Keywords: Predictive regressions, long horizons, confidence intervals, small sample problems, persistence
Abstract:
Asset returns are widely thought to be somewhat forecastable, and perhaps more so at long than at short horizons. But inference in long-horizon predictive regressions is well known to be complicated by severe econometric problems in empirically relevant sample sizes. The problems arise because the predictors that are used are variables like the dividend yield or term spread that are highly persistent, while the regressor is an overlapping sum of short-term returns. This creates something akin to a spurious regression. This is compounded by the feedback effect, or absence of strict exogeneity--a shock to returns will in turn affect future values of the predictors. As a result, conventional t-statistics have rejection rates that are well above their nominal levels. The vast literature on the problems with long-horizon predictive regressions includes work such as Goetzmann and Jorion (1993), Elliott and Stock (1994), Stambaugh (1999), Valkanov (2003) and Campbell and Yogo (2006).
Hodrick (1992) proposed an approach to test the null hypothesis that a certain predictor does not help forecast long-horizon returns. His idea was instead of regressing the cumulative -period returns onto the predictor at the start of the holding period, to regress the one-period return onto the average of the predictors over the previous periods. Under stationarity, for the coefficient in the first projection to be equal to zero is necessary and sufficient for the coefficient in the second projection to be equal to zero. However, the second regression has a persistent right-hand-side variable, but not a persistent left-hand side variable. Intuitively, this might mean that the size distortions of a test based on the second regression are much smaller. Hodrick finds that this is indeed the case. This approach to inference has become fairly widely used.
However, many researchers believe that there is some time series predictability in asset returns, even after controlling for econometric problems (see for example Campbell (2000)). The contribution of this paper is to show that a methodology related to the reverse-regression can be used more widely, to test any hypothesis about the parameter vector in a long-horizon regression, not just that it is equal to zero. A confidence set for the parameter vector can then be formed by inverting the acceptance region of the test. The proposed confidence set is asymptotically equivalent to the conventional estimation of the predictive regression. However, we show that it has substantially better small-sample properties.
The approach to inference proposed here applies regardless of whether there is a single predictor or multiple predictors. That is an advantage of this approach to inference relative to some others that have been proposed, such as the method of Campbell and Yogo (2006) that applies only for a scalar predictor.
The plan for the remainder of the paper is as follows. Section 2 describes long-horizon regressions and the proposed approach to inference. Section 3 assesses the small sample performance of the methodology in a Monte-Carlo simulation. Section 4 contains an empirical application to forecasting excess stock and bond returns. Section 5 concludes.
2. The Methodology
Let denote the continuously compounded return from to and let
denote the -period return. Let
be some x1 vector of predictors. Assume that
is covariance-stationary and that
where is a lag polynomial with all roots outside the
unit circle and
is a martingale difference sequence with finite moments for
some . Consider the long-horizon predictive regression
Consider also the reverse regression of the one-period return on the -period average of the regressor:
This paper proposes methods for inference on beyond just testing that it is equal to zero. The proposed approach is asymptotically equivalent to Wald tests/confidence sets for in equation (1), but turns out to have better small sample properties. The idea is that from equation (3), under covariance-stationarity, and so inference about from the reverse regression can be used for inference on , taking account of the distribution of the s. Since , we only need to adjust the numerator of the reverse regression, as
We now describe concretely how to use (4) for inference on . First let
and
. Also let
and
be the sample counterparts where
and
. We have
and assume that
Two approaches to inference on can be considered. The first uses the delta method as is a nonlinear function of that is itself root-T consistently estimable and asymptotically normal. Define an estimator of as
However, the delta method can provide a poor approximation to the ratio of two random variables in small samples. This observation led Fieller (1954) to propose an alternative approach to inference on the ratio of two random variables. This method is based on inverting the acceptance region of a
hypothesis test of a linear hypothesis that does not require any delta method approximation. This approach can be adapted here noting that
In the case, the computation of this confidence interval does not require evaluating a test statistic at each point in a grid of values of because the confidence set for is
Theorem 1 shows that the two proposed confidence sets are asymptotically equivalent to each other (for any , which in turn means that they are both asymptotically equivalent to the conventional Wald confidence sets formed from estimating equation (1).
Theorem 1: The two proposed test statistics are asymptotically equivalent.
Proof. The delta-method tests the hypothesized value using the test statistic:
Implementation of the proposed confidence intervals requires choosing a specific estimator of , the spectral density matrix of . We use a Newey-West estimator with lag length equal to .
We now turn to assessing how the proposed methods work in practice. The methods are referred to as "reverse regression" estimates even though they do not require explicit estimation of equation (2) because they are both based on assessing the covariance between one-period returns and the -period mean of the predictor.
3. Monte-Carlo simulation.
The proposed approaches to inference are both asymptotically equivalent to conventional Wald tests and confidence intervals. The motivation for considering them is that they may work better in small samples. Like the conventional methods, their justification is based on an assumption of stationarity, and methods that assume stationarity often fare poorly in the presence of a unit root, or a near unit root, at least in empirically relevant sample sizes. But the proposed methods might in practice be quite robust to near non-stationarity. The intuition is that they back out the implied coefficient in the long-horizon regression from the correlation between one-period returns and a long-run average of the predictor. How well the proposed methods actually work in finite samples with nearly non-stationary predictors is the key practical question that we answer in a Monte-Carlo experiment.
In this experiment, returns and the predictor follow a VAR(1):
After some algebra, the slope coefficient in the long-horizon regression is
The proposed confidence intervals are based on an assumption of stationarity, while the matrix has roots very close to unity. Nonetheless, while the Fieller confidence interval can have coverage that is somewhat below the nominal level, in no case is it less than 86 percent, and in most cases it is above 90 percent. The delta method consistently has modestly lower effective coverage, but it still always has effective coverage of at least 80 percent, and usually a good bit more. The comparison of the coverage rates leads us to prefer the Fieller interval, even though it is a little more complicated to compute and the improvement is small.
For the Newey-West confidence intervals, the effective coverage is much lower. It is generally around 80-85 percent at a horizon , and falls as the horizon increases, and is around 70 percent at a horizon of 48 months. Using Hodrick standard errors 1B gives good coverage if is small, but can work very poorly if is large. This is not surprising given that these standard errors are only justified under the null of no predictability.
