Keywords: Fiscal policy, government spending, incomplete risk sharing, entrepreneurial risk.
Abstract:
JEL codes: E13, E62.
Studying the impact of government spending on macroeconomic outcomes is one of the most celebrated policy exercises within the neoclassical growth model: it is important for understanding the business-cycle implications of fiscal policy, the macroeconomic effects of wars, and the cross-section of countries. Some classics include Hall (1980), Barro (1981, 1989), Aiyagari, Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992), Baxter and King (1993), Braun and McGrattan (1993), and McGrattan and Ohanian (1999, 2006).
These studies have all maintained the convenient assumption of complete markets, abstracting from the possibility that agents' saving and investment decisions, and hence their reaction to changes in fiscal policy, may crucially depend on the extent of risk sharing within the economy. This paper contributes towards filling this gap. It revisits the macroeconomic effects of government consumption within an incomplete-markets variant of the neoclassical growth model.
The key deviation we make from the standard paradigm is the introduction of uninsurable idiosyncratic risk in production and investment. All other ingredients of our model are the same as in the canonical neoclassical growth model: firms operate neoclassical constant-returns-to-scale technologies, households have standard CRRA/CEIS preferences, and markets are competitive.
The focus on idiosyncratic production/investment risk is motivated by two considerations. First, this friction is empirically relevant. This is obvious for less developed economies. But even in the United States, privately-owned firms account for nearly half of aggregate production and employment. Furthermore, the typical investor--the median rich household--holds a very undiversified portfolio, more than one half of which is allocated to private equity.1 And second, as our paper shows, this friction upsets some key predictions of the standard neoclassical paradigm.
In the standard paradigm, the steady-state values of the capital-labor ratio, productivity (output per work hour), the wage rate, and the interest rate, are all pinned down by the equality of the marginal product of capital with the discount rate in preferences. As a result, any change in the level of government consumption, even if it is permanent, has no effect on the long-run values of these variables.2On the other hand, because higher consumption for the government means lower net-of-taxes wealth for the households, a permanent increase in government consumption raises labor supply. It follows that employment and, by implication, output and investment increase. But the long-run levels of capital intensity and productivity unchanged.
The picture is quite different once we allow for incomplete markets. The same wealth effect that, in response to an increase in government consumption, stimulates labor supply in the standard paradigm, now also discourages investment. This is simply because risk taking, and hence investment, is sensitive to wealth. We thus find very different long-run effects. First, a permanent increase in government consumption necessarily reduces the risk-free interest rate. And second, unless the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is low enough, it also reduces the capital-labor ratio, productivity, and wages.
The effect on the risk-free rate is an implication of the precautionary motive: a higher level of consumption for the government implies a lower aggregate level of wealth for the households, which is possible in steady state only with a lower interest rate. If investment was risk-free, a lower interest rate would immediately translate to a higher capital-labor ratio. But this is not the case in our model precisely because market incompleteness introduces a wedge between the risk-free rate and the marginal product of capital--this wedge is simply the risk premium on investment. Furthermore, because of diminishing absolute risk aversion, this wedge is higher the lower the wealth of the households. It follows that the negative wealth effect of higher government consumption raises the risk premium on investment and can thereby lead to a reduction in the capital-labor ratio, despite the reduction in the interest rate. We show that a sufficient condition for this to be the case is that the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is sufficiently high relative to the income share of capital--a condition easily satisfied for plausible calibrations of the model.
Turning to employment and output, there are two opposing effects. On the one hand, as with complete markets, the negative wealth effect on labor supply contributes towards higher employment and output. On the other hand, unlike complete markets, the reduction in capital intensity, productivity, and wages contributes towards lower employment and output. Depending on the income and wage elasticities of labor supply, either of the two effects can dominate.
The deviation from the standard paradigm is significant, not only qualitatively, but also quantitatively. For our preferred parametrizations of the model, the following hold. First, the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is comfortably above the critical value that suffices for an increase in government consumption to reduce the long-run levels of the capital-labor ratio, productivity, and wages. Second, a 1% increase in government spending under incomplete markets has the same impact on capital intensity and labor productivity as a 0.5%-0.6% increase in capital-income taxation under complete markets. Third, these effects mitigate, but do not fully offset, the wealth effect on labor supply. Finally, the welfare consequences are non-trivial: the welfare cost of a permanent 1% increase in government consumption is three times larger under incomplete markets than under complete markets.
The main contribution of the paper is thus to highlight how wealth effects on investment due to financial frictions can significantly modify the supply-side channel of fiscal policy. In our model, these wealth effects emerge from idiosyncratic risk along with diminishing absolute risk aversion; in other models, they could emerge from borrowing constraints. Also, such wealth effects are relevant for both neoclassical and Keynesian models. In this paper we follow the neoclassical tradition because this clarifies best our contribution: whereas wealth effects have been central to the neoclassical approach with regard to labor supply, they have been mute with regard to investment.
