-0768.404043.476243.476243.47624
1983-1068.816393.497193.497193.49719
1984-0169.414113.527573.527573.52757
1984-0469.673153.540733.540733.54073
1984-0769.981723.556413.556413.55641
1984-1070.153563.565153.565153.56515
1985-0170.281653.571663.571663.57166
1985-0470.507043.583113.583113.58311
1985-0770.725573.594223.594223.59422
1985-1070.973823.606833.606833.60683
1986-0171.111393.613823.613823.61382
1986-0471.567193.636993.636993.63699
1986-0771.900733.653943.653943.65394
1986-1072.045303.661283.661283.66128
1987-0172.247103.671543.671543.67154
1987-0472.622993.690643.690643.69064
1987-0773.084643.714103.714103.71410
1987-1073.494393.734923.734923.73492
1988-0173.549523.737733.737733.73773
1988-0473.869953.754013.754013.75401
1988-0774.338063.777803.777803.77780
1988-1074.751693.798823.798823.79882
1989-0175.102603.816653.816653.81665
1989-0475.495703.836633.836633.83663
1989-0775.598243.841843.841843.84184
1989-1076.042113.864403.864403.86440
1990-0176.477403.886523.886523.88652
1990-0476.676513.896643.896643.89664
1990-0776.938503.909953.909953.90995
1990-1077.317193.929203.929203.92920
1991-0177.504543.938723.938723.93872
1991-0477.844313.955983.955983.95598
1991-0778.221863.975173.975173.97517
1991-1078.374273.982923.982923.98292
1992-0178.763084.002684.002684.00268
1992-0478.912404.010264.010264.01026
1992-0779.021554.015814.015814.01581
1992-1079.233494.026584.026584.02658
1993-0179.200934.024934.024934.02493
1993-0479.402024.035154.035154.03515
1993-0779.687464.049654.049654.04965
1993-1079.981504.064594.064594.06459
1994-0180.394984.085614.085614.08561
1994-0480.932984.112954.112954.11295
1994-0781.365894.134954.134954.13495
1994-1081.951194.164694.164694.16469
1995-0182.313814.183124.183124.18312
1995-0482.773554.206484.206484.20648
1995-0783.055794.220834.220834.22083
1995-1083.366744.236634.236634.23663
1996-0183.756144.256424.256424.25642
1996-0483.997454.268684.268684.26868
1996-0784.404324.289364.289364.28936
1996-1084.934044.316284.316284.31628
1997-0185.419464.340954.340954.34095
1997-0486.026134.371784.371784.37178
1997-0786.503024.396014.396014.39601
1997-1086.798894.411054.411054.41105
1998-0187.040604.423334.423334.42333
1998-0487.150894.428944.428944.42894
1998-0787.160664.429434.429434.42943
1998-1087.220764.432494.432494.43249
1999-0187.491444.446244.446244.44624
1999-0488.000674.472124.472124.47212
1999-0788.515714.498304.498304.49830
1999-1089.104954.528244.528244.52824
2000-0189.855194.566374.566374.56637
2000-0490.372784.592674.592674.59267
2000-0790.930884.621034.621034.62103
2000-1091.286034.639084.639084.63908
2001-0191.076044.628414.628414.62841
2001-0490.793384.614054.614054.61405
2001-0790.535724.600954.600954.60095
2001-1090.377454.592914.592914.59291
2002-0190.711784.609904.609904.60990
2002-0491.284344.639004.639004.63900
2002-0791.599094.654994.654994.65499
2002-1091.830614.666764.666764.66676
2003-0192.049534.677884.677884.67788
2003-0492.067834.678814.678814.67881
2003-0792.463804.698934.698934.69893
2003-1093.168934.734774.734774.73477
2004-0193.695394.761524.761524.76152
2004-0494.274314.790944.790944.79094
2004-0794.679534.811544.811544.81154
2004-1095.140124.834944.834944.83494
2005-0195.225014.839264.839264.83926
2005-0495.799954.868484.868484.86848
2005-0796.164514.887004.887004.88700
2005-1096.650534.911704.911704.91170
2006-0197.207444.940004.940004.94000
2006-0497.595474.959724.959724.95972
2006-0797.782914.969254.969254.96925
2006-1098.180884.989474.989474.98947
2007-0198.585495.010035.010035.01003
2007-0498.874055.024705.024705.02470
2007-0799.258505.044245.044245.04424
2007-1099.533875.058235.058235.05823
2008-0199.954175.079595.079595.07959
2008-04100.030245.083455.083455.08345
2008-07100.000005.081925.081925.08192
2008-1098.741185.017955.017955.01795
2009-0196.859314.922314.922314.92231
2009-0496.844134.921544.921544.92154
2009-0797.559604.957904.957904.95790
2009-1098.098024.985264.985264.98526
2010-0198.702125.015965.015965.01596
2010-04#N/A5.053795.041135.03827
2010-07#N/A5.092595.063855.05643
2010-10#N/A5.130075.085415.07303
2011-01#N/A5.163965.104785.08784
2011-04#N/A5.195245.123265.10212
2011-07#N/A5.224475.141395.11636
2011-10#N/A5.252045.159405.13075
2012-01#N/A5.279165.178315.14608
2012-04#N/A5.305425.197535.16186
2012-07#N/A5.330755.216835.17787
2012-10#N/A5.355205.236125.19401
2013-01#N/A5.378995.255505.21036
2013-04#N/A5.402155.274875.22681
2013-07#N/A5.424715.294205.24332
2013-10#N/A5.446775.313495.25987
2014-01#N/A5.468495.332845.27654
2014-04#N/A5.489865.352185.29326
2014-07#N/A5.510915.371505.31002
2014-10#N/A5.531685.390785.32678
2015-01#N/A5.552195.410035.34356
2015-04#N/A5.572505.429245.36034
2015-07#N/A5.592625.448435.37713
2015-10#N/A5.612585.467605.39392

Other factors argue in favor of a more permanent adverse impact of the worst financial crisis in post-war history on global trade, consistent with empirical evidence showing that imports recover only sluggishly in countries that underwent a financial crisis, even when conditioning on output (e.g. IMF 2010). Firstly, Kannan (2010) presents evidence showing that stressed credit conditions partly explain the fact that recoveries from financial crises tend to be sluggish. In light of the ongoing sovereign debt crises and the feeble state of the banking sector in many advanced economies, global financial conditions are unlikely to fully return to the levels recorded prior to the crisis in the near term.12 International trade would be particularly exposed to such deterioration in financial conditions, as it is generally more sensitive to financial distress than domestic transactions (Amiti and Weinstein 2009). To some extent, this can be explained by the higher working capital requirements and risk associated with cross-border trade.13 Therefore, the financial crisis made the downturn particularly trade-intensive. This might have been amplified by a drying-up of trade finance in the midst of the crisis (Auboin 2009, Chauffour and Farole 2009, Dorsey 2009).

