Keywords: Plant size, productivity, trade, geographic concentration
Abstract:
There is wide variation in the sizes of manufacturing plants, even within the most narrowly defined industry classifications used by statistical agencies. Standard theories attribute all such size differences to productivity differences. This paper develops an alternative theory in which industries are made up of large plants producing standardized goods and small plants making custom or specialty goods. It uses confidential Census data to estimate the parameters of the model, including estimates of plant counts in the standardized and specialty segments by industry. The estimated model fits the data relatively well compared with estimates based on standard approaches. In particular, the predictions of the model for the impacts of a surge in imports from China are consistent with what happened to U.S. manufacturing industries that experienced such a surge over the period 1997-2007. Large-scale standardized plants were decimated, while small-scale specialty plants were relatively less impacted.
JEL Classification: F10, L11, L25, R12The sizes of manufacturing plants exhibit wide variation, even within the most narrowly defined industry classifications used by statistical agencies. For example, in the wood furniture industry in the United States (NAICS industry code 337122), one can find plants with over a thousand employees and other plants with as few as one or two employees. The dominant theory of such within-industry plant-size differentials models plants as varying in terms of productivity. (See Lucas (1978), Jovanovic (1982), and Hopenhayn (1992).) In this theory, some plants are lucky and draw high productivity at start-up, whereas others are unlucky and draw low productivity. The size distribution is driven entirely by the productivity distribution.
The approach has been extremely influential. It underpins recent developments in the international trade literature. Melitz (2003) and Bernard, Eaton, Jensen, and Kortum (2003, hereafter BEJK) use the approach to explain plant-level trade facts. In Melitz, plants with higher productivity draws have large domestic sales and also have the incentive to pay fixed costs to enter export markets. In this way, the Melitz model explains the fact--documented by Bernard and Jensen (1995)--that large plants within narrowly defined industries are more likely to be exporters than small plants. Relatedly, in BEJK, more productive plants have wider trade areas. Both the Melitz and the BEJK theories have a sharp implication about the impact of increased exposure to import competition on a domestic industry: the smaller plants in the industry--which are also the low productivity plants in the industry under these theories--are the first to exit.
In our view, the dominant approach to modeling plant-size differentials goes too far in attributing all variation in plant size within narrowly defined census industries to differences in productivity. It is likely that plants that are dramatically different in size are performing different functions, even if the Census Bureau happens to classify them in the same industry. Moreover, these differences in function may be systematic and may very well be directly related to how increased import competition would affect the plants.
Take wood furniture as an example. The large plants in this industry with more than a thousand employees are concentrated in North Carolina, particularly in a place called High Point. These plants make the stock bedroom and dining room furniture pieces found at traditional furniture stores. Also included in the Census classification are small facilities making custom pieces to order, such as small shops employing skilled Amish craftsmen. Let us apply the standard theory of the size distribution to this industry. Entrepreneurs that enter and draw high productivity parameters would likely open up megaplants in High Point, North Carolina; those that get low draws might open Amish shops in other locations. The Melitz model and the BEJK model both predict that the large North Carolina plants will have large market areas, while the small plants will tend to ship locally. So far so good, because this result is consistent with the data, as we will show. But what happens when China enters the wood furniture market in a dramatic fashion, as has occurred over the past 10 years? While all of the U.S. industry will be hurt, the Melitz and BEJK theories predict that the North Carolina industry will be relatively less affected because it is home to the large, productive plants. In fact, the opposite turns out to be true in the data.
To address this shortcoming, our theory takes into account that most industries have some segment that provides specialty goods, often custom-made goods, the provision of which is facilitated by face-to-face contact between buyers and sellers. This specialty segment is the province of small plants. Large plants tend to make standardized products. Here we follow the ideas of Piore and Sable (1984) and a subsequent literature distinguishing between the mass production of standardized products taking place in large plants and the craft production of specialty products taking place in small plants. When China enters the wood furniture market, naturally it follows its comparative advantage and enters the standardized segment of the market, making products similar to the stock furniture pieces produced in North Carolina. Thus, in our theory, the North Carolina industry is hurt the most by China's entry into the industry, as actually happened.