Table 2 repeats this exercise, with a sample size of T=1,000. All of the confidence intervals have coverage that is closer to the nominal level than in the smaller sample size; the relative coverage of the different methods is about the same. In this larger sample size, the proposed Fieller confidence intervals always have coverage over 90 percent, while the coverage rates of the delta method confidence intervals are just slightly lower. Meanwhile, confidence intervals based on estimating equation (1) with Newey-West standard errors or Hodrick standard errors 1B can have coverage rates below 80 and 60 percent, respectively.
Although in this Monte-Carlo simulation, we know the true value of , in practice, of course, the researcher does not know the true value of this parameter and so it is important that the coverage of a confidence interval be as close as possible to the nominal level uniformly in . In this regard, Tables 1 and 2 show that the proposed confidence intervals are more reliable than using either Newey-West standard errors or Hodrick standard errors 1B, because the coverage rates of intervals based on conventional standard errors are close to the nominal value only for some parts of the parameter space.
Coverage is of course not the only criterion for a confidence interval; precision matters too. The median width of the alternative confidence intervals is shown in Tables 3 and 4, for sample sizes of T=500 and T=1,000 respectively. The proposed confidence sets from the reverse regression are wider than those based on estimating equation (1) with Newey-West standard errors or Hodrick standard errors 1B. The Fieller confidence intervals are typically nearly twice as wide as those based on Newey-West standard errors and range from having the same width as Hodrick standard errors 1B to being more than twice as wide. The cases in which the proposed confidence intervals are particularly wide are, not surprisingly, also the cases in which the conventional confidence intervals have poor coverage. This is what one would expect, given that these are symmetric one-dimensional confidence intervals constructed around the parameter estimates.
4. Empirical Results.
We now apply this proposed methodology to two standard predictive regressions in finance; the prediction of excess stock returns using the dividend-yield and short-term interest rates and the prediction of excess bond returns using the term structure of interest rates.
4.1 Forecasting Excess Stock Returns
We first consider the regression of -month cumulative excess returns for the value-weighted dividend-inclusive CRSP index on the log dividend yield at the start of the holding period. The sample period is December 1952-December 2007. The horizons are 12, 24, and 36 months.
Coefficient estimates are shown in Table 5, along with Newey-West standard errors and Hodrick standard errors 1B. Judging from the Newey-West standard errors, the estimates of are significantly positive at all horizons, at least at the 10 percent level. Using the Hodrick standard errors, the estimate of is significant only at the 10 percent level and only at the horizon of 12 months.
There is thus marginal evidence of predictability in returns, and of course even where we cannot reject the hypothesis that , this does not rule out the possibility of some predictability of returns. This motivates testing a range of hypotheses, or equivalently forming a confidence interval for that should have coverage close to the nominal level uniformly in the parameter space. Our simulation results earlier indicate that the confidence intervals proposed in this paper come close to doing this, while the use of existing standard errors (Newey-West or Hodrick standard errors 1B) does not. Accordingly, Table 5 also shows the 95 percent confidence intervals for using both the delta method and Fieller variants of the proposed methodology. These are wider than one would get from conventional standard errors and also tend to be asymmetric around the OLS estimate of . For example, at the three-year horizon, the OLS estimate of is 0.55, the 95 percent confidence interval using Hodrick standard errors 1B would span from -0.37 to 1.47, but the Fieller confidence interval is from -0.95 to 1.39.
Following Ang and Bekaert (2007), we also considered the regression of -month cumulative excess stock returns on both the log dividend yield and the one-month interest rate (using the Fama-Bliss riskfree rate) as they and other authors find that predictability is substantially greater in this bivariate regression. A useful property of the proposed approach to inference is that it can accommodate multiple predictors. Table 6 reports the coefficient estimates from estimating equation (1) with both Newey-West standard errors and Hodrick standard errors 1B. The coefficients on the dividend yield and short-term interest rate are significantly positive and negative, respectively, at the horizon of one year. The significance goes down at longer horizons, especially when using Hodrick standard errors 1B. All of this is consistent with Ang and Bekaert (2007).
Figure 1 shows the confidence sets for formed by the methods proposed in this paper. The confidence sets are quite large and include values of both elements of that are far from zero. At the twelve-month horizon, the delta and Fieller variants of the proposed methods deliver very similar confidence sets. At longer horizons, they are notably different and the Fieller confidence set--that consistently gives the best coverage rates in the Monte-Carlo simulation--looks quite non-elliptical meaning that it cannot be close to any confidence set that is formed from a normal approximation to the distribution of any point estimate of .
4.2 Forecasting Excess Bond Returns with the Slope of the Yield Curve
Let be the price of an month zero-coupon bond in month ; the per annum continuously compounded yield on this bond is
. The excess return from buying this bond in month and selling it in month is, over the one-month risk-free rate is
A basic premise of term structure analysis is that today's yield curve can be used to forecast future yield curves and the excess returns on long bonds. For example, when the yield curve is steep, long-term bonds have high expected returns (Fama and Bliss (1987)). Accordingly, researchers
project excess returns onto the term structure of interest rates at the start of the holding period, running regressions of the form
We considered estimates of formed from estimating equation (9) with the long-term bond maturity, , ranging from 5 to 10 years and the holding period, , being 1, 2 or 3 years. End-of-month data on zero-coupon yields from the dataset of Gürkaynak, Sack and Wright (2007) were used, except that for the one-month yield, the Fama-Bliss risk-free rate from CRSP was used instead.
We first used the spread between the ten-year and one-month yield as the sole predictor, . Results are shown in Table 7, along with Newey-West standard errors and Hodrick standard errors 1B. Judging from these conventional standard errors, at the 12-month horizon, the estimates of are all significantly positive, at least at the 5 percent level. At longer horizons, the estimate of is not significant at the 5 percent level in the direct estimation of equation (9).