Second, policymakers might increasingly succumb to protectionism and thereby lower the trade intensity of world GDP. While protectionism has so far been contained, protectionist pressures have surfaced amid a sluggish recovery in many advanced economies, persisting global imbalances and the growing risk of "currency wars" (Evenett 2010, Kee et al. 2010). Evidence on the Great Depression suggests that governments are particularly prone to protectionism if they cannot resort to alternative expansionary policies, such as fiscal or monetary policy (Eichengreen and Irwin 2009).

Third, a shift in demand from tradable to non-tradable goods could also be reinforced by the crisis-induced increase in government expenditure relative to GDP across the globe, as the latter is typically characterized by more pronounced home bias than private absorption.

In terms of the error correction model described in Section 3, there are several ways to capture persistent changes in the relationship between trade and GDP. In our "downward shift" scenario, we assume that there will be no further error correction in world trade going forward. Loosely speaking, we force the model not to interpret the remaining deviation from the long-run relationship of world trade and world GDP over the projection horizon as a transitory event that is to be further corrected in the subsequent quarters. As a consequence, there is a permanent one-off downward shift in the level of trade. Technically speaking, we set the residuals from the first-step Engle-Granger equation to zero from 2010Q2 onwards. Under this scenario, the projected profile for world trade growth for 2011 would be much lower, but still above the path projected by the IMF (see Chart 6 and Table 4).

An alternative way to model a more inward-oriented growth profile is to assume that the elasticity of trade to GDP would be lower than before the crisis, at least for some time. We add these alternative elasticities to the downward shift in the level of trade implemented before and call this scenario "new normal". In more detail, we assume that both the short-run elasticity $ \gamma_{1} $ and the long-run elasticity ($ \beta$) shrink by a factor of 0.8. In this case, the positive impact of an increase in world GDP on world trade is lower than in the baseline scenario. Taking the GDP profile as given, the trajectory of world trade is now significantly flatter than in the "downward shift" or the baseline scenario, and very close to the IMF projection.14

Table 4. World Trade Growth Under Alternative Scenarios (Annual Percentage Growth)

 
2010
2011
2012
baseline
12.6%
13.6%
10.9%
"downward shift"
11.7%
9.3%
8.2%
"new normal"
11.2%
7.7%
6.6%
Memo: IMF
11.4%
7.0%
-

Note: The IMF forecast refers to the WEO October 2010. See main text for details on the various scenarios.

At first sight, it appears that the "new normal" scenario is at odds with the data. After all, world trade expanded rapidly in the second half of 2009 and the first half of 2010, casting doubt on the notion of lower trade elasticities. However, structural changes in the global economy might so far have been concealed by the countervailing impact of temporary factors, such as the inventory cycle and the extensive fiscal stimuli across the globe. These factors may have temporarily stimulated world trade (also by propping up world GDP), but their impacts are already waning. Indeed, world trade growth slowed down considerably in the second half of 2010. It seems fair to conclude that the jury is still out on this, as more sophisticated econometric analysis has to wait until a sufficient number of post-crisis observations become available.

Clearly, imposing a lower elasticity of trade to GDP (Section 4.3) is observationally equivalent to assuming a lower GDP profile compared to the baseline (Section 4.2) as far as the future path of world trade is concerned. Nevertheless, these scenarios differ with respect to the underlying rationale. More specifically, the "new normal" scenario assumes that trade will be hit more than overall economic activity, due to trade-specific frictions such as an increase in protectionism. By contrast, the "lower GDP growth" scenarios are concerned with the possibility of prolonged economic weakness in overall economic activity, which translates "one-to-one" into a lower trade profile.

In summary, there is a possibility that the fallout of the financial crisis will affect the relationship between international trade and economic activity, at least in the near term. Our scenario analysis illustrates that this would dramatically alter the future path of world trade. Crucially, such a scenario has to be imposed by the modeler, as the equilibrating forces are inherent to our error correction model. In the following section, we develop an alternative to this approach by augmenting the model with a financial distress variable. As a result, the model will be able to generate a rather sluggish recovery in world trade without turning off the error correction mechanism.

4.4  How Financial Distress Affects World Trade

As already indicated the near-term growth in world trade might be hindered by the fact that financial conditions have not yet returned to pre-crisis levels. In this section we try to account for stressed credit conditions more explicitly. We explore the role of financial conditions in determining the future path of world trade by augmenting the short-term dynamics of the error correction model with a widely-used measure of financial distress: the Chicago Board Options Exchange Market Volatility Index (VIX). The VIX measures the implied volatility of S&P 500 index options and is available from 1990 onwards. Spikes in the VIX tend to coincide with periods of financial distress (see Chart 7).

Chart 7. Financial Distress Indicators (VIX, Global Crisis Index, Ted Spread)

Data for Chart 7 immediately follows

Sources: Bloomberg, Laeven and Valencia (2010) and IMF.
Note: The global "crisis index" is a GDP-weighted index of financial crises in individual countries. The crisis episodes are taken from Laeven and Valencia (2010) and the GDP weights from teh IMF-WEO database.