Our starting point is the Eaton and Kortum (2002) model of geography and trade as further developed in BEJK. In its basic form, plants in this model vary in productivity and location but are otherwise symmetric in terms of transportation costs and underlying consumer demand. We take this model "off the shelf" as our model of the standardized segment of an industry, and we fold in a simple model of a specialty segment. We explore two issues in the model. First, how is the size distribution of plants connected to the geographic distribution of plants (call this the plant size/geographic concentration relationship)? Second, if there is a surge in imports, what is the relative impact of the trade shock across locations that vary by geographic concentration and mean plant size?
We estimate the model separately for individual industries, using Census data that include survey information from the Commodity Flow Survey on the origins and destinations of shipments. The shipment information is critical for our analysis because it enables us to recover parameters related to the transportation cost structure in the BEJK framework.
We obtain four main empirical results. First, we estimate that in most industries, more than half of the plants in an industry can be classified as being in the specialty segment; the specialty segment dominates plant counts. Second, the pure BEJK model fails to quantitatively match the plant size/geographic concentration relationship, whereas the general model that includes the specialty segment fits this relationship well. For example, in High Point where the wood furniture industry concentrates, average plant size (as measured by sales revenue) is 6.6 times the national average. The pure BEJK model predicts a difference of only a factor 1.6, but the general model comes in quite close with a factor 6.9. The third empirical result concerns industries negatively affected by a surge of imports from China. We examine the period between the 1997 and 2007 Economic Census years. Our estimated pure BEJK model predicts that those locations with high industry concentration and high average plant size should have experienced a small increase in relative share of the domestic industry; e.g., High Point's market share in wood furniture should have risen relative to the rest of the country. Instead these areas experienced sharp declines over the period, consistent with our hypothesis. Indeed, we show that the High Point region went from having 14 wood furniture plants with more than 500 employees to only 3 plants. For our fourth empirical result, we use our general model and estimate the distribution of plant counts by standardized and specialty segments for 1997 and 2007 and analyze the changes over time. Consistent with our hypothesis, we find that those industries facing a surge of imports from China experienced a dramatic decline in the number of standardized plants. In these industries, standardized plants in 2007 numbered only about one-third of their 1997 level. In contrast, changes in counts of specialty segment plants were much less pronounced.
We find it particularly revealing to analyze what has happened in large metropolitan areas. Generally speaking, in recent decades large cities have not been home to huge manufacturing plants in the kinds of industries, like furniture and clothing, that China now dominates. In the United States, large plants in these industries have been concentrated in smaller, manufacturing-oriented areas like High Point. We show that over the period 1997 to 2007, in industries where exports from China have surged, the domestic industry has shifted toward large metropolitan areas, places where average plant size has typically been small. These are places where we expect to see a large demand for specialty and custom goods. And we also expect to find there a large supply of inputs suited for specialty and niche products. These are different from the low-skill inputs used in mass production of standardized products in large plants--inputs readily available in China and places like High Point. Our theory with a specialized-good sector can account for how import pressure from China shifts industries from places like High Point to places like New York City. Without the specialized-good segment in the model, the shift goes the other way. An interesting analogue to recent experience is found in an early case study of the garment industry circa 1960 (Hall, 1959). That study explained how large plants in places like North Carolina tended to mass-produce standardized garments like nurses' uniforms, while the small plants in New York City tended to produce fashion items. The new development is that China has entered to play the role of North Carolina, while New York still plays New York (albeit in a relative sense, given the overall decline of manufacturing as a share of the domestic economy).
There is an emerging new literature that allows for richer forms of heterogeneity across plants than the first generation of trade models with heterogeneous firms found in Melitz (2003) and BEJK. Hallak and Sivadasan (2009) allow plants to differ in the standard way regarding cost structure, but also along a second dimension in terms of a plant's ability to provide quality. Their theory can explain why smaller plants sometimes export more than larger plants. (This outcome can happen in their model if the smaller plant has sufficiently higher quality.) Bernard, Redding, and Schott (2010) develop a multi-product model of a firm with differences not only in overall firm productivity levels but also in the heterogeneity of product-specific attributes. Our paper is in the spirit of these papers in that it allows for richer heterogeneity. One difference is that we are adding heterogeneity within narrowly defined industries in the extent to which the goods being produced are tradable, with customized versions of goods being more difficult to trade. Holmes and Stevens (2004a) include a margin like this in a regional model linking plant size and geographic concentration. This paper is different from our earlier paper because it (1) uses BEJK to develop an entirely different modeling structure, (2) takes the model to the data and estimates its parameters, and (3) examines the impact of a trade shock.
