Keywords: Affine term structure model, inflation risk premium
Abstract:
This paper decomposes nominal Treasury yields into expected real rates, expected inflation rates, real risk premiums, and inflation risk premiums by separately calibrating a three-factor affine term structure model to the nominal Treasury and TIPS yield curves. Although this particular application seems to produce expected real short rates and inflation rates that are somewhat static, there are theoretical advantages to calibrating the model to nominal and real yields separately. Moreover, the estimates correlate positively with back-of-the-envelope measures of the inflation risk premium. With respect to the current environment, monetary policy uncertainty does not seem to have contributed to the apparent increase in the inflation risk premium since the beginning of 2006. Also, in purely nominal terms, the increase in term premiums thus far this year might be just as much a global as a domestic phenomenon, given that nominal term premiums have also increased in Germany and the United Kingdom.
This paper outlines an estimate of the inflation risk premium based on a three-factor Gaussian term structure model of both the nominal U.S. Treasury and TIPS yield curves. Model calibration to the nominal and real yield curves separately produces estimates of nominal and real term premiums and, in turn, (zero coupon and forward) inflation risk premiums along the term structure. This particular application of the model produces expected real short rates and inflation rates that are somewhat static, likely because of the very short available sample of TIPS data. Nonetheless, there may be some key theoretical advantages to separate as opposed to joint estimation of the real and nominal curves. Besides, the estimates of the real and inflation risk premiums seem quite sensible. Consistent with similar approaches (Kim and Wright, 2005), these results suggests that term premiums reached very low historical levels during the monetary policy tightening cycle that commenced in June 2004, and even more recently, some of those declines have retraced since the beginning of this year. Also, estimates of the inflation risk premium derived from the model correlate positively with common back-of-the-envelope measures.
This paper also examines whether the inflation risk premium produced by the model correlates with measures of inflation and monetary policy uncertainty. Depending on the particular proxy for those variables, some time-series regressions produce a statistically significant and positive correlation between inflation uncertainty and the inflation risk premium either in levels or first differences. And, at least in levels, there does appear to be a statistically significant and positive relation between Eurodollar implied volatility and the inflation risk premium estimate. Also, the small increase in option-implied monetary policy uncertainty this year has contributed minimally to the apparent increase in the inflation risk premium. Application of a three-factor model to nominal government bond yields in Germany and the United Kingdom also indicates that term premiums have increased in these countries by a similar magnitude, which suggests that the recent rise in term premiums is in part a global rather than a purely domestic phenomenon.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly reviews the broad literature on inflation risk premiums and outlines the methodology. Section 3 reviews the three-factor (Gaussian) affine term structure used to disentangle expected real rates, expected inflation, the real term premium, and the inflation risk premium from nominal forward and zero-coupon rates, and Section 4 outlines the results in the context of the current environment. Sections 5 and 6 examine the estimates with respect to other measures of the inflation risk premium and to proxies for inflation and monetary policy uncertainty, and Section 7 describes estimates of nominal term premiums in Germany and the United Kingdom vis-à-vis those in the United States. Section 8 concludes.
The inflation risk premium is one of many risk premiums that compensate investors for uncertainty, and financial economists have used a wide variety of approaches to estimate that premium. For example, some studies examine ex ante and ex post returns on nominal and inflation-indexed sovereign debt (Kandel et al., 1996), others focus on the covariance of returns on nominal and (hypothetical) indexed government bonds in a traditional CAPM or consumption-based CAPM framework (Campbell and Shiller, 1996; Bodie, 1979), and a few employ a much more behavioral approach (Hammond et al., 1999). More recently, however, inflation risk premium estimates have been obtained from arbitrage-free (affine) term structure models that include both nominal interest rates and inflation (D'Amico et al., 2005).1 By calibrating a three-factor term structure model to the nominal and real yield curves separately, this paper is most akin to these more recent efforts.