Data for Chart 7

 Crisis indexTed spread (rhs)VIX
1980Q14.256  
1980Q24.256  
1980Q34.256  
1980Q44.256  
1981Q17.135  
1981Q27.135  
1981Q37.135  
1981Q47.135  
1982Q16.807  
1982Q26.807  
1982Q36.807  
1982Q46.807  
1983Q16.551  
1983Q26.551  
1983Q36.551  
1983Q46.551  
1984Q15.43  
1984Q25.43  
1984Q35.43  
1984Q45.43  
1985Q14.0940.674 
1985Q24.0940.872 
1985Q34.0940.911 
1985Q44.0940.757 
1986Q10.6830.865 
1986Q20.6830.721 
1986Q30.6830.806 
1986Q40.6830.568 
1987Q10.5110.7645 
1987Q20.5111.3185 
1987Q30.5111.464 
1987Q40.5111.5885 
1988Q125.5451.0835 
1988Q225.5451.1805 
1988Q325.5451.103 
1988Q425.5451.262 
1989Q11.2851.1285 
1989Q21.2851.0785 
1989Q31.2851.0165 
1989Q41.2850.596 
1990Q15.6290.45622.17
1990Q25.6290.38318.72
1990Q35.6290.962525.2
1990Q45.6290.99526.11
1991Q17.8120.44222.52
1991Q27.8120.494517.15
1991Q37.8120.37116.63
1991Q47.8120.354517.46
1992Q16.8940.168517.49
1992Q26.8940.289515.63
1992Q36.8940.38413.88
1992Q46.8940.296514.74
1993Q19.5680.29313.26
1993Q29.5680.232512.97
1993Q39.5680.39812.11
1993Q49.5680.31612.42
1994Q112.6270.384513.43
1994Q212.6270.6614.52
1994Q312.6270.72712.56
1994Q412.6270.81315.25
1995Q18.9720.3812.05
1995Q28.9720.490612.22
1995Q38.9720.542112.49
1995Q48.9720.54812.9
1996Q16.9740.332715.48
1996Q26.9740.42516.37
1996Q36.9740.59316.78
1996Q46.9740.391517.22
1997Q118.1330.451419.94
1997Q218.1330.614319.92
1997Q318.1330.669522.45
1997Q418.1330.465527.11
1998Q127.230.590921.32
1998Q227.230.609521.53
1998Q327.230.951529.76
1998Q427.230.613629.53
1999Q112.3320.52527.25
1999Q212.3320.588524.4
1999Q312.3321.232823.31
1999Q412.3320.673322.63
2000Q112.4090.41923.13
2000Q212.4090.914424.89
2000Q312.4090.601319.17
2000Q412.4090.503826
2001Q111.30.592825.75
2001Q211.30.180323.99
2001Q311.30.21925.37
2001Q411.30.156327.93
2002Q11.0030.25321.35
2002Q21.0030.180421.64
2002Q31.0030.243335.07
2002Q41.0030.190230.7
2003Q10.8430.170730.02
2003Q20.8430.270721.53
2003Q30.8430.222419.32
2003Q40.8430.234817.43
2004Q10.1510.172516.66
2004Q20.1510.348816.23
2004Q30.1510.319715.44
2004Q40.1510.352613.65
2005Q10.0570.353612.79
2005Q20.0570.400113.41
2005Q30.0570.527412.25
2005Q40.0570.462212.78
2006Q100.397712.04
2006Q200.50514.53
2006Q300.498113.61
2006Q400.353911.03
2007Q124.540.322412.56
2007Q224.540.55813.73
2007Q324.541.433121.59
2007Q424.541.465722.07
2008Q142.0681.372626.12
2008Q242.0681.052520.67
2008Q342.0683.148125.07
2008Q442.0681.348958.6
2009Q140.8750.99145
2009Q240.8750.417533.03
2009Q340.8750.179425.53
2009Q440.8750.20323.11
2010Q1 0.141420.15
2010Q2 0.363526.31
2010Q3   
2010Q4   
2011Q1   
2011Q2   
2011Q3   
2011Q4   
2012Q1   
2012Q2   
2012Q3   
2012Q4   
2013Q1   
2013Q2   
2013Q3   
2013Q4   
2014Q1   
2014Q2   
2014Q3   
2014Q4   
2015Q1   
2015Q2   
2015Q3   
2015Q4   

Interestingly, the VIX turns out to be insignificant when included in levels or first differences (results not reported here). Hence, in general, the impact of financial conditions on world trade appears to be well-captured by the other variables of the model, particularly world GDP. However, the results change notably when we differentiate between "normal times" and periods of severe financial distress. Technically speaking, we construct a dummy variable that is equal to one if the VIX deviates significantly (i.e. one-and-a-half standard deviations) from its longer-term mean, and zero otherwise. This financial distress dummy turns out to be statistically significant and has a negative sign, as expected (see Table 5, third column). The estimated coefficient is relatively small, with quarterly world trade growth being around 1p.p. lower in periods of financial distress as compared to "normal" times, ceteris paribus. This is equivalent to about one standard deviation of world trade growth. However, one should bear in mind that the dummy captures the effects of financial distress on world trade over and above those already captured by the other variables, particularly world GDP and the history of world trade itself. In other words, our results indicate that severe financial distress has a significant effect on world trade growth, over and above its indirect impact through GDP. Moreover, episodes of severe financial distress may last more than one quarter, in which case the estimated impact has to be cumulated.

Table 5: The Impact of Financial Distress - Estimation Results From the Global Error Correction Model

Dependent Variable: Quarterly Growth in World Trade(1)
Benchmark: 1981Q1-2008Q3
(2)
Short Sample: 1990Q1-2008Q3
(3)
VIX: 1990Q1-2008Q3
(4)
Ted Spread: 1985Q1-2008Q3
(5)
Crisis Index: 1980Q1-2008Q3
Long-Term Relationship: Global Activity0.9780.9780.9810.9810.981
Long-Term Relationship: Globalization Trend0.0080.0080.0070.0070.007
Speed of Adjustment-0.085***-0.097***-0.100***-0.101***-0.083***
Short-Term Dynamics: Global Activity Growth1.229***1.179***1.281***1.257***1.279***
Short-Term Dynamics: Global Trade Growth (Lagged)0.354***0.416***0.384***0.377***0.351***
Financial Distress---0.006*-0.003*-0.003*
adj. R20.540.560.590.530.55

To illustrate the impacts of renewed financial distress on the future path of world trade, we consider a scenario in which financial conditions remain strained over the entire forecast horizon. More specifically, we feed the estimated model (see Table 5, column 3) with a financial distress dummy that is equal to unity from 2010Q2 onwards. Unfortunately, our simple model does not allow us to capture interactions between financial distress and GDP growth, since both variables are treated as exogenous. Therefore, we make the additional (and admittedly ad-hoc) assumption that financial distress will be associated with a 0.8 p.p. reduction in GDP growth over the horizon compared to the baseline (as in Section 4.2). The corresponding path of world trade is well below the baseline (see Chart 8). At the end of the forecast horizon, trade is 12 percent lower than it would have been in the baseline scenario with benign financial conditions. Even if we assume that GDP growth remains unchanged with respect to the baseline, annual world trade growth would be around one percentage point lower than in the baseline in both 2011 and 2012.

Obviously, it is not straightforward to capture the "global financial conditions" with a single variable. To check for the robustness of our results, we have therefore considered alternative measures of financial conditions, including the Ted spread and a GDP-weighted index of financial crises. The key finding remains that these financial variables are insignificant when included in non-binary form, but turn out to be significant as a dummy variable (see Table 5, columns 4 and 5).

Chart 8. The Impacts of Financial Distress (Log Scale)

Data for Chart 8 immediately follows

Note: The last observation is 2010Q1. Projections up to 2012Q4. For details see main text.