Table 7 also shows the proposed confidence intervals for ; both the delta method and Fieller variants. At the 12-month horizon, these are a bit wider than would be obtained from Newey-West standard errors or Hodrick standard errors 1B. In the case , the conventional confidence intervals do not span zero, while the proposed ones do. Judging from these results, there is virtually no evidence against the hypothesis that at longer horizons. However, there is no evidence against the hypothesis that takes on many nonzero values either, as the proposed confidence intervals are very wide. The proposed confidence intervals are much wider than those based on either Newey-West standard errors or Hodrick standard errors 1B, but neither of these comes close to controlling coverage uniformly in .
4.3 Forecasting Excess Bond Returns with the Term Structure of Forward Rates
In an influential paper, Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005) argued that while the slope of the yield curve has some predictive power for bond returns, using a combination of forward rates gives better forecasting performance, and that a "tent-shaped" function of forward rates has remarkable predictive ability for excess bond returns with R-squared values up to 44 percent.
Motivated by this finding, we estimated equation (9), using as the predictors the one-year yield, and the one-year forward rates ending in three and five years.4 Table 8 shows p-values from the conventional Wald test of the hypothesis that and using both the delta method and Fieller variants on the proposed approach to inference.
The Newey-West p-values indicate overwhelming significance at the shortest horizon of 12 months, and are also highly significant at the 24-month horizon. In contrast, Hodrick standard errors 1B and the proposed tests give p-values that are between 3 and 13 percent at the twelve-month horizon and are not significant at all at longer horizons. Thus, evidence for predictability of excess bond returns using forward rates is fairly marginal at the twelve month horizon and is nonexistent at longer horizons. This is based on just testing the hypothesis of no predictability and so does not require the use of the methods proposed in this paper, but it nonetheless is a finding of some interest, suggesting that the evidence that the tent-shaped factor helps forecast returns may not be nearly as strong as had been thought.5 What does require the methods proposed in this paper is testing other hypotheses about or forming confidence sets.
Confidence sets for when this vector contains more than two elements are hard to represent graphically. But for the delta method, the proposed point estimates for individual coefficients, given in equation (6), can be computed along with the associated delta-method standard errors. These are shown in Table 9 for . The point estimates do indeed show the "tent-shaped" pattern, with a high coefficient on the one-year forward rate ending three years hence and lower coefficients on the other two forward rates. The proposed point estimates are almost identical to the conventional OLS point estimates, but the proposed standard errors are much larger than their conventional counterparts. Overall, the exercise indicates that the coefficients in the regression considered by Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005) are far less precisely estimated than one might suppose from conventional inference approaches and indeed even their significance is in doubt.
5. Conclusion
We have proposed two related methods for inference in a long-horizon predictive regression in this paper. Both methods are based on assessing the covariance between one-period returns and a long-term average of the predictor, and so have a motivation that is similar to the reverse regression of Hodrick (1992). However, our proposal for inference allows us to test any hypothesis on the slope coefficient in the long-horizon predictive regression; not just to test that it is zero, as in Hodrick's paper. The acceptance region of this test can be represented as a confidence set for this slope coefficient.
In Monte-Carlo simulations we have demonstrated that the proposed methods control the effective coverage of confidence intervals (equivalently control the size of tests) fairly well, uniformly in the parameter space. In empirical applications, we find that any evidence for predictability of excess stock and bond returns is marginal. However, using our methodology we are also unable to reject the hypothesis that the coefficient in the predictive regression takes on specific nonzero values. We are left with confidence sets for the coefficients in canonical predictive regressions in finance that include zero in some, but not all cases, and that are quite different from the conventional confidence sets as they are wider and sometimes asymmetric around the OLS point estimate of the predictive regression.
Andrews, Donald W.K. (1991): Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation, Econometrica, 59, pp.817-858.
Ang, Andrew and Geert Bekaert (2007): Stock Return Predictability: Is it There? Review of Financial Studies, 20, pp.651-707.
Bekaert, Geert, Robert J. Hodrick and David Marshall (2001): Peso Problem Explanations for Term Structure Anomalies, Journal of Monetary Economics, 48, pp.241-270.
Campbell, John Y. (2000): Asset Pricing at the Millennium, Journal of Finance, 55, pp.1515-1567.
Campbell, John Y. (2001): Why Long Horizons? A Study of Power Against Persistent Alternatives, Journal of Empirical Finance, 9, pp.459-491.
Campbell, John Y. and Motohiro Yogo (2006): Efficient Tests of Stock Return Predictability, Journal of Financial Economics, 81, pp.27-60.
Cochrane, John H. and Monika Piazzesi (2005): Bond Risk Premia, American Economic Review, 95, pp.138-160.
Cochrane, John H. and Monika Piazzesi (2008), "Decomposing the Yield Curve," manuscript, University of Chicago.
Elliott, Graham and James H. Stock (1994): Inference in Time Series Regression When the Order of Integration of a Regressor is Unknown, Econometric Theory, 10, pp.672-700.
Fama, Eugene F. and Robert R. Bliss (1987): The Information in Long-Maturity Forward Rates, American Economic Review, 77, pp.680-692.
Fieller, Edgar C. (1960): Some Problems in Interval Estimation, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B, 16, pp.175-185.
Goetzmann, William and Philippe Jorion (1993): Testing the Predictive Power of Dividend Yields, Journal of Finance, 48, pp.663-679.
Gürkaynak, Refet S., Brian Sack and Jonathan H. Wright (2007): The U.S. Treasury Yield Curve: 1961 to the Present, Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, pp.2291-2304.
Hansen, Lars P. and Robert J. Hodrick (1980): Forward Exchange Rates as Optimal Predictors of Future Spot Rates: An Econometric Analysis, Journal of Political Economy, 88, pp.829-853.
Hodrick, Robert J. (1992): Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns: Alternative Procedures for Inference and Measurement, Review of Financial Studies, 5, pp.357-386.
Newey. Whitney K. and Kenneth D. West (1987): A Simple, Positive Definite, Heteroscedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix, Econometrica, 55, pp.703-708.
Stambaugh, Robert (1999): Predictive Regressions, Journal of Financial Economics, 54, pp.375-421.
Valkanov, Rossen (2003): Long-Horizon Regressions: Theoretical Results and Applications, Journal of Financial Economics, 68, pp.201-232.