The methodology in this paper abstracts from tax, liquidity, convexity, and other issues. To begin, an instantaneous nominal forward interest rate at some horizon , denoted by , is comprised of the expected future real rate, ; the expected future inflation rate, ; the real forward term premium, ; and the inflation risk premium, , as in
Finally, with and , one can easily recover the (forward) inflation risk premium simply as
To briefly review how to obtainfrom the nominal term structure, assume, just as in Kim and Wright (2005) and similar to Langetieg (1980) and others, that the underlying factors that drive nominal bond prices, denoted by the vector , follow a multivariate (mean-reverting) Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, as in
For and the real curve, I calibrate precisely the same model, where the underlying stochastic processes again follow
Separate calibration of the model to nominal Treasuries and TIPS obviously implies that the relevant state vectors, and , are formally distinct. They certainly can be positively correlated, as one indeed would expect, but this method imposes no constraints on the latent variables that drive the real and nominal yield curves. The key potential problematic issue with the implementation of (8) and (9) is the very short history of TIPS. Moreover, liquidity was poor during the early period of trading, and therefore any estimate of the real term premium likely includes a sizeable liquidity premium, which in turn biases the inflation risk premium estimate downward.
The top panel of Exhibit 1 plots the nominal ten-year instantaneous forward term premium based on the nominal term structure, the real ten-year instantaneous forward term premium based on the TIPS term structure, and the model-implied forward inflation risk premium at that horizon from January 4, 2000 through July 25, 2006. Again, given the relative illiquidity of the TIPS market after the inception of trading, the real term premium likely includes a substantial liquidity premium, and therefore the inflation risk premium is probably understated for the earlier part of the sample. More recently, the inflation risk premium has increased from near sample lows in mid-2005, but it remains at a moderate level--59 basis points, very close to the sample average of 61 basis points.
Table 1 shows the decomposition of ten-year nominal forward rates in more detail for selected dates in the sample. Column 1 indicates that forward rates have fallen 95 basis points from the day before tightening began on June 30, 2004 to the most recent observation on July 25, 2006, and Column 2 shows that the model-implied forward rate has fallen by 69 basis points over this period. The expected real short rate has increased about 14 basis points, while expected inflation is largely unchanged, as noted in Columns 3 and 4, respectively. Also, as indicated in Columns 5 and 6, the decline in the nominal term premium is 45 basis points, and the inflation risk premium is 36 basis points lower since the inception of policy firming.6 Regarding developments since the beginning of 2006, the results might be interpreted as consistent with at least a partial unwinding of the "conundrum" of unusually low long-term interest rates, perhaps first identified in early 2005.7 In fact, the model attributes virtually all of the increase in forward rates since year-end 2005 to increases in risk premiums, with the increase in the inflation risk premium (32 basis points) a bit more pronounced than the rise in the real term premium (24 basis points).8
Returning to the middle panel of Exhibit 1, seven-year instantaneous forward term premiums, perhaps not surprisingly reflect a similar pattern, as they also have rebounded from historic lows. But, some differences are noteworthy. As indicated in Table 2, the increase in the expected real rate since the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) began tightening policy is more pronounced than at the ten-year horizon, and the decline in term premiums is comparatively more concentrated in the real as opposed to the inflation risk premium. Also, in general, term premiums over the sample are considerably lower, as the current estimate is 23 basis points, with a sample average of 13 basis points.
Finally, the bottom panel of Exhibit 1 plots the ten-year zero coupon premiums. These estimates are less intuitive, as the inflation risk premium is largely negative from the beginning of the sample through the middle of 2002 and hovers close to zero beyond that point. These results might reflect the fact that fewer TIPS issues are used to fit the shorter end of the curve, which is a less pronounced issue with respect to distant horizon forward rates.
Comparisons with other measures of the inflation risk premium are instructive. One back-of-the-envelope proxy refers to the difference between nearly adjacent distant-horizon nominal and real forward rates. For example, the spread between nominal (real) forward rates at two distant horizons is often considered a rough approximation for the nominal (real) term premium, because investors likely expect the nominal (real) short rate to be unchanged far into the future. In turn, one can deduce the inflation risk premium from such estimates. This estimate is based on the assumption that investors' best guess about the trajectory of inflation between, say, nine and ten years ahead is that it will be constant, and therefore the difference between distant forward breakeven rates is the inflation risk premium.