Data for Chart 8

DATEWorld TradeBaselineFinancial Distress
1980-01#N/A#N/A#N/A
1980-04#N/A#N/A#N/A
1980-07#N/A#N/A#N/A
1980-10#N/A#N/A#N/A
1981-0166.703123.389803.38980
1981-0466.997523.404763.40476
1981-0767.158843.412963.41296
1981-1067.314833.420883.42088
1982-0167.423833.426423.42642
1982-0467.396753.425053.42505
1982-0767.516013.431113.43111
1982-1067.451093.427813.42781
1983-0167.639363.437383.43738
1983-0468.029343.457203.45720
1983-0768.404043.476243.47624
1983-1068.816393.497193.49719
1984-0169.414113.527573.52757
1984-0469.673153.540733.54073
1984-0769.981723.556413.55641
1984-1070.153563.565153.56515
1985-0170.281653.571663.57166
1985-0470.507043.583113.58311
1985-0770.725573.594223.59422
1985-1070.973823.606833.60683
1986-0171.111393.613823.61382
1986-0471.567193.636993.63699
1986-0771.900733.653943.65394
1986-1072.045303.661283.66128
1987-0172.247103.671543.67154
1987-0472.622993.690643.69064
1987-0773.084643.714103.71410
1987-1073.494393.734923.73492
1988-0173.549523.737733.73773
1988-0473.869953.754013.75401
1988-0774.338063.777803.77780
1988-1074.751693.798823.79882
1989-0175.102603.816653.81665
1989-0475.495703.836633.83663
1989-0775.598243.841843.84184
1989-1076.042113.864403.86440
1990-0176.477403.886523.88652
1990-0476.676513.896643.89664
1990-0776.938503.909953.90995
1990-1077.317193.929203.92920
1991-0177.504543.938723.93872
1991-0477.844313.955983.95598
1991-0778.221863.975173.97517
1991-1078.374273.982923.98292
1992-0178.763084.002684.00268
1992-0478.912404.010264.01026
1992-0779.021554.015814.01581
1992-1079.233494.026584.02658
1993-0179.200934.024934.02493
1993-0479.402024.035154.03515
1993-0779.687464.049654.04965
1993-1079.981504.064594.06459
1994-0180.394984.085614.08561
1994-0480.932984.112954.11295
1994-0781.365894.134954.13495
1994-1081.951194.164694.16469
1995-0182.313814.183124.18312
1995-0482.773554.206484.20648
1995-0783.055794.220834.22083
1995-1083.366744.236634.23663
1996-0183.756144.256424.25642
1996-0483.997454.268684.26868
1996-0784.404324.289364.28936
1996-1084.934044.316284.31628
1997-0185.419464.340954.34095
1997-0486.026134.371784.37178
1997-0786.503024.396014.39601
1997-1086.798894.411054.41105
1998-0187.040604.423334.42333
1998-0487.150894.428944.42894
1998-0787.160664.429434.42943
1998-1087.220764.432494.43249
1999-0187.491444.446244.44624
1999-0488.000674.472124.47212
1999-0788.515714.498304.49830
1999-1089.104954.528244.52824
2000-0189.855194.566374.56637
2000-0490.372784.592674.59267
2000-0790.930884.621034.62103
2000-1091.286034.639084.63908
2001-0191.076044.628414.62841
2001-0490.793384.614054.61405
2001-0790.535724.600954.60095
2001-1090.377454.592914.59291
2002-0190.711784.609904.60990
2002-0491.284344.639004.63900
2002-0791.599094.654994.65499
2002-1091.830614.666764.66676
2003-0192.049534.677884.67788
2003-0492.067834.678814.67881
2003-0792.463804.698934.69893
2003-1093.168934.734774.73477
2004-0193.695394.761524.76152
2004-0494.274314.790944.79094
2004-0794.679534.811544.81154
2004-1095.140124.834944.83494
2005-0195.225014.839264.83926
2005-0495.799954.868484.86848
2005-0796.164514.887004.88700
2005-1096.650534.911704.91170
2006-0197.207444.940004.94000
2006-0497.595474.959724.95972
2006-0797.782914.969254.96925
2006-1098.180884.989474.98947
2007-0198.585495.010035.01003
2007-0498.874055.024705.02470
2007-0799.258505.044245.04424
2007-1099.533875.058235.05823
2008-0199.954175.079595.07959
2008-04100.030245.083455.08345
2008-07100.000005.081925.08192
2008-1098.741185.017955.01795
2009-0196.859314.922314.92231
2009-0496.844134.921544.92154
2009-0797.559604.957904.95790
2009-1098.098024.985264.98526
2010-0198.702125.015965.01596
2010-04#N/A5.053795.04171
2010-07#N/A5.092595.06492
2010-10#N/A5.130075.08677
2011-01#N/A5.163965.10616
2011-04#N/A5.195245.12448
2011-07#N/A5.224475.14236
2011-10#N/A5.252045.16009
2012-01#N/A5.279165.17880
2012-04#N/A5.305425.19789
2012-07#N/A5.330755.21710
2012-10#N/A5.355205.23632
2013-01#N/A5.378995.25564
2013-04#N/A5.402155.27496
2013-07#N/A5.424715.29425
2013-10#N/A5.446775.31348
2014-01#N/A5.468495.33279
2014-04#N/A5.489865.35209
2014-07#N/A5.510915.37136
2014-10#N/A5.531685.39060
2015-01#N/A5.552195.40980
2015-04#N/A5.572505.42897
2015-07#N/A5.592625.44811
2015-10#N/A5.612585.46723

5.  An Examination of U.S. Exports

Having discussed the outlook for global trade, we now examine the performance of and prospects for U.S. exports. Our interest in the U.S. is twofold. First, given the United States weight in global trade, developments in U.S. exports are clearly an important driver of aggregate trade volumes. Second, focusing on a single country allows for an examination of bilateral trade relationships that is not possible when considering aggregates.

5.1  An Error Correction Model for U.S. Exports

What do the scenarios for world trade outlined above imply for the trajectory of U.S. exports? In order to assess the impact of the various global trade scenarios on U.S. exports we first construct a baseline model that mimics the structure of the global error correction model outlined earlier.

The global model was modified along two key dimensions. First, a trade-weighted measure of the real exchange rate was included as an independent variable in the U.S. model. In the global model, relative price changes could be ignored, as they would be expected to change the cross-country pattern of trade but leave the aggregate volume of trade unaffected. However, when considering U.S. exports separately, relative prices play a potentially important role in explaining both the long-run equilibrium level of exports as well as the short-term dynamics. Second, attempts to include a trend were met with counterintuitive results and hence the trend term was dropped from the estimation. (The estimated trend was negative with the effect of blowing up the income elasticity.)

The estimated parameters of the U.S. model are presented in Table 6. The estimated long-run income elasticity is in the vicinity of 1 1/2, greater than that in the global model, but in line with other models of U.S. exports (including the Federal Reserve's U.S. International Transactions model). The real exchange rate has a significant negative coefficient and is estimated to have a long lag structure, with changes in the real exchange rate continuing to impact the level of exports for three years. Shocks to U.S. exports are persistent, but the speed of adjustment back to equilibrium is considerably faster than that estimated in the global model. A lagged dependent variable was included in the regression; however, the coefficient was insignificant and is not reported. Overall the regression explains 48 percent of the variation in U.S. exports, and hence performs on par with the global model.