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.93 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.96 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.96 | 0.99 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.92 | 0.91 | 0.92 | 0.94 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.84 | 0.85 | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.84 | 0.84 | 0.83 | 0.82 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.92 | 0.89 | 0.85 |
h=12: | 0.00 | 0.10 | 0.42 | 0.74 | 0.00 | 0.09 | 0.36 | 0.64 | 0.00 | 0.08 | 0.31 | 0.56 |
h=24: Proposed: Fieller | 0.92 | 0.95 | 0.99 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.97 | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.95 |
h=24: Proposed: Delta | 0.90 | 0.94 | 0.98 | 0.98 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.90 | 0.88 | 0.89 | 0.91 |
h=24: Newey-West | 0.80 | 0.82 | 0.84 | 0.83 | 0.82 | 0.83 | 0.81 | 0.80 | 0.81 | 0.79 | 0.78 | 0.77 |
h=24: Hodrick | 0.94 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.92 | 0.83 | 0.94 | 0.91 | 0.83 | 0.72 |
h=24: | 0.00 | 0.15 | 0.54 | 0.75 | 0.00 | 0.13 | 0.42 | 0.63 | 0.00 | 0.11 | 0.35 | 0.54 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.91 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.98 | 0.93 | 0.93 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.91 | 0.89 | 0.90 | 0.92 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.89 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.95 | 0.92 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.89 | 0.85 | 0.85 | 0.86 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.77 | 0.79 | 0.80 | 0.77 | 0.79 | 0.79 | 0.77 | 0.74 | 0.77 | 0.75 | 0.73 | 0.71 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.98 | 0.97 | 0.87 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.88 | 0.72 | 0.95 | 0.89 | 0.77 | 0.61 |
h=36: | 0.00 | 0.19 | 0.56 | 0.69 | 0.00 | 0.15 | 0.42 | 0.57 | 0.00 | 0.12 | 0.33 | 0.49 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.90 | 0.96 | 0.97 | 0.95 | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.90 | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.88 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.88 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.89 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.88 | 0.82 | 0.80 | 0.81 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.73 | 0.77 | 0.75 | 0.71 | 0.77 | 0.75 | 0.72 | 0.68 | 0.73 | 0.71 | 0.68 | 0.67 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.98 | 0.95 | 0.76 | 0.96 | 0.93 | 0.83 | 0.62 | 0.94 | 0.87 | 0.71 | 0.53 |
h=48: | 0.00 | 0.20 | 0.54 | 0.62 | 0.00 | 0.15 | 0.39 | 0.51 | 0.00 | 0.12 | 0.31 | 0.43 |
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.92 | 0.94 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.93 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.96 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.90 | 0.92 | 0.96 | 0.99 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.90 | 0.90 | 0.91 | 0.93 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.83 | 0.84 | 0.85 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.84 | 0.83 | 0.82 | 0.81 | 0.79 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.93 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.91 | 0.88 | 0.83 |
h=12: | 0.00 | 0.19 | 0.62 | 0.86 | 0.00 | 0.18 | 0.55 | 0.80 | 0.00 | 0.16 | 0.50 | 0.74 |
h=24:Proposed: Fieller | 0.91 | 0.96 | 0.99 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.92 | 0.91 | 0.92 | 0.95 |
h=24:Proposed: Delta | 0.89 | 0.94 | 0.98 | 0.98 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.89 | 0.87 | 0.88 | 0.91 |
h=24:Newey-West | 0.78 | 0.81 | 0.83 | 0.81 | 0.82 | 0.82 | 0.79 | 0.76 | 0.75 | 0.79 | 0.79 | 0.72 |
h=24:Hodrick | 0.94 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.90 | 0.80 | 0.94 | 0.98 | 0.96 | 0.81 |
h=24: | 0.00 | 0.31 | 0.74 | 0.87 | 0.00 | 0.27 | 0.63 | 0.79 | 0.00 | 0.39 | 0.76 | 0.83 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.91 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.98 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.91 | 0.89 | 0.90 | 0.92 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.87 | 0.96 | 0.97 | 0.95 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.87 | 0.83 | 0.83 | 0.86 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.75 | 0.79 | 0.79 | 0.72 | 0.79 | 0.78 | 0.73 | 0.69 | 0.75 | 0.71 | 0.68 | 0.65 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.94 | 0.98 | 0.96 | 0.81 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.84 | 0.64 | 0.94 | 0.86 | 0.70 | 0.53 |
h=36: | 0.00 | 0.39 | 0.76 | 0.83 | 0.00 | 0.31 | 0.64 | 0.75 | 0.00 | 0.26 | 0.55 | 0.69 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.90 | 0.97 | 0.97 | 0.96 | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.93 | 0.89 | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.89 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.87 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.88 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.79 | 0.79 | 0.82 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.71 | 0.76 | 0.73 | 0.65 | 0.75 | 0.73 | 0.67 | 0.62 | 0.71 | 0.66 | 0.62 | 0.60 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.94 | 0.98 | 0.92 | 0.65 | 0.95 | 0.92 | 0.77 | 0.53 | 0.94 | 0.83 | 0.62 | 0.44 |
h=48: | 0.00 | 0.43 | 0.74 | 0.78 | 0.00 | 0.34 | 0.62 | 0.71 | 0.00 | 0.27 | 0.53 | 0.65 |
Notes: This Table shows the simulated coverage of alternative confidence intervals for the coefficient in equation (1). The methods considered include confidence intervals from the reverse regression proposed in this paper. The delta-method and Fieller variants are labeled Proposed: Delta and Proposed: Fieller, respectively. Wald confidence intervals using the OLS estimates of equation (1) using Newey-West standard errors with a lag-truncation parameter of and using Hodrick standard errors 1B (only valid if are also considered. These are Newey-West and Hodrick. The simulation design is described in section 3. The row labeled 2 gives the population R-squared in the regression. All confidence intervals have a 95 percent nominal coverage rate.