Table 3 summarizes the correlation matrix using daily data from January 4, 2000 through July 25, 2006 between the three-factor model estimate of the ten- and seven-year instantaneous forward inflation risk premiums and two such back-of-the-envelope measures--the forward breakeven inflation spreads between six and seven and between nine and ten years ahead. Consistent with intuition, the ten-year (seven-year) model-based estimate is positively and statistically significantly correlated with the alternative measures, as the coefficients are 0.49 and 0.28 (0.31 and 0.28) vis-à-vis the six- to seven- and nine to ten-year spreads, respectively.9 Therefore in general, although the proxies are somewhat crude, these results provide some additional confidence in the model-based estimates.
Besides alternative measures, another issue is whether the inflation risk premium estimates correlate with other key variables, including various proxies for inflation and monetary policy uncertainty.10 Toward that end, Table 4 summarizes time-series regressions that generally follow
Regarding , the regressions also consider implied Eurodollar volatility, measured at the six-month horizon, as a proxy for uncertainty regarding the path of monetary policy. Of course, uncertainty about policy might be related to uncertainty not only about inflation but also about the real economy and about the reaction function of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). In addition, the regressions include a dummy variable for the period after the transition to the current Chairman on February 1, 2006.
Turning to the results, Regressions 1 and 2 in Table 4 include the monthly average level of the ten-year instantaneous forward inflation risk premium on the left-hand-side. With respect to , two of the crude indicators of inflation uncertainty do not support the hypothesis--somewhat curiously, the variance of the Michigan survey enters Regression 1 negatively and is statistically significant, and the level of relative price changes in the CPI is positive as expected but statistically insignificant in Regressions 1 and 2. However, as Regression 2 indicates, the dispersion in long-run inflation forecasts from Blue Chip enters significantly with the expected positive sign. The coefficient suggests that the range of dispersion in the sample, from 0.6 to 1.1 percent, implies about a 34 basis point increase in the inflation risk premium.
With respect to , the results do suggest that the inflation risk premium correlates significantly and positively with Eurodollar implied volatility. The coefficients from Regressions 1 and 2 imply that a one standard deviation increase in volatility corresponds to just under a 20 basis point increase in the inflation risk premium, which ranged from about 15 to 120 basis points over the sample period. But whatever the economic significance in general, the increase in the inflation risk premium since the beginning of the year, or indeed since the end of the Greenspan era, does not appear to be related to policy uncertainty.14 In fact, implied volatility has remained historically low so far during 2006,15 and the coefficient from Regression 1, for example, suggests that only 1 (3) basis point(s) of the 32 (14) basis point increase in the inflation risk premium from December 30, 2005 (January 31, 2006) through July 25, 2006 owes to an increase in uncertainty about the path of short rates, which, it may bear repeating, has been quite small anyway.16 In addition, the dummy variable for the post January 2006 period is statistically insignificant in both Regressions 1 and 2.
Regressions 3 and 4 examine first differences, and only one of the variables on the right-hand-side enters the model significantly. Monthly changes in the dispersion of long-run inflation forecasts from the Blue Chip survey correlate positively with changes in the premium, although the result is only significant at the 10 percent level.
Again, the increase in inflation risk premiums in the United States since the beginning of the year does not seem to be related to any notable increase in monetary policy uncertainty. Cross-country evidence, albeit suggestive, might also be generally relevant on this score. Briefly, and just in nominal terms, if the recent increase in term premiums in the United States is primarily due either to increased monetary policy uncertainty or idiosyncratic developments related to the central bank, then one might expect smaller relative increases in other countries, all else equal.
Of course, controlling for all relevant variables across cases is impossible, but to consider this issue, I calibrated the same three-factor model used to fit the nominal and real yields curves in the United States, as outlined in (5) - (6),17 to fitted government bond yield curves for Germany and the United Kingdom.18 Table 5 summarizes the relevant results, including ten-year instantaneous forward rates, the model-implied ten-year instantaneous forward rates, and nominal forward term premiums for key dates in the sample. Model-implied forward rates in Germany and the United States increased by 60 and 54 basis points, respectively, between July 25, 2006 and year-end 2005, but notably, the comparative increase in the nominal term premium was actually a touch more pronounced in the German than in the American case (70 versus 56 basis points). Also, although the increase in forward rates was smaller in the United Kingdom, the model nonetheless suggests that the back-up in rates so far this year owes primarily to an increase in the nominal term premium. In addition, the share of the drop in forward rates due to declines in term premiums since the inception of Federal Reserve tightening in June 2004 is largely comparable across these three cases. Therefore, although the comparisons are naturally only suggestive and global debt markets are closely interrelated, these results are consistent with the view that the increase in term premiums thus far this year is perhaps just as much a global as a domestic financial phenomenon.