Table 6. Estimation Results From the U.S. Exports Error Correction Model

Dependent Variable: Quarterly Growth in U.S. Real Exports of Goods*Benchmark
Sample1981Q1-2008Q3
MethodologyEngle-Granger
Activity variableExport -Weighted Foreign GDP
Long-Term Relationship (a): Global Activity1.474
Long-Term Relationship (a): Real Exchange Rate: Sum (0 to -12)-0.725
Speed of adjustment-0.193***
Short-Term Dynamics: Lagged Global Activity Growth1.755***
Short-Term Dynamics: Real Exchange Rate: Sum (0 to -12)-0.772***
Test for Autocorrelation: LM(1); p-value0.73
Test for Autocorrelation: LM(4); p-value0.45
Test for Heteroscedasticity: ARCH(1); p-value0.28
Test for Heteroscedasticity: ARCH(4); p-value0.12
Adj. R20.48

Goods excluding end-use code 213 (Computers). Due to idiosyncratic price developments, real computer exports exhibit movements that are not well explained by the model determinates and obscure the overall analysis.

Projected U.S. exports from the baseline model are plotted in Chart 9, along with the model solution for the long-run level of exports. For the purposes of the projections the real exchange rate is assumed to be unchanged from 2010:Q3 onward and foreign GDP expands in line with the IMF WEO forecast. As can be seen by comparing the long-run equilibrium with the data, a large model error opened up over the 2008-09 period, such that even given the decline in foreign GDP, U.S. exports appeared exceptionally weak. By the third quarter of 2010, the error had closed a bit from the mid-2009 trough, but the gap remains substantial. The "baseline" forecast, indicated by the dashed-circle line, calls for the rapid expansion of exports over the next two years, boosted importantly by the model's error correction mechanism.

The chart also plots the "downward shift" and "new normal" scenarios discussed previously. In the "downward shift" scenario it is assumed that there is no further error correction in exports, such that the gap between level of exports in the third quarter of 2010 and the estimated long-run equilibrium level remains constant. Under this scenario, export growth in the projection is determined only by the path of foreign GDP growth and the lagged effect of previous exchange rate changes. The "new normal" scenario maintains the no further bounce back assumption of the "downward shift" scenario, but also assumes a 20 percent decline in the foreign income elasticity of exports going forward.

Chart 9: Baseline Projection and Alternative Scenarios: 2010Q4 - 2012Q4

Data for Chart 9 immediately follows

Data for Chart 9

 Long-Run ModelBaselineDownward ShiftNew NormalData
2005Q1804.3680785   789.4561635
2005Q2819.0313923   813.9278254
2005Q3838.0442365   808.5115141
2005Q4859.2795717   830.9078691
2006Q1881.394423   867.0737987
2006Q2903.378696   883.2834409
2006Q3917.9043594   888.8367421
2006Q4927.8629372   917.6276972
2007Q1947.295152   927.1540652
2007Q2969.5116165   944.6457943
2007Q3989.6590069   976.6033351
2007Q41004.916719   997.9724102
2008Q11025.762512   1022.671757
2008Q21046.31277   1056.645459
2008Q31050.011709   1051.685027
2008Q41051.73516   976.245276
2009Q11022.712097   878.9673039
2009Q2979.1736093   870.9290463
2009Q31000.073126   909.0191704
2009Q41023.162715   969.4535634
2010Q11049.597979   999.1927719
2010Q21073.316174   1021.206649
2010Q31100.6469231039.5757081039.5757081039.5757081039.575708
2010Q41106.8181131057.820541045.4044791045.404479 
2011Q11130.3245421088.4438091067.6066151063.14507 
2011Q21147.6633651112.3646371083.9833651077.032467 
2011Q31167.2378071137.418281102.4716871093.198149 
2011Q41188.7094841163.5014611122.7519721111.473795 
2012Q11211.6111551190.2907641144.3829061131.338638 
2012Q21236.0775571218.0345781167.4917491152.476872 
2012Q31258.565591243.330111188.7319961172.057531 
2012Q41280.2938891267.443571209.2546641191.11884 

A comparison of projected export growth rates is presented in Table 7. As can be seen by comparing the "baseline" forecast with the "downward shift" scenario, the assumption of further export bounce back in the baseline is adding almost 2 1/2 percentage points to export growth in 2011 and over 1 percentage point in 2012. Thus, the prospect of further bounce back and whether or not it materializes is central to any near-term and medium-term forecast for U.S. export growth. Giving the importance of bounce back, the lower income elasticity assumed in the "new normal" scenario is second-order in the near-term, although would be of increasing importance going forward.

Table 7. U.S. Export Growth Under Alternative Scenarios

 201020112012
Baseline8.79.58.6
"Downward Shif"7.57.17.4
"New Normal"7.56.16.9

5.2  U.S. Exports by Destination and the Impact of a Multi-Speed Recovery

One of the advantages of examining U.S. trade as opposed to world trade is the ability to focus on bilateral trading relationships. In this section we consider U.S. exports by destination disaggregated across advanced foreign economies (AFEs) and emerging market economies (EMEs). This disaggregation will allow two further avenues for examining the prospects for U.S. exports. First, we can decompose the model error into components due to trade with the AFEs and EMEs. Since, as outlined earlier, the prospect for further bounce back is key to the outlook for U.S. export growth; insight into the distribution of the error can provide important information as to whether bounce back will actually materialize. Second, given that the pace of EME growth is expected to far exceed AFE growth over the next few years, a forecast embodied in the IMF WEO projection, we can examine the implications of the projected multi-speed recovery for U.S. exports.

We estimate separate error-correction models for U.S. exports to AFE and EME country groupings. The models are similar in structure to that estimated for aggregate exports. For each country group, the dependent variable is the growth rate of real goods exports from the U.S. to that country group and the independent variables are export-weighted GDP and real exchange rates calculated within each grouping. The results of the regressions are reported in Table 8. A few notable differences are apparent across the two regions. First, the advanced economies have a higher income elasticity but lower price elasticity for U.S. exports compared with the emerging market economies. Second, exports to the emerging market economies tend to bounce back more quickly to their long-run equilibrium than exports to the advanced economies.