To the best of our knowledge, this paper is the first to study the macroeconomic effects of government consumption in an incomplete-markets version of the neoclassical growth paradigm that allows for uninsurable investment risk. A related, but different, exercise is conducted in Heathcote (2005) and Challe and Ragot (2007). These papers study deviations from Ricardian equivalence in Bewley-type models like Aiyagari's (1994), where borrowing constraints limit the ability of agents to smooth consumption intertemporally. In our paper, instead, deviations from Ricardian equivalence are not an issue: our model allows households to freely trade a riskless bond, thus ensuring that the timing of taxes and the level of debt has no effect on allocations, and instead focuses on wealth effects on investment due to incomplete risk sharing.
The particular framework we employ in this paper is a continuous-time variant of the one introduced in Angeletos (2007). That paper showed how idiosyncratic capital-income risk can be accommodated within the neoclassical growth model without loss of tractability, studied the impact of this risk on aggregate saving, and contrasted it with the impact of labor-income risk in Bewley-type models (Aiyagari, 1994; Huggett, 1997; Krusell and Smith, 1998). Other papers that introduce idiosyncratic investment or entrepreneurial risk in the neoclassical growth model include Angeletos and Calvet (2005, 2006), Buera and Shin (2007), Caggeti and De Nardi (2006), Covas (2006), and Meh and Quadrini (2006).3 The novelty of our paper is to study the implications for fiscal policy in such an environment.
Panousi (2008) studies the macroeconomic effects of capital taxation within a similar environment as ours. That paper shows that, when agents face idiosyncratic investment risk, an increase in capital taxation may paradoxically stimulate more investment in general equilibrium. This provides yet another example of how the introduction of idiosyncratic investment risk can upset some important results of the neoclassical growth model.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the basic model, which fixes labor supply so as to focus on the most novel results of the paper. Section 3 characterizes its equilibrium and Section 4 analyzes its steady state. Section 5 examines the steady-state effects of government consumption on the interest rate and capital accumulation. Section 6 considers three extensions that endogenize labor supply. Section 7 examines the dynamic response of the economy to a permanent change in government consumption. Section 8 concludes. All the formal results are explained in the main text; but the complete proofs are delegated to the Online Appendix.
Time is continuous, indexed by . There is a continuum of infinitely-lived households, indexed by and distributed uniformly over . Each household is endowed with one unit of labor, which it supplies inelastically in a competitive labor market. Each household also owns and runs a firm, which employs labor in the competitive labor market but can only use the capital stock invested by the particular household.4 Households cannot invest in other households' firms and cannot otherwise diversify away from the shocks hitting their firms, but can freely trade a riskless bond. Finally, all uncertainty is purely idiosyncratic, and hence all aggregates are deterministic.
The financial wealth of household , denoted by , is the sum of its holdings in private capital, , and the riskless bond, :
(2) |
Whereas the sequences of prices and taxes are deterministic (due to the absence of aggregate risk), firm profits, and hence household capital income, are subject to undiversified idiosyncratic risk. In particular:
(3) |
Turning to preferences, we assume an Epstein-Zin specification with constant elasticity of intertemporal substitution (CEIS) and constant relative risk aversion (CRRA). Given a consumption process, the utility process is defined by the solution to the following integral equation:
Standard expected utility is nested with . We find it useful to allow in order to clarify that the qualitative properties of the steady state depend crucially on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution rather than the coefficient of relative risk aversion (which in turn also guides our preferred parameterizations of the model). However, none of our results rely on allowing . A reader who feels uncomfortable with the Epstein-Zin specification can therefore ignore it, assume instead standard expected utility, and simply replace with (or vice versa) in all the formulas that follow.
The government consumes output at the rate . Government spending is deterministic, it is financed with lump-sum taxation, and it does not affect either the household's utility from private consumption or the production of the economy. The government budget constraint is given by:
(6) |
The initial position of the economy is given by the cross-sectional distribution of . Households choose plans , contingent on the history of their idiosyncratic shocks, and given the price sequence and the government policy, so as to maximize their lifetime utility. Idiosyncratic risk, however, washes out in the aggregate. We thus define an equilibrium as a deterministic sequence of prices , policies , and macroeconomic variables , along with a collection of individual contingent plans , such that the following conditions hold: (i) given the sequences of prices and policies, the plans are optimal for the households; (ii) the labor market clears, , in all ; (iii) the bond market clears, , in all ; (iv) the government budget is satisfied in all ; and (v) the aggregates are consistent with individual behavior, , , and , in all . (Throughout, we let denote the mean in the cross-section of the population.)
In this section we characterize the equilibrium of the economy. We first solve for a household's optimal plan for given sequences of prices and policies. We then aggregate across households and derive the general-equilibrium dynamics.
Since employment is chosen after the capital stock has been installed and the idiosyncratic shock has been observed, optimal employment maximizes profits state by state. By constant returns to scale, optimal firm employment and profits are linear in own capital:
and | (7) |
and |
The key result here is that households face risky, but linear, returns to their capital. To see how this translates to linearity of wealth in assets, let denote the present discounted value of future labor income net of taxes, a.k.a. human wealth:
The linearity of budgets, together with the homotheticity of preferences, ensures that, for given prices and policies, the household's consumption-saving problem reduces to a tractable homothetic problem as in Samuelson's and Merton's classic portfolio analysis. It then follows that the optimal policy rules are linear in wealth, as shown in the next proposition.