In summary, this paper decomposes nominal interest rates into expected real rates, expected inflation rates, real risk premiums, and inflation risk premiums by calibrating standard three-factor affine term structure models separately to the nominal Treasury and TIPS yield curves. The key caveats with the procedure regard not the model per se, but the parameter estimation and the short sample on real yields. As noted by Kim and Orphanides (2005), in the absence of survey data, a short sample period biases the estimates of the persistence of the factors downwards, and this effect is especially severe with the TIPS data. In short, this particular application of the model seems comparatively biased toward attributing too much of the movement in forward rates to term premiums. But despite some drawbacks, there may be substantial theoretical advantages in calibrating the model separately to the nominal and real yield curves, as opposed to joint estimation. Joint estimation as conducted by D'Amico et al. (2005) and Kim and Wright (2005) requires that the same three factors drive both the nominal and real term structures, a potentially limiting feature that this estimate avoids.
In addition, the results, both in terms of the current level (at least at more distant horizons) and the time variation of the inflation risk premium, seem broadly consistent with alternative back-of-the-envelope measures and proxies for uncertainty. Also, some tentative inferences regarding the current interest rate environment are noteworthy. Namely, the apparent increase in the inflation risk premium since the beginning of 2006 does not in fact seem to be driven by monetary policy uncertainty, which appears to have remained low this year. More generally and in nominal terms, given similar yield curve developments in Germany and the United Kingdom, the increase in term premiums thus far in 2006 might be more of a global than a primarily domestic financial development.
Bodie, Zvi, 1979, "Inflation Risk and Capital Market Equilibrium," NBER Working Paper No. 373 (July).
Campbell, John Y. and Robert J. Shiller, 1996, "A Scorecard for Indexed Government Debt," NBER Working Paper No. 5587 (May).
Cox, J.C., J.E. Ingersoll, and S.A. Ross, 1985, "A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates," Econometrica, Vol. 53, pp. 385-408.
Dai, Q. and K. J. Singleton, 2002, "Expectations Puzzles, Time-Varying Risk Premia, and Dynamic Models of the Term Structure," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 63, pp. 415-441.
D'Amico, Stefania, Don Kim, and Min Wei, 2005, "Tips from TIPS: The Informational Content of Treasury Inflation-Protected Security Prices," mimeo.
Das, Sanjiv. R., 2002, "The Surprise Element: Jumps in Interest Rates," Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 106, pp. 27-65.
Durham, J. Benson, 2006, "Additional Analytical Approximations of the Term Structure and Distributional Assumptions for Jump-Diffusion Processes," Journal of Fixed Income, Vol. 15 No. 4 (March), pp. 61-73.
Hammond, P. Brett, Andrew C. Fairbanks, and J. Benson Durham, 1999, "Understanding the Inflation Risk Premium," in John Brynjolfsson, Frank J. Fabozzi, eds., Handbook of Inflation Indexed Bonds. New Hope, PA: Frank J. Fabozzi Associates.
Ho, T. and S. Lee, 1986, "Term Structure Movements and Pricing Interest Rate Contingent Claims," Journal of Finance, Vol. 41, pp. 1011-1029.
Kandel, Shmuel, Aharon R. Ofer, and Oded Sarig, 1996, "Real Interest Rates and Inflation: An Ex-Ante Empirical Analysis, Journal of Finance, Vol. 50 No. 1 (March), pp. 205-225.
Kim, Don and Athanasios Orphanides, 2005, "Term Structure Estimation with Survey Data on Interest Rate Forecasts," Finance and Economics Discussion Series, No. 48.
Kim, Don and Jonathan Wright, 2005, "An Arbitrage-Free Three-Factor Term Structure Model and the Recent Behavior of Long-Term Yields and Distant-Horizon Forward Rates," Finance and Economics Discussion Series, No. 33.
Langetieg, Terrence, 1980, "A Multivariate Model of the Term Structure," Journal of Finance, Vol. 35 No. 1 (March), pp. 71-97.
Piazzesi, M., 2005, "Bond Yields and the Federal Reserve," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113 No. 2, pp. 311-344.