Table 8. Estimation Results From the U.S. Exports Error Correction Model - Disaggregated Markets

Dependent Variable: Quarterly Growth in U.S. Real Exports(1)
AFEs
(2)
EMEs
Sample1981Q1-2008Q31981Q1-2008Q3
Long-Term Relationship: GDP1.6561.335
Long-Term Relationship: Real Exchange Rate (0 to -12)-0.484-0.904
Speed of Adjustment-0.148***-0.244***
Short-Term Dynamics: Lagged GDP Growth2.169***1.538***
Short-Term Dynamics: Real Exchange Rate (0 to -12)-0.437***-1.507***
adj. R20.360.33

Having estimated separate trade models for the AFE and EME countries, we can forecast exports to the two country groupings independently. Before looking at the implications of the disaggregated forecasts for the U.S. export outlook, it is instructive to use the model forecast to examine the 2008-09 trade collapse and the current state of the bounce back in exports. The disaggregated models allow us to decompose the deviation between actual exports and the model-predicted long-run equilibrium (apparent in Chart 9) into components due to underperformance of exports to the AFEs and EMEs separately. As shown in Chart 10, the collapse in exports in 2008-09 resulted in roughly equal model errors for the AFEs and EMEs, with exports underperforming relative to GDP by about the same amount in both regions. The model errors in both regions decreased through the second half of 2009, as exports to both regions bounced back; however, exports to the EME countries appear to have retraced slightly more of their unexplained weakness. So far through 2010, neither the AFE nor the EME model errors has closed much further, and exports have remained weak relative to GDP in both markets. This does not necessarily imply a loss in U.S. export market share, as it may partly reflect a change in the elasticity of trade to GDP across all exporters worldwide, as discussed in Section 4. The model-implied weakness of exports to the EMEs may come as a surprise given the strong growth of apparent exports to the region over 2010; however, EME GDP growth has also been robust over the period and the model would have had exports increase by an even greater amount than was realized.

What does the error decomposition in Chart 10 tell us regarding the prospects for continued error correction in U.S. exports? The relative importance of the AFE countries in the continued underperformance of U.S. exports is not surprising given that a number of trading partners in this grouping suffered severe financial crises. As noted earlier, empirical evidence points to only a sluggish recovery of imports in countries impacted by financial crisis (IMF 2010). It therefore seems likely that this residual may persist for some time. The persistence of the EME model error is harder to explain, in that countries in this grouping largely avoided the financial crisis and have had robust recoveries in GDP. It could be that GDP growth in these countries has been boosted largely by sectors that are less import intensive, i.e. government spending and infrastructure, and as such the model, ignorant of the source of GDP growth, is disappointed by the relative paucity of imports drawn in by such growth. As the impact of fiscal stimulus fades and increased government spending is replaced by other components of GDP, it is likely that imports will recover, pushing U.S. exports to the region closer in line with the level of GDP. However, the persistent gap between actual exports and their estimated equilibrium level might also partly reflect a change in the relationship of trade to GDP, as discussed in Section 4.

A disaggregated consideration of AFE and EME exports also allows us to examine the likely impact of the multi-speed recovery embodied in the IMF's outlook for world growth. In the October 2010 WEO the IMF projects that advanced economies will grow at a sluggish 0.5 percent quarter-on-quarter pace in 2011, picking up a bit to 0.7 percent in 2012. In contrast, emerging market economies are projected to expand at a robust 1.6 percent rate through 2011 and 2012. Using the IMF's growth projections and keeping the real exchange rate flat for both AFEs and EMEs, we are able to project U.S. exports to each region separately, and then aggregate up to a forecast for total U.S. export growth. As shown in Table 9, it turns out that the multi-speed recovery has only a small impact on the forecast in comparison with the baseline aggregate model considered in the previous section.

Chart 10. Decomposition of U.S. Export Model Error Across Destination Markets

Data for Chart 10 immediately follows

Data for Chart 10

 Advanced Foreign EconomiesEmerging Market Economies
2008Q1-9.421582993-1.249106382
2008Q20.8910562321.521879445
2008Q3-7.0205495930.854011752
2008Q4-42.12989677-39.81057967
2009Q1-73.54469013-73.618414
2009Q2-64.172204-43.71566898
2009Q3-52.20919641-37.00143234
2009Q4-29.90918792-22.60148125
2010Q1-39.95843823-10.48353307
2010Q2-37.60724436-14.97761244
2010Q3-32.24357901-29.53783986

The relatively muted impact of the multi-speed recovery on projected export growth is a result of two factors. First, the AFEs and EMEs each accounted for roughly half of U.S. exports and half of global output in the third quarter of 2010. Thus, from a weighting perspective it makes little difference if we consider global GDP growth or disaggregated growth. Second, the higher growth rate of the EME economies is almost balanced by their lower estimated income elasticity and vice versa for the AFE economies, as such that there is little net impact on the projection for export growth.

Another scenario the disaggregated models allow us to consider is a multi-speed adjustment back to long-run equilibrium. Given that the financial crisis has been centered in the AFEs, it is possible that U.S. exports to the region will remain below their long-run equilibrium for an extended period of time. The "prolonged AFE weakness" scenario then is one where there is no further error correction on the part of exports to the AFEs while exports to the EMEs are allowed to bounce back in line with the model. As shown in Table 9, the lack of bounce back in the AFEs lowers projected export growth by 1 percentage point in 2011 and 0.6 percentage point in 2012.

Table 9. U.S. Export Growth With a Multi-Speed Recovery

 201020112012
Aggregate Baseline8.79.58.6
"Multi-Speed Recovery"8.69.89.0
"Prolonged AFE Weakness"8.38.88.4

5.3  U.S. Exports by Commodity

Having considered disaggregated markets, we now turn to an examination of U.S. exports of disaggregated commodities. By separately modeling U.S. exports by category of good we can take another cut at examining the weakness of exports through 2008-09 and the prospects for growth going forward.

We estimated error correction models of the same style as in the previous two sections for a comprehensive breakdown of exports into six major commodity headings. For each regression the independent variables, GDP and the real exchange rate, are identical to the series used in the aggregate regression in Table 6. As can be seen in Table 10, there is considerable variation in the income and price elasticity of exports across commodities. Exports of capital goods show the greatest price sensitivity, while food and "other" goods are relatively price inelastic. Consumer goods are the most income elastic, while exports of foods and "other" goods (importantly military goods) are less sensitive to changes in income.