Condition simply says that the fraction of wealth invested in the risky asset is increasing in the risk premium and decreasing in risk aversion and the amount of risk . Condition (13) is essentially the Euler condition: it describes the growth rate of the marginal propensity to consume as a function of the anticipated path of risk-adjusted returns to saving. Whether higher risk-adjusted returns increase or reduce the marginal propensity to consume depends on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. To see this more clearly, note that in steady state this condition reduces to so that higher decreases if and only if that is, a higher risk-adjusted return to saving increases the fraction of savings out of effective wealth if and only if the EIS is higher than one. This is due to the familiar tension between the income and substitution effects implied by an increase in the rate of return.
Because individual consumption, saving and investment are linear in individual wealth, aggregates at any point in time do not depend on the extent of wealth inequality at that time. As a result, the aggregate equilibrium dynamics can be described with a low-dimensional recursive system.
Define as the production function in intensive form (output per work hour). From Proposition , the equilibrium ratio of capital to effective wealth and the equilibrium risk-adjusted return to savings are identical across agents and can be expressed as functions of the current capital stock and risk-free rate: and , where
This system has a simple interpretation. Condition is the resource constraint of the economy; it follows from aggregating budgets across all households and the government, imposing labor- and bond-market clearing, and using the linearity of individual firm employment to individual capital together with constant returns to scale, to get . Condition is the aggregate Euler condition for the economy; it follows from aggregating consumption and wealth across agents, together with the optimality condition for the marginal propensity to consume. Condition expresses the evolution of the present value of aggregate net-of-taxes labor income in recursive form; it follows from the definition of human wealth combined with the intertemporal government budget, which imposes that the present value of taxes equals the present value of government consumption. Finally, condition represents market-clearig in the bond market; more precisely, it follows from aggregating bond holdings and investment across agents to get and , using the latter to replace in the former, and imposing .
This system characterizes the equilibrium dynamics of the economy under both complete and incomplete markets. In particular, conditions (14), (16) and (17) are exactly the same under either market structure; the key differences between complete and incomplete markets rest in the Euler condition (15) and in the relation between the risk-adjusted return , the risk-free rate and the marginal product of capital .
When (complete markets), arbitrage imposes that and the Euler condition reduces to its familiar complete-market version, . When instead (incomplete markets), there are two important changes. First, the precautionary motive for saving introduces a positive drift in consumption growth, represented by the term in the Euler condition (15). And second, the fact that investment is subject to undiversifiable idiosyncratic risk introduces a wedge between the risk-free rate and the marginal product of capital, so that . It is worth noting here that the first effect is also shared by Aiyagari (1994) and other Bewley-type models that consider labor-income risk, whereas the second effect relies on the presence of capital-income risk.
Finally note that condition (17) can be solved for as a function of the contemporaneous , so that the equilibrium dynamics of the economy reduce to a simple three-dimensional ODE system in Indeed, the equilibrium dynamics can be approximated with a simple shooting algorithm, similar to the one applied to the complete-markets neoclassical growth model. For any historically given guess some initial values and use conditions to compute the entire path of for , for some large then iterate on the initial guess till is close enough to its steady-state value.7 In the special case of a unit EIS (), we have that and hence for all . One can then drop the Euler condition from the dynamic system and analyze the equilibrium dynamics with a simple phase diagram in the space, much alike in a textbook exposition of the neoclassical growth model. Either way, this is a significant gain in tractability relative to other incomplete-markets models, where the entire wealth distribution--an infinite dimensional object--is usually a relevant state variable for aggregate equilibrium dynamics. As in Angeletos (2007), the key is that individual policy rules are linear in individual wealth, so that aggregate dynamics are invariant to the wealth distribution.
We henceforth parameterize government spending as a fraction of aggregate output to study the steady state of the economy, that is, the fixed point of the dynamic system in Proposition 2. We now show that this can be characterized as the solution to a system of two equations in and .
First, note that the growth rate of consumption must be zero in steady state. Setting into the Euler condition (15) gives:
Second, note that the growth rate of human wealth from (16) must also be zero in steady state. From this we get that:
In any steady state, the capital stock and the risk-free rate must jointly solve equations and . In the Appendix we further show that a solution to this system exists and is unique. We thus reach the following result.
To understand the determination of the steady state of our model and its relation to its complete-markets counterpart, note first that condition imposes . That is, the risk-adjusted return to saving must be lower than the discount rate. In particular, must be low enough just to offset the precautionary motive for saving. If the risk-adjusted return were higher than this critical level, consumption (and wealth) would increase over time without bound, which would be a contradiction of steady state. Conversely, if the risk-adjusted return were lower than this level, consumption (and wealth) would shrink to zero, which would once again be a contradiction of steady state. Combining this with the fact that , we infer that the risk-free rate is also lower than the discount rate: . At the same time, because , it is unclear whether the marginal product of capital is higher or lower than the discount rate. Using these observations, along with the fact that the complete-markets steady state features , we conclude that incomplete markets necessarily reduce the risk-free rate but can have an ambiguous effect on the capital stock. In simple words, the precautionary motive guarantees that the interest rate is lower under incomplete markets than under complete markets, but this does not necessarily translate to a higher capital stock, because investment risk introduces a wedge between the marginal product of capital and the interest rate.