Vasicek, O., 1977, "An Equilibrium Characterization of the Term Structure of Interest Rates," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 5, pp. 177-188.
Date | (1)
Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(2)
Model-implied Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(3)
Expected Real Rate |
(4)
Expected Inflation |
(5)
Real Term Premium |
(6)
Inflation Risk Premium |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
12/29/00 | 5.90 | 6.10 | 1.92 | 2.34 | 1.57 | 0.27 |
12/28/01 | 6.72 | 6.92 | 1.82 | 2.39 | 1.95 | 0.76 |
12/31/02 | 6.28 | 6.18 | 1.74 | 2.39 | 1.40 | 0.65 |
12/31/03 | 6.38 | 6.39 | 1.77 | 2.38 | 1.19 | 1.05 |
06/29/04 | 6.42 | 6.38 | 1.78 | 2.42 | 1.23 | 0.94 |
12/30/04 | 5.82 | 5.62 | 1.81 | 2.44 | 0.71 | 0.65 |
12/30/05 | 4.86 | 5.15 | 1.92 | 2.42 | 0.54 | 0.27 |
07/25/06 | 5.47 | 5.68 | 1.92 | 2.40 | 0.78 | 0.59 |
Change to 07/25/06: from 06/29/2004 |
-0.95 | -0.69 | 0.14 | -0.03 | -0.45 | -0.36 |
Change to 07/25/06:
from 12/30/2005 |
0.61 | 0.54 | 0.00 | -0.02 | 0.24 | 0.32 |
Change to 07/20/05:
from 06/29/2004 |
-1.56 | -1.35 | 0.11 | 0.03 | -0.70 | -0.79 |
Kim and Wright (2005) | NA | -1.30 | -0.11 | -0.14 | -0.73 | -0.34 |
Date | (1)
Instantaneous 7-year Forward Rate |
(2)
Model-implied Instantaneous 7-year Forward Rate |
(3)
Expected Real Rate |
(4)
Expected Inflation |
(5)
Real Term Premium |
(6)
Inflation Risk Premium |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
12/29/00 | 5.61 | 5.64 | 1.98 | 2.26 | 1.63 | -0.23 |
12/28/01 | 6.54 | 6.58 | 1.70 | 2.35 | 2.31 | 0.22 |
12/31/02 | 5.57 | 5.49 | 1.50 | 2.27 | 1.68 | 0.04 |
12/31/03 | 5.80 | 5.79 | 1.58 | 2.25 | 1.23 | 0.73 |
06/29/04 | 5.94 | 5.87 | 1.60 | 2.41 | 1.31 | 0.55 |
12/30/04 | 5.18 | 5.02 | 1.69 | 2.50 | 0.56 | 0.26 |
12/30/05 | 4.53 | 4.60 | 1.98 | 2.52 | 0.23 | -0.14 |
07/25/06 | 5.18 | 5.22 | 1.97 | 2.45 | 0.57 | 0.23 |
Change to 07/25/06 from 06/29/2004 | -0.76 | -0.65 | 0.37 | 0.04 | -0.74 | -0.32 |
Change to 07/25/06 from 12/30/2005 | 0.64 | 0.63 | -0.01 | -0.08 | 0.34 | 0.37 |
Ten-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium | Seven-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium | Instantaneous Forward Breakeven Spread, 9 to 10 Years | Instantaneous Forward Breakeven Spread, 6 to 7 Years | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Ten-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium | 1.00 | |||
Seven-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium | 0.96 | 1.00 | ||
Instantaneous Forward Breakeven Spread, 9 to 10 Years | 0.28 | 0.28 | 1.00 | |
Instantaneous Forward Breakeven Spread, 6 to 7 Years | 0.49 | 0.31 | 0.59 | 1.00 |
Independent Variables | Dependent Variable: Ten-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium - Level (1) |
Dependent Variable: Ten-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium - Level (2) |
Dependent Variable: Ten-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium - Change (3) |
Dependent Variable: Ten-year Instantaneous Forward Inflation Risk Premium - Change (4) |
---|---|---|---|---|
Michigan Inflation Survey Variance | -0.0144 | |||
Michigan Inflation Survey Variance Robust p values | (0.001)** | |||