On the surface, the higher income elasticity of consumer goods may appear surprising given that consumption, particularly of non-durables, is generally less cyclical than investment. In part, this surprising result is likely the outcome of the specific composition of U.S. exports of consumer goods. For example in the second quarter of 2008, fully 20 percent of U.S. real consumer goods exports consisted of artwork, jewellery, and gemstones, probably exceeding the weight on such goods in all but a few consumption bundles. More surprising given the high estimated income elasticity, is that pharmaceuticals comprised roughly a quarter of U.S. consumer goods exports, and it seems likely that such exports would be particularly income inelastic.15

Table 10. Estimation Results From the U.S. Exports Error Correction Model - Disaggregated Commodities

Dependent Variable: Quarterly Growth in U.S. Real Exports(1)
Food
(2)
Industrial Materials
(3)
Capital Goods
(4)
Autos
(5)
Consumer Goods
(6)
Other
Sample1995Q2-2008Q31995Q2-2008Q31995Q2-2008Q31995Q2-2008Q31995Q2-2008Q31995Q2-2008Q3
Long-Term Relationship: Global GDP0.7721.3161.4801.6152.1050.885
Long-Term Relationship: Real Exchange Rate: Sum (0 to -12)-0.318-0.504-0.889-0.715-0.7660.0254
Speed of Adjustment-0.431***-0.315***-0.183***-0.754***-0.319***-0.446***
Short-Term Dynamics: Lagged Global Growth0.3241.219***1.770***1.964***1.813***1.332***
Short-Term Dynamics: Real Exchange Rate: Sum (0 to -12)0.114-0.295-.187-0.345-0.783***2.934***
adj. R20.180.260.330.420.320.20

As was done with destination markets, the separate equations across commodity groups allow us to decompose the deviation from long-run equilibrium into the components due to each commodity. As shown in Chart 11, the unexplained decline in exports that occurred over the 2008-09 period was concentrated in two categories, autos and capital goods. The importance of autos in explaining the model error is particularly pronounced given that this sector accounted for only 10 percent of goods exports in the first half of 2008 and yet accounts for over half of the model error during the trade collapse. The closing of the model error that occurred in the second half of 2009 primarily reflected a narrowing of the large error in autos, while the error in the capital goods model has proven surprisingly resilient. In addition, exports of industrial materials have actually been stronger than the model would have predicted, decreasing the aggregate residual.

One factor contributing to the sluggishness of the recovery in capital goods exports could be the historical persistence of deviations from long-term equilibrium in this sector. As shown in Table 10, the estimated "speed of adjustment" is slowest in the capital goods sector.

Another factor could be that capital goods are impacted more by financial distress than other commodity groups. To investigate this possibility we estimated the capital goods error-correction model including the financial distress variable discussed in section 4.4. However, the coefficients on the financial distress variables did not enter significantly into the regression, perhaps reflecting the relatively short sample period of the regression.

Chart 11. Decomposition of U.S. Export Model Error Across Commodities

Data for Chart 11 immediately follows

Data for Chart 11

 Food Industrial MaterialsCapital GoodsAutosConsumption GoodsOther
2008Q18.3152948.975791864-8.835310211-3.722137904-1.0345810821.936481546
2008Q25.74251620.06167573-5.166901731-2.136770268-0.2679637373.920243788
2008Q33.87464618.83039358-2.889042297-0.2536331811.566452086-4.552864947
2008Q41.784555-0.665392492-26.26753546-22.79905606-9.5143275580.747385956
2009Q1-1.12709-18.578373-41.60765369-51.77876779-12.139550170.662152552
2009Q21.0497360.033903452-39.92313238-45.5370034-3.318164711.309838819
2009Q30.090817.67369083-41.80790851-34.14148636-2.249931431-3.507847794
2009Q49.06253118.43252128-36.37561505-27.906089840.3073458063.051791187
2010Q18.20605123.86771099-41.62845886-24.33320402-1.35152703-0.944633939
2010Q2-0.1220727.36038833-41.45737764-23.03861511-9.2020171563.377279599
2010Q33.38616319.59701713-41.72626819-27.63627033-11.189770352.043179097

6.  Conclusions

Our analysis suggests that during the crisis both world trade and U.S. exports declined significantly more than would have been expected on the basis of historical relationships with economic activity. Moreover, this gap between actual and equilibrium trade is closing only slowly and, under reasonable assumptions, could persist for some time to come. Our analysis highlights that in assessing the near- and medium-term outlook for trade, both globally and for the U.S. specifically, assumptions regarding the speed and degree to which the gap between actual and equilibrium trade closes are absolutely central to any projection for trade going forward. It is too soon to say with any certainty whether the crisis will have only transitory or persistent effects on the relationship between trade and economic activity. However, we have constructed plausible scenarios through which the impact on trade is both long-lasting and meaningful.

Our analysis has shown that many of the factors shaping the future path of world trade will affect U.S. exports in a similar fashion. However, it is also clear that world trade and U.S. trade are highly interdependent (di Mauro et al. 2010). While these linkages are not endogenous to our models, some of the scenarios discussed in this paper can nevertheless be interpreted along these lines. For instance, the scenario with lower world GDP growth (Section 4.2) could partly reflect lower activity growth in the U.S. Of course, the interdependency also works in the other direction. For instance, a possible break in the elasticity of world imports to GDP might further complicate the task of forecasting U.S. exports on the basis of foreign GDP.


References

G. Alessandria, J. Kaboski and V. Midrigam, "The Great Trade Collapse of 2008-09: An Inventory Adjustment?", NBER Working Paper 16059, 2010.

M. Amiti and D. Weinstein, "Exports and financial shocks", NBER Working Paper No. 15556, 2009.

M. Auboin, "Boosting the availability of trade finance in the current crisis: Background analysis for a substantial G20 package", CEPR Policy Insight No 35, 2009.

M. Bussière and B. Schnatz, "Evaluating China's Integration in World Trade: A Benchmark Based on a Gravity Model", Open Economies Review, 2009, Vol. 20, No. 1, pp. 85-111, 2009.

R. Bems, R. C. Johnson and K.-M. Yi, "Demand Spillovers and the Collapse of Trade in the Global Recession", IMF Working Papers 10/142, International Monetary Fund, 2010.

J.-P. Chauffour and T. Farole, "Trade finance in crisis: market adjustment or market failure?", Policy Research Working Paper No 5003, The World Bank, 2009.

C. Cheung and S. Guichard, "Understanding the World Trade Collapse", OECD Working Papers, No. 729, 2009.

G. Dell'Ariccia, E. Detragiache and R. Rajan, "The real effects of banking crises", Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 17, pp. 89-112, 2008.

J. di Giovanni and A. Levchenko, "Putting the parts together: Trade, vertical linkages, and business cycle comovement", American Economic Journal, Vol.2, Issue 2, 2010.

J. di Giovanni and A. Levchenko, "International Trade and Aggregate Fluctuations in Granular Economies", Working Papers 585, PlaceTypeplaceUniversity of PlaceNameMichigan, 2009.

F. di Mauro, S. Dées and M. Lombardi, "Catching the flu from the United States. Synchronisation and transmission mechanisms to the euro area", Palgrave Macmillan, 2010.

T. Dorsey, "Trade finance stumbles", Finance and Development, Vol. 46, No 1, March 2009.

S. Djankov, C. Freund and C. Pham, "Trading on time", Policy Research Working Paper No 3909, The World Bank, 2006.

B. Eichengreen and D. Irwin, "The slide to protectionism in the Great Depression: Who succumbed and why?", Working Paper No. 15142, NBER, 2009.