A graphical representation of the steady state helps appreciate further this tension between the precautionary motive and the risk premium in our model (and will also facilitate the comparative statics of the steady state). Let and denote the functions defined by solving, respectively, equations and for as functions of . We discuss the properties of these functions in what follows and illustrate them in Figure 1.8
Consider first the curve . When , condition reduces to . The complete-markets counterpart of is therefore given by a standard curve for the marginal product of capital, represented by curve in Figure 1. The positive risk premium introduced on investment when implies that curve lies uniformly below curve . Indeed, the distance between the two curves measures the risk premium, as captured by the right-hand side of . Clearly, the latter is decreasing in : the higher the risk-free rate, the lower the risk premium in steady state. To understand the intuition behind this property, take for a moment the interest rate to be exogenously given. Then, an increase in would lead to an increase in the steady-state level of wealth. Because of diminishing absolute risk aversion, the increase in wealth would stimulate capital accumulation. However, because of diminishing returns to capital accumulation, the ratio of capital to wealth, i.e. the fraction , would fall. But then the risk premium, which is given by , would also fall. And because wealth explodes as , while remains bounded, it follows that the risk premium must vanish as . These observations explain why the distance between the two curves indeed falls monotonically with , and vanishes as .
To recap, there are two important economic effects behind curve . On the one hand, a higher raises the opportunity cost of capital. This effect, which is present under both complete and incomplete markets, tends to discourage investment. On the other hand, a higher is possible in steady state under incomplete markets only if aggregate wealth is higher in that steady state. This wealth effect, which is present only under incomplete markets, tends to encourage investment. Moreover, from condition it is immediate that is U-shaped, as illustrated in Figure 1. Therefore, the opportunity-cost effect must be dominating for low , while the wealth effect must be dominating for high .9
Let's now turn to the curve . The complete-markets counterpart of is the vertical line at : as , converges to this vertical line, whereas for any , lies to the left of this vertical line. In Lemma 1 in the Appendix we show that is monotonically decreasing in , with as and as .10 The intuition for the monotonicity of is simple. For given , and hence given , an increase in reduces both and and thereby necessarily reduces the right-hand side of . But then, for to hold with the lower , it must be that also falls, which explains why is decreasing.
Since and are continuous in , and using their limiting properties from above, it is then clear that the two curves intersect at least once at some . But, as already mentioned, we further show in the Appendix that this intersection is in fact unique. The incomplete-markets steady state of our model is thus represented by point IM in Figure 1, while its complete-markets counterpart is represented by point CM. For the particular economy we have considered in this figure, the steady-state capital stock is lower under incomplete markets than under complete markets. However, the opposite could also be true. Clearly, a sufficient condition for the steady-state capital stock to be lower than under complete markets is that the two curves intersect on the upward portion of , or that the wealth effect on investment due to risk aversion dominates the usual opportunity cost effect. The following proposition identifies a condition that is both necessary and sufficient for the capital stock to be lower than under complete markets.
This result, which was first reported in Angeletos (2007), highlights how augmenting the neoclassical growth model for idiosyncratic capital-income risk can lead to lower aggregate saving, and thereby to lower aggregate output and consumption than under complete markets. This result stands in contrast to Aiyagari (1994), which documents how labor-income risk raises aggregate saving.11 We refer the interested reader to that earlier work for a more extensive discussion and quantification of this result. In the remainder of our paper, we focus on the effects of government spending, which is our main question of interest.
In this section we study how the steady state changes when the rate of government consumption increases. The analysis will make clear that the different impact that government spending has in our model as compared to the standard paradigm originates precisely from the wealth effects that idiosyncratic risk introduces in the demand for investment.
To study the long-run effects of an increase in the level of government consumption, we again use a graphical representation of the steady state, namely Figure 2, which is a variant of Figure 1.
Let the initial level of government spending be and suppose that the corresponding steady state is given by point in Figure 2. Subsequently, let government spending increase to . Note that condition does not depend on , and hence an increase in government consumption does not affect the curve. Rather, it is condition , and the curve, that depend on . In particular, because a higher means lower net-of-taxes labor income, and hence a lower in steady state for any given , an increase in government consumption causes the curve to shift leftwards, as illustrated in Figure 2. This leftward shift is a manifestation of the negative wealth effect of higher lump-sum taxes on investment.
The new steady state is then represented by point . Clearly, the leftward shift in the curve leads unambiguously to a decrease in . The impact on , on the other hand, is ambiguous. This is because, as explained in the previous section, a reduction in entails two opposing effects on the demand for investment: the familiar opportunity-cost channel tends to encourage investment, while the novel wealth channel of our model tends to discourage investment. As evident from the figure, if the two curves intersect on the upward portion of the curve, that is, in the portion where the wealth effect dominates, then the increase in leads to a reduction in . In the Appendix we show that the intersection occurs in the upward portion of the curve if and only if . Finally, it is easy to check that .12 We thus reach the the following result.
This is the key theoretical result of our paper. It establishes that, as long as the EIS is sufficiently high relative to the income share of capital, a permanent increase in the rate of government consumption has a negative long-run effect on both the interest rate and the capital intensity of the economy.