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 1.00 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.98 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.93 | 0.93 | 0.95 | 0.97 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.87 | 0.87 | 0.88 | 0.89 | 0.88 | 0.88 | 0.87 | 0.87 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.86 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.93 | 0.91 | 0.88 |
h=12: | 0.00 | 0.10 | 0.42 | 0.74 | 0.00 | 0.09 | 0.36 | 0.64 | 0.00 | 0.08 | 0.31 | 0.56 |
h=24: Proposed: Fieller | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.99 | 1.00 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 |
h=24: Proposed: Delta | 0.92 | 0.95 | 0.99 | 1.00 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.94 | 0.96 |
h=24: Newey-West | 0.85 | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.85 | 0.84 | 0.84 | 0.83 |
h=24: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.96 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.92 | 0.86 | 0.94 | 0.91 | 0.85 | 0.76 |
h=24: | 0.00 | 0.15 | 0.54 | 0.75 | 0.00 | 0.13 | 0.42 | 0.63 | 0.00 | 0.11 | 0.35 | 0.54 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.93 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.93 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.96 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.92 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.92 | 0.91 | 0.92 | 0.94 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.83 | 0.84 | 0.86 | 0.84 | 0.84 | 0.84 | 0.83 | 0.82 | 0.83 | 0.82 | 0.81 | 0.81 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.97 | 0.89 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.89 | 0.76 | 0.95 | 0.89 | 0.80 | 0.66 |
h=36: | 0.00 | 0.19 | 0.56 | 0.69 | 0.00 | 0.15 | 0.42 | 0.57 | 0.00 | 0.12 | 0.33 | 0.49 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.93 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.98 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.97 | 0.93 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.95 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.91 | 0.96 | 0.97 | 0.97 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.91 | 0.89 | 0.90 | 0.92 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.82 | 0.83 | 0.83 | 0.81 | 0.83 | 0.82 | 0.81 | 0.80 | 0.82 | 0.80 | 0.79 | 0.79 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.98 | 0.96 | 0.80 | 0.95 | 0.93 | 0.85 | 0.67 | 0.95 | 0.88 | 0.75 | 0.58 |
h=48: | 0.00 | 0.20 | 0.54 | 0.62 | 0.00 | 0.15 | 0.39 | 0.51 | 0.00 | 0.12 | 0.31 | 0.43 |
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.97 | 1.00 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.97 | 1.00 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.93 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.97 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.86 | 0.87 | 0.88 | 0.89 | 0.88 | 0.88 | 0.87 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.85 | 0.84 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.96 | 0.94 | 0.92 | 0.90 | 0.88 |
h=12: | 0.00 | 0.19 | 0.62 | 0.86 | 0.00 | 0.18 | 0.55 | 0.80 | 0.00 | 0.16 | 0.50 | 0.74 |
h=24: Proposed: Fieller | 0.93 | 0.96 | 0.99 | 1.00 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.98 |
h=24: Proposed: Delta | 0.92 | 0.95 | 0.99 | 1.00 | 0.93 | 0.94 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.91 | 0.91 | 0.94 | 0.96 |
h=24: Newey-West | 0.84 | 0.85 | 0.87 | 0.86 | 0.85 | 0.85 | 0.85 | 0.83 | 0.84 | 0.82 | 0.81 | 0.81 |
h=24: Hodrick | 0.94 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.96 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.92 | 0.85 | 0.94 | 0.90 | 0.83 | 0.75 |
h=24: | 0.00 | 0.31 | 0.74 | 0.87 | 0.00 | 0.27 | 0.63 | 0.79 | 0.00 | 0.39 | 0.76 | 0.83 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.93 | 0.97 | 0.99 | 1.00 | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.95 | 0.97 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.91 | 0.96 | 0.99 | 0.99 | 0.92 | 0.94 | 0.96 | 0.97 | 0.90 | 0.90 | 0.93 | 0.95 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.82 | 0.84 | 0.85 | 0.82 | 0.84 | 0.84 | 0.82 | 0.80 | 0.82 | 0.80 | 0.79 | 0.78 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.95 | 0.98 | 0.97 | 0.86 | 0.95 | 0.94 | 0.87 | 0.73 | 0.94 | 0.88 | 0.76 | 0.63 |
h=36: | 0.00 | 0.39 | 0.76 | 0.83 | 0.00 | 0.31 | 0.64 | 0.75 | 0.00 | 0.26 | 0.55 | 0.69 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.92 | 0.98 | 0.99 | 0.99 | 0.94 | 0.95 | 0.97 | 0.97 | 0.92 | 0.92 | 0.94 | 0.96 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.90 | 0.97 | 0.98 | 0.97 | 0.92 | 0.93 | 0.95 | 0.95 | 0.90 | 0.88 | 0.91 | 0.93 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.80 | 0.83 | 0.82 | 0.78 | 0.82 | 0.81 | 0.79 | 0.77 | 0.80 | 0.78 | 0.76 | 0.76 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.94 | 0.98 | 0.94 | 0.74 | 0.95 | 0.93 | 0.81 | 0.62 | 0.94 | 0.85 | 0.70 | 0.54 |
h=48: | 0.00 | 0.43 | 0.74 | 0.78 | 0.00 | 0.34 | 0.62 | 0.71 | 0.00 | 0.27 | 0.53 | 0.65 |
Notes: As for Table 1, except that the sample size is 1,000.