C. Engel and J. Wang, "International trade in durable goods: Understanding volatility, cyclicality, and elasticities", NBER Working Paper No. 13814, 2008.

European Central Bank, "Recent developments in global and euro area trade", article in the ECB Monthly Bulletin, August 2010.

S. Evenett (ed.), "Tensions contained...for now: The 8th GTA Report", CEPR, November 2010.

C. Freund, "The Trade Response to Global Downturns - Historical Evidence", World Bank Policy Research Paper, No. 5015, 2009.

D. Haugh, A. Mourougane and O. Chatal, "The automobile industry in and beyond the crisis", Economics Department Working Papers, No 745, OECD, 2010.

D. Hummels, "Time as a trade barrier", GTAP Working Paper Series, No 18, 2001.

D. Hummels, J. Ishii and K.-M. Yi, "The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade", Journal of International Economics, Vol. 54, Issue 1, 2001.

International Monetary Fund, "World Economic Outlook", October 2010.

International Monetary Fund, "World Economic Outlook", April 2009.

P. Kannan, "Credit conditions and recoveries from recessions associated with financial crises", IMF Working Paper, No. 83, 2010.

H. Kee, C. Neagu and A. Nicita, "Is protectionism on the rise? Assessing national trade policies during the crisis of 2008", Policy Research Working Paper No. 5274, The World Bank, 2010.

J. Kleinert and placeN. Zorell (2010), ,,"The export magnification effect of offshoring", IAW Discussion Papers, No. 63.

A. Levchenko, L. Lewis and L. Tesar, "The collapse of international trade during the 2008-2009 crisis: In search of the smoking gun", Working Paper No 16006, NBER, 2010.

G. Maddala and I. Kim, "Unit roots, cointegration, and structural change", Cambridge University Press, 2003.

C. Reinhart and K. Rogoff, "This time is different: Eight centuries of financial folly", Princeton University Press, 2009.

J. Wang, "Durable goods and the collapse of global trade", Economic Letter, Vol. 5, No 2, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 2010.


Appendix

Table A.1. International Trade in Goods During the Recent Episode (Percentage Changes)

 80s90s2000s (Up to 2008Q3)2000s (Up to 2010Q1)Full Sample
Δy: Mean0.80.70.90.80.8
Δy: Median0.80.81.11.00.9
Δy: Std. Dev.0.30.30.40.60.3
Δy: Observations38403541113
Δm: Mean1.41.71.61.21.5
Δm: Median1.31.72.02.01.7
Δm: Std. Dev.0.80.81.32.51.0
Δm: Observations35403541110
Δm/Δy(*)1.72.21.71.41.9
Correlation0.650.590.750.910.65

(1) "China" includes Hong Kong
Note: The country-specific peaks and troughs are based on the period 2008-09. The underlying data are seasonally adjusted and transformed into three-month-moving averages. Aggregates include intra-regional trade.
Sources: CPB and ECB staff calculations.

Table A.2. Descriptive Statistics (Based on Quarterly Percentage Growth Rates)

 80s90s2000s (up to 2008Q3)2000s (up to 2010Q1)full sample
Δy: Mean0.80.70.90.80.8
Δy: Mean0.80.81.11.00.9
Δy: Mean0.30.30.40.60.3
Δy: Mean38403541113
Δm: Mean1.41.71.61.21.5
Δm: Mean1.31.72.02.01.7
Δm: Mean0.80.81.32.51.0
Δm: Mean35403541110
Δm/Δy(*)1.72.21.71.41.9
Correlation0.650.590.750.910.65

Note: "Full sample" refers to 1980Q1-2008Q3.


Footnotes

+  International Finance Division, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington DC 20551 U.S.A. [email protected]Return to text

++  European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany. [email protected], [email protected], [email protected]Return to text

**  The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System nor those of the European Central Bank. We have benefited from comments from Tamarah Shakir and the participants at the Workshop on "The Impact of the Crisis on the Assessment of the International Environment: Lessons for Modelers and Practitioners", December 16-17 2010. Return to text

1.  In the aftermath of the burst of the dotcom bubble in 2001, global trade recorded a peak-to-trough decline of about 4 1/2 percent. Before that there were globally only rare quarterly incidents of small negative growth rates in world trade. Return to text

2.  For up-to-date analysis of business cycle synchronisation and the role of trade linkages, see di Mauro et al. (2010). Return to text

3.  For the role of durable goods, see Engel and Wang (2008) and Wang (2010). Return to text

4.  Freund (2009) suggests an elasticity larger than 3, while Cheung and Guichard (2009) find a long-run elasticity of about 2-2.5. This finding may be due to the fact that Cheung and Guichard argue that including a time trend leads in their data to inconclusive results. Accordingly, the autonomous globalisation trends, which are not (or only indirectly) specified in their model, may bias their parameter estimates for the relationship between economic activity and trade upwards. Return to text

5.  We also considered additional lags of $ \Delta m$ and $ \Delta y$ . However, the refined lag structure was not robust across different sub-samples. Return to text

6.  It is well known that such outliers can produce misleading inferences in the application of unit root tests; see, e. g. Maddala and Kim (2003). Return to text

7.  Another possibility - not discussed in this paper - would be a structural break in the globalisation (time) trend. Return to text

8.  See IMF (2009), pp. 103-138. Return to text

9.  See ECB (2010) for an overview of the different factors shaping the downturn and the subsequent recovery in world trade. Return to text

10.  See Di Giovanni and Levchenko (2009) for evidence on how the shock was transmitted via international production networks. See also di Giovanni and Levchenko (2010) and Levchenko et al. (2010). Return to text

11.  For an overview of the recent measures to support the car industry, see D. Haugh et al. (2010). Return to text

12.  Banking crises like the one observed in the recent past are typically followed by other episodes of financial distress, particularly as far as sovereign debt is concerned. See Reinhart and Rogoff (2009). Return to text

13.  For more details on the time lags involved in international trade, see Djankov et al. (2006) and Hummels (2001). Return to text

14.  If only the long-run elasticity changed, the discrepancy between the "downward shift" and the "new normal" scenarios would be relatively small in the short and medium term - due to the low speed of adjustment - but increase considerably over time. Return to text

15.  In fact, looking just at the most recent downturn and rebound in exports, the greatest volatility in consumer goods exports was recorded in the "gem diamonds" category which plunged 50 percent from the second quarter of 2008 through the second quarter of 2009 only to then rebound 50 percent through the third quarter of 2010. In contrast, exports of pharmaceuticals actually increased 25 percent during the downturn in trade and have fallen back a bit during the rebound. Return to text


This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text

Home | Economic research and data | Publications and education resources
Accessibility | Contact us
Last update: March 24, 2011