It is important to appreciate how this result deviates from the standard neoclassical paradigm. With complete markets, in steady state the interest rate is equal to the discount rate , and the capital-labor ratio is determined by the equality of the marginal product of capital to the discount rate . It follows that, in the long run, government consumption has no effect on either or and This is true even when labor supply, , is endogenous.13 The only difference is that, with endogenous labor supply, changes with . In particular, when labor supply is fixed, the increase in government consumption simply leads to a one-to-one decrease in private consumption. When instead labor supply is elastic, the increase in government consumption has a negative wealth effect, inducing agents to work more. The capital stock then increases one-to-one with labor supply, so as to keep the the capital-labor ratio and the interest rate invariant with .
In our model, instead, government consumption has non-trivial long-run effects on both the interest rate and the capital intensity of the economy. Building on the earlier discussions, we can now summarize the key mechanism in our model as follows. Because households face consumption risk, they have a precautionary motive to save. Because preferences exhibit diminishing absolute risk aversion, this motive is stronger when the level of wealth is lower. It follows that, by reducing household wealth, higher government spending stimulates precautionary saving. But then, the risk-free rate at which aggregate saving can be stationary has to be lower, which explains why the risk-free rate falls with At the same time, because of diminishing absolute risk aversion, the reduction in wealth tends to discourage the demand for investment. Provided that the positive effect of the lower opportunity cost of investment is not strong enough to offset this negative wealth effect, the capital-labor ratio also falls with
For empirically plausible calibrations of the model, the critical condition appears to be satisfied quite easily. For example, take the interest rate to be R=4% and labor income to be 65% of GDP (as in US data). This implies that H is about 16 times GDP. With a capital-output ratio of 4 (again as in US data), this translates to an H of about 4 times K. Since in steady state this exercise gives a calibrated value for of about 0.25. This critical value is lower than most of the recent empirical estimates of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, which are in most cases above 0.5 and often even above 1.14 Hence, a negative long-run effect of government consumption on aggregate saving and productivity appears to be the most likely scenario.
In the remainder of this section, we make a first pass at the potential quantitative importance of our results within the context of our baseline model. In the next section we then turn to an enriched version of the model that allows for endogenous labor supply, as well as a certain type of agent heterogeneity.
The economy is fully parameterized by , where is the income share of capital, is the discount rate, is the coefficient of relative risk aversion, is the (mean) depreciation rate, is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, is the standard deviation of the rate of return on private investment, and is the share of government consumption in aggregate output.
In our baseline parametrization, we take , =0.042, and =0.08; these values are standard in the literature. For risk aversion, we take =5, a value commonly used in the macro-finance literature to help generate plausible risk premia. For the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, we take =1, a value consistent with recent micro and macro estimates.15 For the share of government, our baseline value is g=25% (as in the United States) and a higher alternative is g=40% (as in some European countries).
What remains is . Unfortunately, there is no direct measure of the rate-of-return risk faced by the "typical" investor in the US economy. However, there are various indications that investment risks are significant. For instance, the probability that a privately held firm survives five years after entry is less than 40%. Furthermore, even conditional on survival, the risks faced by entrepreneurs and private investors appear to be very large: as Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen (2002) document, not only is there a dramatic cross-sectional variation in the returns to private equity, but also the volatility of the book value of a (value-weighted) index of private firms is twice as large as that of the index of public firms--one more indication that private equity is more risky than public equity. Note then that the standard deviation of annual returns is about 15% per annum for the entire pool of public firms; it is over 50% for a single public firm (which gives a measure of firm-specific risk); and it is about 40% for a portfolio of the smallest public firms (which are likely to be similar to large private firms).
Given this suggestive evidence, and lacking any better alternative, we let =30% for our baseline parameterization and consider =20% and =40% for sensitivity analysis. Although these numbers are somewhat arbitrary, it is reassuring that the volatility of individual consumption generated by our model is comparable to its empirical counterpart. For instance, using the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX), Malloy, Moskowitz and Vissing-Jørgensen (2006) estimate the standard deviation of consumption growth to be about 8% for stockholders (and about 3% for non-stockholders). Similarly, using data that include consumption of luxury goods, Aït-Sahalia, Parker and Yogo (2001) get estimates between 6% and 15%. In our simulations, on the other hand, the standard deviation of individual consumption growth is less than 5% per annum (along the steady state).
Putting aside these qualifications about the parametrization of we now examine the quantitative effects of government consumption on the steady state of the economy. Table 1 reports the per-cent reduction in the steady-state values of the capital-labor ratio labor productivity and the saving rate , relative to what their values would have been if were 0.16 Complete markets are indicated by CM and incomplete markets by IM.
: CM | : IM | : CM | : IM | : CM | : IM | : CM | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
baseline | |||||||
0 | -12.18 | 0 | -4.57 | 0 | -1.21 | 20 | |
0 | -6.78 | 0 | -2.5 | 0 | -0.88 | 12 | |
0 | -17.82 | 0 | -6.82 | 0 | -2.05 | 28 |
In our baseline parametrization, the capital-labor ratio is about 10% lower when g=25% than when Similarly, productivity is about 4% lower and the saving rate is about 1 percentage point lower. These are significant effects. They are larger (in absolute value) than the steady-state effects of precautionary saving reported in Aiyagari (1994). They are equivalent to what would be the steady-state effects of a marginal tax on capital income equal to 17% in the complete-markets case. (The tax rate on capital income that would generate the same effects under complete markets is given in the last column of the table, as .)