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.040 | 0.038 | 0.041 | 0.053 | 0.040 | 0.041 | 0.046 | 0.061 | 0.040 | 0.043 | 0.051 | 0.068 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.037 | 0.036 | 0.038 | 0.049 | 0.037 | 0.038 | 0.043 | 0.057 | 0.037 | 0.040 | 0.047 | 0.063 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.030 | 0.029 | 0.027 | 0.027 | 0.030 | 0.030 | 0.031 | 0.034 | 0.030 | 0.032 | 0.035 | 0.041 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.040 | 0.040 | 0.041 | 0.045 | 0.040 | 0.040 | 0.041 | 0.045 | 0.040 | 0.040 | 0.041 | 0.044 |
h=24: Proposed: Fieller | 0.038 | 0.038 | 0.047 | 0.075 | 0.038 | 0.041 | 0.053 | 0.082 | 0.038 | 0.043 | 0.058 | 0.089 |
h=24: Proposed: Delta | 0.034 | 0.034 | 0.042 | 0.067 | 0.034 | 0.037 | 0.047 | 0.074 | 0.034 | 0.039 | 0.052 | 0.079 |
h=24: Newey-West | 0.026 | 0.024 | 0.024 | 0.029 | 0.027 | 0.027 | 0.030 | 0.039 | 0.026 | 0.029 | 0.035 | 0.047 |
h=24: Hodrick | 0.038 | 0.039 | 0.040 | 0.043 | 0.038 | 0.038 | 0.039 | 0.042 | 0.038 | 0.038 | 0.039 | 0.042 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.036 | 0.037 | 0.051 | 0.087 | 0.036 | 0.040 | 0.056 | 0.094 | 0.036 | 0.043 | 0.061 | 0.099 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.031 | 0.032 | 0.044 | 0.076 | 0.032 | 0.035 | 0.049 | 0.081 | 0.031 | 0.037 | 0.053 | 0.086 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.024 | 0.021 | 0.022 | 0.033 | 0.024 | 0.025 | 0.030 | 0.043 | 0.024 | 0.027 | 0.035 | 0.050 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.037 | 0.037 | 0.038 | 0.041 | 0.037 | 0.037 | 0.038 | 0.040 | 0.037 | 0.037 | 0.037 | 0.040 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.034 | 0.035 | 0.052 | 0.091 | 0.034 | 0.039 | 0.057 | 0.097 | 0.034 | 0.041 | 0.061 | 0.102 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.029 | 0.030 | 0.044 | 0.078 | 0.029 | 0.033 | 0.049 | 0.083 | 0.029 | 0.035 | 0.052 | 0.087 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.021 | 0.019 | 0.022 | 0.035 | 0.021 | 0.023 | 0.029 | 0.045 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 0.034 | 0.052 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.035 | 0.035 | 0.036 | 0.039 | 0.035 | 0.035 | 0.036 | 0.038 | 0.035 | 0.035 | 0.036 | 0.038 |
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.033 | 0.032 | 0.035 | 0.046 | 0.033 | 0.034 | 0.039 | 0.053 | 0.033 | 0.036 | 0.043 | 0.059 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.031 | 0.030 | 0.032 | 0.043 | 0.031 | 0.032 | 0.037 | 0.050 | 0.031 | 0.034 | 0.040 | 0.055 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.025 | 0.024 | 0.023 | 0.022 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.026 | 0.029 | 0.025 | 0.026 | 0.029 | 0.034 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.033 | 0.034 | 0.035 | 0.040 | 0.033 | 0.033 | 0.035 | 0.039 | 0.033 | 0.033 | 0.034 | 0.038 |
h=24: Proposed: Fieller | 0.032 | 0.033 | 0.044 | 0.073 | 0.033 | 0.036 | 0.049 | 0.079 | 0.032 | 0.038 | 0.052 | 0.083 |
h=24: Proposed: Delta | 0.029 | 0.029 | 0.039 | 0.065 | 0.029 | 0.032 | 0.043 | 0.070 | 0.029 | 0.033 | 0.046 | 0.074 |
h=24: Newey-West | 0.022 | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.025 | 0.022 | 0.023 | 0.026 | 0.034 | 0.022 | 0.025 | 0.030 | 0.041 |
h=24: Hodrick | 0.033 | 0.033 | 0.034 | 0.038 | 0.033 | 0.033 | 0.034 | 0.038 | 0.033 | 0.033 | 0.034 | 0.037 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.031 | 0.034 | 0.051 | 0.092 | 0.032 | 0.037 | 0.056 | 0.097 | 0.031 | 0.038 | 0.059 | 0.100 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.027 | 0.029 | 0.044 | 0.079 | 0.027 | 0.031 | 0.048 | 0.083 | 0.027 | 0.033 | 0.050 | 0.086 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.020 | 0.018 | 0.020 | 0.031 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.026 | 0.039 | 0.020 | 0.024 | 0.031 | 0.046 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.032 | 0.032 | 0.034 | 0.037 | 0.032 | 0.032 | 0.033 | 0.036 | 0.032 | 0.032 | 0.033 | 0.036 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.030 | 0.034 | 0.056 | 0.104 | 0.031 | 0.037 | 0.060 | 0.107 | 0.030 | 0.038 | 0.063 | 0.111 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.025 | 0.029 | 0.047 | 0.087 | 0.026 | 0.031 | 0.050 | 0.090 | 0.025 | 0.032 | 0.053 | 0.093 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.018 | 0.016 | 0.020 | 0.035 | 0.018 | 0.020 | 0.027 | 0.043 | 0.018 | 0.022 | 0.032 | 0.050 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.031 | 0.032 | 0.033 | 0.036 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.032 | 0.035 | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.032 | 0.034 |
Notes: As for Table 1, except that here the median width of the confidence intervals is reported instead.