The theory developed here is consistent with a variety of empirical findings in the literature. First, there is conflicting evidence in the trade literature on how tariff reductions affect domestic plant sizes. (See Head and Ries (1999).) When we take into account that plants vary in productivity as well as in function (with small plants specializing in specialty goods), we cannot tell a priori whether a given large plant will be more likely to survive a trade onslaught than a small plant. Second, the theory provides a new explanation for the well-known findings discussed earlier that exporters tend to be larger than other plants in the same narrowly defined industry. Third, the theory is consistent with the well-known fact that the size distribution of plants is highly skewed--there are many more small plants than large plants. The most prominent explanation in the literature for this skewness is the random growth theory. See Luttmer (2007) for a recent treatment. In this literature, a big plant is a lucky one that gets, say, "heads" 50 times in a row in a series of coin flips. This event is unlikely, of course, so big plants are rare. In our theory, the little plants are doing different things than the big plants. In particular, in providing a custom service that is hard to trade, there will need to be many such plants diffused across all local markets.1
The paper is related to the macroeconomics literature on quantitative dynamic models incorporating plant heterogeneity. This literature makes heavy use of the standard theory where size differences are driven entirely by productivity differences. Given a monotonic relationship between plant size and productivity, it is possible to invert the relationship and read off the distribution of plant productivities from the distribution of plant sizes. Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993) is an early example, Alessandria and Choi (2007) a recent example. To the extent plants of different sizes are doing different things, this strategy overstates productivity differences. The paper is also related to Buera and Kaboski (2008), which emphasizes how structural change impacts average plant size.
The first part of this section presents the model. The second part derives the analytic results.
There is a fixed set of locations, indexed by . Each location typically produces goods in a variety of industries. When we go to the data, we will take into account that industries differ in their model parameters. Here we describe the model in terms of a particular industry and leave implicit the industry index.
Consumers have Cobb-Douglas utility for industry composites. Assume is the spending share on the particular industry we are looking at. For this industry, let be the composite industry price index and be the composite industry quantity, at location . Given the Cobb-Douglas assumption, spending on the industry at the location equals
The industry has two segments, the standardized segment indexed by and the specialty segment indexed by (where can be remembered as "boutique"). The industry composite is made up of a standardized segment composite and a specialty (or boutique) segment composite in the usual CES way,
We use the BEJK model as our model of the standardized segment. There is a continuum of differentiated standard goods indexed by . For example, if the industry is the wood furniture industry, then specifies a particular kind of wood furniture, such as a kitchen table of a particular size, finish, shape, and kind of wood. The different standardized goods are aggregated to obtain the standardized segment composite in the usual CES way. Let be the elasticity of substitution, and let be the price of good at location . (For simplicity we leave the superscript implicit here, as the index only refers to tradable goods.) Then the expenditure at location for good equals
where is spending on the standardized segment composite at location and is the price index,As in BEJK, there are potential producers at each location with varying levels of technical efficiency. Let index the efficiency of the th most efficient producer of good located at . This index represents the amount of good made by this producer, per unit of input.
There is an "iceberg" cost to ship tradable segment goods across locations. Let be the amount of good that must be shipped to location from location in order to deliver one unit. There is no transportation cost for delivering to the location where the good is produced, i.e., . Otherwise, , for . Assume that the triangle inequality holds.