Not surprisingly, the effects are smaller if is lower (third row) or if is lower (not reported), because then risk matters less. On the other hand, the effects are larger when g=40% (final row): productivity is almost 18% lower, the saving rate is 2 percentage points lower, and the tax on capital income that would have generated the same effects under complete markets is 28%.
Table 2 turns from level to marginal effects: it reports the change in and as we increase government spending by 1 percent, either from to , or from to . In the first case, productivity falls by ; in the second, by . This is equivalent to what would have been, under complete markets, the effect of increasing the tax rate on capital income by about 0.75 percentage points in the first case, and about 0.8 percentage points in the second case.
: CM | : IM | : CM | : IM | : CM | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 | -0.52 | 0 | -0.19 | 0.75 | |
0 | -0.71 | 0 | -0.26 | 0.8 |
In this section we endogenize labor supply in the economy. We consider three alternative specifications that achieve this goal without compromising the tractability of the model.
One easy way to accommodate endogenous labor supply in the model is to assume preferences that rule out income effects on labor supply, as in Greenwood, Hercowitz and Huffman (1998). In particular, suppose that preferences are given by with
This specification highlights an important difference between complete and incomplete markets with regard to the employment impact of fiscal shocks. Under incomplete markets, an increase in government spending can have a negative general-equilibrium effect on aggregate employment. This is never possible with complete markets, but it is possible with incomplete markets when an increase in reduces the capital-labor ratio, and thereby the wage rate, which in turn discourages labor supply. Indeed, with GHH preferences, suffices for both and to fall with in both the short run and the long run.
Although it is unlikely that wealth effects on labor supply are zero in the long run, they may well be very weak in the short run. In light of our results, one may then expect that after a positive shock to government consumption both employment and investment could drop on impact under incomplete markets. Indeed, an interesting extension would be to consider a preference specification that allows for weak short-run but strong long-run wealth effects on labor supply, as in Jaimovich and Rebelo (2006).
A second tractable way to accommodate endogenous labor supply is to assume that agents have homothetic preferences over consumption and leisure, as in King, Plosser, and Rebelo (1988). The specification assumed in that paper is with
The benefit of this specification is that it is standard in the literature (making our results comparable to previously reported results), while it also comes with zero cost in tractability.18 The homotheticity of the household's optimization problem is then preserved and the equilibrium analysis proceeds in a similar fashion as in the benchmark model.19 The only essential novelty is that aggregate employment is now given by , where
For the quantitative version of this economy, we take . This value, which is in line with King, Plosser, and Rebelo (1988) and Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992), ensures that the steady-state fraction of available time worked approximately matches US data. The rest of the parameters are as in the baseline specification of the benchmark model.
A third approach is to split the population into two groups. The first group consists of the households that have been modeled in the benchmark model; we will call this group the "investors". The second group consists of households that supply labor but do not hold any assets, and simply consume their entire labor income at each point in time; we will call this group the "hand-to-mouth workers". Their labor supply is given by
(23) |
This approach could be justified on its own merit. In the United States, a significant fraction of the population holds no assets, has limited ability to borrow, and sees its consumption tracking its income almost one-to-one. This fact calls for a richer model of heterogeneity than our benchmark model. But is unclear what the "right" model for these households is. Our specification with hand-to-mouth workers is a crude way of capturing this form of heterogeneity in the model, while preserving tractability.
A side benefit of this approach is that it also gives freedom in parameterizing the wage and wealth elasticities of labor supply. Whereas the KPR preference specification imposes , the specification introduced above permits us to pick much lower elasticities, consistent with micro evidence. The point is not to argue which parametrization of the labor-supply elasticities is more appropriate for quantitative exercises within the neoclassical growth model; this is the subject of a long debate in the literature, to which we have nothing to add. The point here is rather to cover a broader spectrum of empirically plausible quantitative results.
For the quantitative version of this economy, we thus take and , which are in the middle of most micro estimates.21 What then remains is the fraction of aggregate income absorbed by hand-to-mouth workers. As mentioned above, a significant fraction of the US population holds no assets. For example, using data from both the PSID and the SCF, Guvenen (2006) reports that the lower of the wealth distribution owns only of aggregate wealth and accounts for about of aggregate consumption. Since some households may be able to smooth consumption even when their net worth is zero, is likely to be an upper bound for the fraction of aggregate consumption accounted for by hand-to-mouth agents. We thus opt to calibrate the economy so that hand-to-mouth agents account for of aggregate consumption. This is also the value of the relevant parameter that one would estimate if the model were to match US aggregate consumption data--we can deduce this from Campbell and Mankiw (1989).22
Our main theoretical result (Proposition 5) continues to hold in all of the above variants of the benchmark model: in steady state, a higher rate of government consumption necessarily reduces the interest rate and it also reduces the capital-labor ratio labor productivity and the wage rate if and only if the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is higher than .23
What is not clear anymore is the effect of on and , because now is not fixed. On the one hand, the reduction in wealth stimulates labor supply, thus contributing to an increase in . This is the familiar neoclassical effect of government spending on labor supply. On the other hand, as long as , the reduction in capital intensity depresses real wages, contributing towards a reduction in . This is the novel general-equilibrium effect due to incomplete markets. The overall effect of government spending on aggregate employment is therefore ambiguous under incomplete markets, whereas it is unambiguously positive under complete markets.