Michigan Inflation Survey Variance | 0.0019 | |||
Michigan Inflation Survey Variance Robust p values | (0.574) | |||
Blue Chip Inflation Survey Dispersion | 0.6754 | |||
Blue Chip Inflation Survey Dispersion Robust p values | (0.000)** | |||
Blue Chip Inflation Survey Dispersion | 0.8155 | |||
Blue Chip Inflation Survey Dispersion Robust p values | (0.063)+ | |||
CPI Relative Price Dispersion | 0.5068 | -2.1891 | ||
CPI Relative Price Dispersion Robust p values | (0.876) | (0.565) | ||
Eurodollar Implied Volatility, 6 Months Ahead | 0.0144 | 0.0140 | ||
Eurodollar Implied Volatility, 6 Months Ahead Robust p values | (0.000)** | (0.000)** | ||
Dummy for Post January 2006 | 0.0403 | 0.0526 | 0.0114 | 0.0304 |
Dummy for Post January 2006Robust p values | (0.428) | (0.247) | (0.729) | (0.517) |
CPI Relative Price Dispersion | -0.1523 | 0.3298 | ||
CPI Relative Price Dispersion Robust p values | (0.949) | (0.894) | ||
Eurodollar Implied Volatility, 6 Months Ahead | 0.0065 | 0.0074 | ||
Eurodollar Implied Volatility, 6 Months Ahead Robust p values | (0.394) | (0.318) | ||
Squared CPI Surprise | -0.3352 | -0.2383 | ||
Squared CPI Surprise Robust p values | (0.415) | (0.587) | ||
Squared PPI Surprise | -0.0067 | -0.0146 | ||
Squared PPI Surprise Robust p values | (0.783) | (0.599) | ||
Constant | 0.4885 | -0.3088 | 0.0033 | 0.0036 |
Constant Robust p values | (0.000)** | (0.045)* | (0.906) | (0.896) |
Observations | 78 | 75 | 77 | 74 |
R-squared | 0.545 | 0.572 | 0.043 | 0.062 |
Durbin-Watson | 0.849 | 0.802 | 2.108 | 2.127 |
*Robust p values in parentheses (+ significant at 10%; * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%). Regressions that include Blue Chip data cover January 2000 - March 2006. Return to Table
Date | (1) Germany Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(2) Germany Model-implied Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(3) Germany Nominal Forward Term Premium |
(4) United Kingdom Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(5) United Kingdom Model-implied Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(6) United Kingdom Nominal Forward Term Premium |
(7) United States Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(8) United States Model-implied Instantaneous 10-year Forward Rate |
(9) United States Nominal Forward Term Premium |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
12/29/00 | 5.64 | 5.62 | 2.55 | 4.15 | 4.18 | -0.02 | 5.90 | 6.10 | 1.83 |
12/28/01 | 5.81 | 5.91 | 2.85 | 4.78 | 4.72 | 0.40 | 6.72 | 6.92 | 2.70 |
12/31/02 | 5.49 | 5.54 | 2.46 | 4.66 | 4.71 | 0.50 | 6.28 | 6.18 | 2.04 |
12/31/03 | 5.36 | 5.47 | 2.36 | 4.84 | 4.97 | 0.74 | 6.38 | 6.39 | 2.24 |
06/29/04 | 5.37 | 5.46 | 2.34 | 4.99 | 5.04 | 0.80 | 6.42 | 6.38 | 2.18 |
12/30/04 | 4.65 | 4.68 | 1.45 | 4.57 | 4.58 | 0.42 | 5.82 | 5.62 | 1.37 |
12/30/05 | 3.73 | 3.82 | 0.43 | 3.93 | 3.89 | -0.24 | 4.86 | 5.15 | 0.81 |
07/25/06 | 4.34 | 4.43 | 1.13 | 4.35 | 4.38 | 0.23 | 5.47 | 5.68 | 1.37 |
Change to 07/25/06:
from 06/29/2004 |
-1.04 | -1.03 | -1.21 | -0.63 | -0.65 | -0.58 | -0.95 | -0.69 | -0.81 |
Change to 07/25/06:from 12/30/2005 | 0.61 | 0.60 | 0.70 | 0.43 | 0.49 | 0.46 | 0.61 | 0.54 | 0.56 |