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.026 | 0.025 | 0.026 | 0.034 | 0.026 | 0.027 | 0.030 | 0.040 | 0.026 | 0.028 | 0.034 | 0.045 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.025 | 0.024 | 0.025 | 0.033 | 0.025 | 0.026 | 0.029 | 0.039 | 0.025 | 0.027 | 0.032 | 0.044 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.021 | 0.020 | 0.019 | 0.018 | 0.021 | 0.021 | 0.021 | 0.024 | 0.021 | 0.022 | 0.024 | 0.028 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.026 | 0.026 | 0.027 | 0.030 | 0.026 | 0.026 | 0.027 | 0.030 | 0.026 | 0.026 | 0.027 | 0.030 |
h=24: Proposed: Fieller | 0.025 | 0.024 | 0.030 | 0.050 | 0.025 | 0.027 | 0.035 | 0.056 | 0.025 | 0.029 | 0.039 | 0.061 |
h=24: Proposed: Delta | 0.023 | 0.023 | 0.029 | 0.047 | 0.023 | 0.025 | 0.033 | 0.053 | 0.023 | 0.027 | 0.037 | 0.058 |
h=24: Newey-West | 0.019 | 0.017 | 0.017 | 0.020 | 0.019 | 0.019 | 0.021 | 0.028 | 0.019 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 0.033 |
h=24: Hodrick | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.026 | 0.029 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.026 | 0.029 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.026 | 0.028 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.024 | 0.024 | 0.034 | 0.060 | 0.024 | 0.027 | 0.039 | 0.066 | 0.024 | 0.029 | 0.043 | 0.071 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.022 | 0.022 | 0.031 | 0.055 | 0.022 | 0.025 | 0.036 | 0.061 | 0.022 | 0.027 | 0.040 | 0.065 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.018 | 0.016 | 0.016 | 0.024 | 0.018 | 0.018 | 0.022 | 0.032 | 0.017 | 0.020 | 0.026 | 0.038 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.024 | 0.024 | 0.025 | 0.027 | 0.024 | 0.024 | 0.025 | 0.027 | 0.024 | 0.024 | 0.025 | 0.027 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.023 | 0.023 | 0.036 | 0.065 | 0.023 | 0.027 | 0.041 | 0.071 | 0.023 | 0.029 | 0.045 | 0.076 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.021 | 0.021 | 0.032 | 0.060 | 0.021 | 0.024 | 0.037 | 0.065 | 0.021 | 0.026 | 0.041 | 0.069 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.016 | 0.015 | 0.017 | 0.027 | 0.016 | 0.018 | 0.023 | 0.035 | 0.016 | 0.020 | 0.027 | 0.041 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.023 | 0.023 | 0.024 | 0.026 | 0.023 | 0.023 | 0.024 | 0.026 | 0.023 | 0.023 | 0.024 | 0.026 |
=0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | =0 | =0.02 | =0.05 | =0.1 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
h=12: Proposed: Fieller | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.028 | 0.021 | 0.021 | 0.024 | 0.033 | 0.020 | 0.022 | 0.027 | 0.037 |
h=12: Proposed: Delta | 0.020 | 0.019 | 0.020 | 0.027 | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.023 | 0.032 | 0.020 | 0.022 | 0.026 | 0.036 |
h=12: Newey-West | 0.016 | 0.015 | 0.015 | 0.014 | 0.016 | 0.016 | 0.017 | 0.019 | 0.016 | 0.017 | 0.019 | 0.022 |
h=12: Hodrick | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.022 | 0.026 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.022 | 0.025 | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.022 | 0.025 |
h=24: Proposed: Fieller | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.027 | 0.046 | 0.020 | 0.022 | 0.031 | 0.051 | 0.020 | 0.024 | 0.034 | 0.055 |
h=24: Proposed: Delta | 0.019 | 0.019 | 0.025 | 0.043 | 0.019 | 0.021 | 0.029 | 0.048 | 0.019 | 0.022 | 0.032 | 0.051 |
h=24: Newey-West | 0.015 | 0.014 | 0.013 | 0.017 | 0.015 | 0.015 | 0.017 | 0.023 | 0.015 | 0.017 | 0.020 | 0.028 |
h=24: Hodrick | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.024 |
h=36: Proposed: Fieller | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.033 | 0.061 | 0.020 | 0.023 | 0.037 | 0.065 | 0.019 | 0.025 | 0.040 | 0.069 |
h=36: Proposed: Delta | 0.018 | 0.019 | 0.030 | 0.056 | 0.018 | 0.021 | 0.034 | 0.060 | 0.018 | 0.023 | 0.037 | 0.063 |
h=36: Newey-West | 0.014 | 0.013 | 0.014 | 0.021 | 0.014 | 0.015 | 0.018 | 0.028 | 0.014 | 0.017 | 0.022 | 0.033 |
h=36: Hodrick | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.024 | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.024 | 0.020 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.024 |
h=48: Proposed: Fieller | 0.019 | 0.022 | 0.038 | 0.072 | 0.019 | 0.024 | 0.041 | 0.076 | 0.019 | 0.026 | 0.045 | 0.079 |
h=48: Proposed: Delta | 0.017 | 0.019 | 0.034 | 0.064 | 0.017 | 0.022 | 0.037 | 0.068 | 0.017 | 0.023 | 0.040 | 0.071 |
h=48: Newey-West | 0.013 | 0.012 | 0.014 | 0.026 | 0.013 | 0.015 | 0.020 | 0.032 | 0.013 | 0.017 | 0.023 | 0.037 |
h=48: Hodrick | 0.019 | 0.019 | 0.020 | 0.023 | 0.019 | 0.019 | 0.020 | 0.023 | 0.019 | 0.019 | 0.020 | 0.023 |
Notes: As for Table 3, except that the sample size is 1,000.
h=12 | h=24 | h=36 | |
---|---|---|---|
Coefficient (SE) | 0.826 | 0.683 | 0.548 |
Coefficient (SE) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.403) | (0.401) | (0.323) |
Coefficient (SE) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.475] | [0.470] | [0.468] |
Proposed CI: Fieller | (-0.232,1.763) | (-0.700,1.456) | (-0.945,1.391) |
Proposed CI: Delta | (-0.083,1.775) | (-0.392,1.464) | (-0.566,1.303) |
Notes: This table shows the estimated coefficients in regressions of excess -month cumulative CRSP value-weighted stock returns (relative to the one month rate) on the log dividend yield (divided by 100). Newey-West standard errors with truncation parameter are reported in round brackets and Hodrick standard errors 1B are given in square brackets. Both variants of the confidence intervals proposed in this paper (95 percent nominal coverage rate) are shown as well. The sample period is 1952:12-2007:12.
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Dividend-Yield | 1.14 |
---|---|
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.40) |
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.49] |
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Interest rate | -0.14 |
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.05) |
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.06] |
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Joint p-value: Newey-West | 0.003 |
Twelve-month horizon (h=12): Hodrick | 0.019 |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Dividend-Yield | 0.88 |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.40) |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.49] |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Interest rate | -0.08 |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.03) |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.06] |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Joint p-value: Newey-West | 0.037 |
Two-year horizon (h=24): Hodrick | 0.126 |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Dividend-Yield | 0.70 |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.29) |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.48] |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Interest rate | -0.07 |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.02) |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.05] |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Joint p-value: Newey-West | 0.0009 |
Three-year horizon (h=36): Hodrick | 0.232 |
Notes: As for Table 5, except that the predictive regressions are on both the log dividend yield and one-month interest rates. Point estimates for the long-horizon regression are shown, along with both Newey-West standard errors and Hodrick standard errors 1B, in round and square brackets respectively. The p-values testing the hypothesis that the coefficients on both predictors are jointly equal to zero are shown. The proposed confidence sets are shown graphically in Figure 1.