Other things equal, we expect the negative general-equilibrium effect to dominate, thus leading to a reduction in long-run employment after a permanent increase in government spending, if the wage elasticity of labor supply is sufficiently high relative to its income elasticity. This is clear in the GHH specification, where the wealth effect is zero. It can also be verified for the case of hand-to-mouth workers, where we have freedom in choosing these elasticities, but not in the case of KPR preferences, where both elasticities are restricted to equal one.
Given these theoretical ambiguities, we now seek to get a sense of empirically plausible quantitative effects. As already discussed, the GHH case (zero wealth effects on labor supply) is merely of pedagogical value. We thus focus on the parameterized versions of the other two cases, the economy with KPR (homothetic) preferences and the economy with hand-to-mouth workers.
Table 3 then presents the marginal effects on the steady-state levels of the capital-labor ratio, productivity, employment, and output for each of these two economies, as increases from to , or from to .24 The case of KPR preferences is indicated by KPR, while the case with hand-to-mouth workers is indicated by HTM. In either case, complete markets are indicated by CM and incomplete markets by IM.
: CM | : IM | : CM | : IM | : CM | : IM | : CM | : IM | : CM | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
: KPR | 0 | -0.33 | 0 | -0.12 | 1.4 | 1.27 | 1.4 | 1.15 | 0.52 |
: HTM |
0 | -0.3 | 0 | -0.11 | 0.38 | 0.38 | 0.38 | 0.27 | 0.46 |
: KPR | 0 | -0.52 | 0 | -0.19 | 1.76 | 1.53 | 1.76 | 1.34 | 0.68 |
: HTM |
0 | -0.36 | 0 | -0.13 | 0.57 | 0.57 | 0.57 | 0.44 | 0.48 |
Regardless of specification, the marginal effects of higher government spending on capital intensity and labor productivity are negative under incomplete markets (and are stronger the higher is ), whereas they are zero under complete markets. As for aggregate employment the wealth effect of higher turns out to dominate the effect of lower wages under incomplete markets, so that increases with higher under either complete or incomplete markets. However, the employment stimulus is weaker under incomplete markets, especially in the economy with hand-to-mouth workers. The same is true for aggregate output: it increases under either incomplete or complete markets, but less so under incomplete markets. Finally, the incomplete-markets effects are on average equivalent to what would have been the effect of increasing the tax rate on capital income by about under complete markets.
The results so far indicate that the long-run effects of government consumption can be significantly affected by incomplete risk sharing. We now examine how incomplete risk sharing affects the entire impulse response of the economy to a fiscal shock.25
Starting from the steady state with , we hit the economy with a permanent 1% increase in government spending and trace its transition to the new steady state (the one with ). We conduct this experiment for both the economy with KPR preferences and the economy with hand-to-mouth workers, each parameterized as in the previous section; in either case, the transitional dynamics reduce to a simple system of two first-order ODE's in when .26
The results are presented in Figures 3 and 4. Time in years is on the horizontal axis, while deviations of the macro variables from their respective initial values are on the vertical axis. The interest rate and the investment rate are in simple differences, the rest of the variables are in log differences. The solid lines indicate incomplete markets, the dashed lines indicate complete markets.
Figure 3. Dynamic responses to a permanent shock with KPR preferences.As evident in these figures, the quantitative effects of a permanent fiscal shock can be quite different between complete and incomplete markets. The overall picture that emerges is that the employment and output stimulus of a permanent increase in government spending is weaker under incomplete markets than under complete markets. And whereas we already knew this for the long-run response of the economy, now we see that the same is true for its short-run response.
This picture holds for both the economy with KPR preferences and the one with hand-to-mouth workers. But there are also some interesting differences between the two. The mitigating effect of incomplete markets on the employment and output stimulus of government spending is much stronger in the economy with hand-to-mouth workers. As a result, whereas the short-run effects of higher government spending on the investment rate and the interest are positive under complete markets in both economies, and whereas these effects remain positive under incomplete markets in the economy with KPR preferences, they turn negative under incomplete markets in the economy with hand-to-mouth workers.
To understand this result, consider for a moment the benchmark model, where there are no hand-to-mouth workers and labor supply is completely inelastic. Under complete markets, a permanent change in government spending would be absorbed one-to-one in private consumption, leaving investment and interest rates completely unaffected in both the short- and the long-run. Under incomplete markets, instead, investment and the interest rate would fall on impact, as well as in the long run. Allowing labor supply to increase in response to the fiscal shock ensures that investment and the interest rate jump upwards under complete markets. However, as long as the response of labor supply is weak enough, the response of investment and the interest rate can remain negative under incomplete markets.
As a final point of interest, we calculate the welfare cost, in terms of consumption equivalent, associated with a permanent 1% increase in government spending. Under complete markets, welfare drops by , whereas under incomplete markets it drops by . In other words, the welfare cost of an increase in government spending is three times higher under incomplete markets than under complete markets.27
To recap, the quantitative results indicate that a modest level of idiosyncratic investment risk can have a non-trivial impact on previously reported quantitative evaluations of fiscal policy. Note in particular that our quantitative economy with KPR preferences is directly comparable to two classics in the related literature, Aiyagari, Christiano and Eichenbaum (1992) and Baxter and King (1993). Therefore, further investigating the macroeconomic effects of fiscal shocks in richer quantitative models with financial frictions appears to be a promising direction for future research.
This paper revisited the macroeconomic effects of government consumption within a tractable incomplete-markets variant of the neoclassical growth model. Because private investment is subject to uninsurable idiosyncratic risk and because risk-taking is sensitive to wealth, the aggregate level of investment depends on the aggregate level of net-of-taxes household wealth for any given prices. It follows that an increase in government spending can crowd-out private investment simply by reducing household net worth. As a result, market incompleteness can seriously upset the supply-side effects of fiscal shocks: an increase in government consumption, even if financed with lump-sum taxation, tends to reduce capital intensity, labor productivity, and wages in both the short-run and the long-run. For plausible parameterizations of the model, these results appear to have not only qualitative, but also quantitative content.
These results might, or might not, be bad news for the ability of the neoclassical paradigm to explain the available evidence regarding the macroeconomic effects of fiscal shocks.28 However, the goal of this paper was not to study whether our model could match the data. Rather, the goal was to identify an important mechanism through which incomplete markets modify the response of the economy to fiscal shocks: wealth effects on investment.
In our model, these wealth effects originated from uninsured idiosyncratic investment risk combined with diminishing absolute risk aversion. Borrowing constraints could lead to similar sensitivity of investment to wealth (or cash flow).29 Also, this mechanism need not depend on whether prices are flexible (as in the neoclassical paradigm) or sticky (as in the Keynesian paradigm). The key insights of this paper are thus clearly more general than the specific model we employed--but the quantitative importance of these insights within richer models of the macroeconomy is, of course, a widely open question.
An important aspect left outside our analysis is the optimal financing of government expenditures. In this paper, we assumed that the increase in government spending is financed with lump-sum taxation, only because we wished to isolate wealth effects from the distortionary and redistributive effects of taxation. Suppose, however, that the government has access to two tax instruments, a lump-sun tax and a proportional income tax.30Clearly, with complete markets (and no inequality) it would be optimal to finance any exogenous increase in government spending with only lump-sum taxes. With incomplete markets, however, it is likely that an increase in government spending is financed with a mixture of both instruments: while using only the lump-sum tax would disproportionately affect the utility of poor agents, using both instruments permits the government to trade off less efficiency for more equality. Further exploring these issues, and the nature of optimal taxation for the class of economies we have studied here, is left for future research.
Proof of Proposition 1 (individual policy rules). Let denote the value function for the household's problem. The value function depends on time because of discounting as well as because the price sequence need not be stationary. However, the value function does not depend on , because households have identical preferences, they have access to the same technology, and they face the same sequence of prices and the same stochastic process for idiosyncratic risk. The Bellman equation that characterizes the value function is given by:
Because of the CRRA/CEIS specification of preferences, an educated guess is that there exists a deterministic process such that:
Proof of Proposition 2 (equilibrium dynamics). Since aggregate labor demand is and aggregate labor supply is 1, the labor market clears if and only if It follows that the equilibrium wage satisfies and, similarly, the equilibrium mean return to capital satisfies The bond market, on the other hand, clears if and only if . Combining this with gives condition (17).
Combining the intertemporal government budget with the definition of human wealth, we get
(30) |
Let denote the mean return to total saving. Aggregating the household budgets gives Combining this with (16) and with , we get that Using , we get Together with the fact, in equilibrium, this gives condition (14), the resource constraint.
Finally, using and therefore together with and , gives condition , the aggregate Euler condition.
Proof of Proposition 3 (steady state). First, we derive the two equations characterizing the steady state and . In steady state, the Euler condition gives
Next, we prove existence and uniqueness of the steady state. Let and denote, respectively, the risk premium and the fraction of effective wealth held in capital, when is given by (19):
and |
Fix henceforth, and consider the limits of as and Note that is finite and hence both and are finite. It follows that
If we now show that is strictly decreasing in , then we also have uniqueness. To show this, note that, from (32),
Proof of Proposition 4 (incomplete vs complete markets). Since , wealth stationarity requires . Combining this with the Euler equation in steady state, we get
For any , satisfies the following properties: for all ; is decreasing in and vanishes as ; and, finally, if and only if which in turn is true if and only if is sufficiently high.
For any , always; as , as .
For any as , and (That is, the curve converges to the curve, while the curve converges to the vertical line at .)
Proof of Lemma 1. From it is clear that under complete markets, whereas under incomplete markets. Hence, for any given , steady-state under incomplete markets is lower than under complete markets, which means that lies below for every . Since , it is clear that , i.e. the distance between and , is decreasing in , and that it tends to zero as . Finally, recall that is equivalent to
Proof of Proposition 5 (steady-state impact of government spending). From (32), we have that Together with the property that this implies that the steady-state necessarily decreases with The impact of on the steady-state then follows from the fact that defined by (19), does not depend on and is increasing in if and only if is higher than