n=60 | n=72 | n=84 | n=96 | n=108 | n=120 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): (SE) | 0.126 | 0.155 | 0.183 | 0.212 | 0.240 | 0.268 |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.045) | (0.051) | (0.058) | (0.064) | (0.070) | (0.076) |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.073] | [0.083] | [0.093] | [0.103] | [0.112] | [0.122] |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Proposed CI: Fieller | (-0.007,0.254) | (0.004,0.303) | (0.015,0.351) | (0.026,0.399) | (0.037,0.448) | (0.047,0.496) |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Proposed CI: Delta | (-0.008,0.241) | (0.002,0.287) | (0.013,0.334) | (0.023,0.380) | (0.034,0.426) | (0.044,0.472) |
Two-year holding period (h=24): (SE) | 0.052 | 0.071 | 0.090 | 0.109 | 0.127 | 0.145 |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.052) | (0.059) | (0.066) | (0.073) | (0.079) | (0.086) |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.063] | [0.072] | [0.081] | [0.090] | [0.098] | [0.107] |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Proposed CI: Fieller | (-0.080,0.196) | (-0.079,0.240) | (-0.077,0.284) | (-0.075,0.329) | (-0.072,0.373) | (-0.070,0.418) |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Proposed CI: Delta | (-0.085,0.171) | (-0.087,0.209) | (-0.087,0.248) | (-0.087,0.287) | (-0.088,0.325) | (-0.088,0.364) |
Three-year holding period (h=36): (SE) | 0.017 | 0.030 | 0.043 | 0.056 | 0.069 | 0.081 |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Newey-West Standard Error | (0.033) | (0.036) | (0.039) | (0.042) | (0.045) | (0.048) |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Hodrick Standard Error | [0.055] | [0.063] | [0.071] | [0.080] | [0.087] | [0.095] |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Proposed CI: Fieller | (-0.086,0.112) | (-0.086,0.141) | (-0.084,0.170) | (-0.082,0.199) | (-0.079,0.228) | (-0.077,0.258) |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Proposed CI: Delta | (-0.084,0.100) | (-0.085,0.125) | (-0.084,0.151) | (-0.084,0.176) | (-0.083,0.202) | (-0.082,0.227) |
Notes: This table shows the estimated coefficients in regressions of excess -month cumulative -year bond returns (relative to the one month rate) on the 10-year less 1-month slope of the term structure. Newey-West standard errors with truncation parameter are reported in round brackets and Hodrick standard errors 1B are given in square brackets. Both variants of the confidence intervals proposed in this paper (95 percent nominal coverage) are shown as well.
n=60 | n=72 | n=84 | n=96 | n=108 | n=120 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Newey-West | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Hodrick | 0.031 | 0.031 | 0.032 | 0.033 | 0.035 | 0.037 |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Proposed: Fieller | 0.127 | 0.120 | 0.114 | 0.108 | 0.103 | 0.099 |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12): Delta | 0.047 | 0.042 | 0.038 | 0.035 | 0.032 | 0.030 |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Newey-West | 0.016 | 0.020 | 0.021 | 0.019 | 0.016 | 0.014 |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Hodrick | 0.177 | 0.198 | 0.210 | 0.216 | 0.218 | 0.217 |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Proposed: Fieller | 0.512 | 0.539 | 0.533 | 0.504 | 0.464 | 0.423 |
Two-year holding period (h=24): Delta | 0.320 | 0.360 | 0.375 | 0.373 | 0.361 | 0.344 |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Newey-West | 0.046 | 0.073 | 0.091 | 0.097 | 0.093 | 0.084 |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Hodrick | 0.466 | 0.508 | 0.522 | 0.517 | 0.500 | 0.478 |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Proposed: Fieller | 0.702 | 0.763 | 0.786 | 0.767 | 0.714 | 0.638 |
Three-year holding period (h=36): Delta | 0.446 | 0.570 | 0.650 | 0.678 | 0.665 | 0.628 |
Notes: This table shows p-values from alternative tests of the hypothesis that the slope coefficients are jointly equal to zero in the estimation of the long-horizon regression (equation (9)) when the predictors are the one-year forward rates ending one, three and five years hence.
Long-Horizon Regression | Proposed | |
---|---|---|
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) (SE) | -0.504 | -0.488 |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.133) | (0.210) |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.248] | |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) (SE) | 0.868 | 0.844 |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.344) | (0.574) |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.657] | |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) (SE) | -0.273 | -0.273 |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.270) | (0.460) |
Twelve-month holding period (h=12) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.574] | |
Two-year holding period (h=24) (SE) | -0.264 | |
Two-year holding period (h=24) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.150) | (0.229) |
Two-year holding period (h=24) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.217] | |
Two-year holding period (h=24) (SE) | 0.289 | 0.344 |
Two-year holding period (h=24) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.360) | (0.568) |
Two-year holding period (h=24) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.533] | |
Two-year holding period (h=24) (SE) | 0.072 | 0.005 |
Two-year holding period (h=24) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.254) | (0.434) |
Two-year holding period (h=24) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.404] | |
Three-year holding period (h=36) (SE) | -0.104 | -0.116 |
Three-year holding period (h=36) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.090) | (0.165) |
Three-year holding period (h=36) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.191] | |
Three-year holding period (h=36) (SE) | -0.026 | 0.076 |
Three-year holding period (h=36) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.251) | (0.367) |
Three-year holding period (h=36) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.465] | |
Three-year holding period (h=36) (SE) | 0.229 | 0.119 |
Three-year holding period (h=36) Newey-West Standard Error | (0.219) | (0.271) |
Three-year holding period (h=36) Hodrick Standard Error | [0.361] |
Notes: This table gives the OLS estimate of equation (9) when the excess return is the return on holding a ten-year bond and the predictors are the one-year forward rates ending one, three and five years hence. Newey-West and Hodrick standard errors 1B are shown in round and square brackets, respectively. The table also shows the point estimates and standard errors associated with the delta-method variant of the approach to inference proposed in this paper.
Notes: This shows the proposed confidence sets for the coefficients in regressions of excess -month cumulative CRSP value-weighted stock returns (relative to the one month rate) on the log dividend yield (divided by 100) and the short-term interest rate. The sample period is 1952:12-2007:12. The shaded region gives the Fieller variant of the proposed method; the black ellipses represent the delta method confidence sets.