The distribution of efficiencies is determined as follows. Let denote a parameter governing the distribution of efficiency of the standard segment at location . Suppose the maximum efficiency is drawn according to
Eaton and Kortum (2002) show that for a given standard segment good , the probability that location is the lowest-cost producer to location is
(3) | ||
, |
BEJK consider a rich structure with multiple potential producers at each location who each get their own productivity draws. Then firms engage in Bertrand competition for consumers at each location. The equilibrium may feature limit pricing, where the lowest-cost producer matches the second-lowest-cost producer. Or the lowest cost may be so low relative to rivals' costs that the price is determined by the inverse elasticity rule for the optimal monopoly price. The very useful result of BEJK is that allowing for all of this does not matter. Conditional on a location landing a sale at (i.e., that location is the lowest-cost producer for ), the distribution of prices to is the same for all originations . This implies that the sales revenues from are allocated according to . That is, total sales revenue of origin to destination is
Like BEJK, we associate a plant with a particular good produced at . The measure of standardized-segment goods produced at equals , the measure of goods location sells to itself.2 We allow for a scaling factor , so that the number of standardized-segment plants at location is
We offer two ways to model the specialty segment. Conceptually, the two cases are very different. Yet for much of what we do in this paper, the results for the two cases are similar.
Our first case is the specialty-segment-as-nontradable-goods model. As an example of this case, consider the wood furniture industry. This industry includes plants that look like retail stores in a shopping center. A consumer can go into such an establishment and meet face-to-face with designers to come up with a design for a custom piece. When the furniture is actually made on the premises, the Census Bureau classifies the establishment as being a wood furniture manufacturer. This kind of specialty establishment is aimed at a local market, as consumers do not want to drive long distances to meet with a designer. For simplicity, we assume for this case that the transportation cost across locations is infinitely high precluding trade. For this first model, then, total sales by specialty-segment plants (also called boutique plants) at equal expenditure at ,
Our second case is the specialty-segment-as-high-end-niche model. For this, we go to the other extreme and treat the specialty goods as being perfectly tradable. The products have high value-to-weight ratios and--if face-to-face contact between buyer and seller is not important--transportation costs are then immaterial. The price for these goods is the same at all locations . The amount of high-end niche activity at a location depends on the supply of factors specific to the segment at the location. We think of this as creative talent or artisanship that is likely unrelated to the factor determining suitability for standardized goods. The total value of production at depends implicitly on the supply of creativity. Again, assume that average plant revenue volume is constant at across locations with inverse . The number of specialty plants at origin then equals
This high-end-niche model of the specialty segment can be regarded as the limiting case of the BEJK model, where transportation cost is zero (or ). As we will see below, average plant size is constant across locations in this limiting case of BEJK. In particular, as comparative advantage increases, the resulting expansion of output is met entirely on the extensive margin of more plants.3
We limit ourselves to these two extreme cases for technical tractability. We expect that in many cases the specialty-good sector will be some combination of these two extreme cases. That is, it will have a hard-to-trade element (because face-to-face contact between the buyer and the producer is desirable) and a high-end fashion element (because comparative advantage for the segment depends upon supply factors such as creative talent, which is different from the supply factors used to produce standardized goods).
This subsection uses the model to examine two issues. First, how is average plant size at a location related to the concentration of industry at a location? Second, what is the effect of an import surge on the distribution of domestic production? We begin the analysis by discussing what happens with only standardized goods. Then we discuss how adding the specialty segment affects the results.
To relate average size to industry concentration, we use the location quotient at to measure industry concentration at . Recall that is the total sales revenue of producers located at and is the total expenditure of consumers located at . Letting and be the aggregate totals, the revenue location quotient is a location's share of sales revenue (i.e., production) over its share of expenditure (i.e., consumption),
Following Holmes and Stevens (2002), we can think of a location as having two margins over which it can specialize in an industry: the extensive margin of more plants and the intensive margin of higher average plant size. To highlight these two margins, we decompose the revenue location quotient as the product of a count quotient and a size quotient,
(8) | ||
, | (9) |
For now, suppose there is only a standardized-good segment so the model reduces to an off-the-shelf BEJK model. For the benchmark case with no transportation costs we have the following proposition.
Proposition 1. With only standardized goods and no transportation costs ( all ), then for all so average plant size (in sales volume) is identical at all locations. All variation in is through the extensive margin .
Proof. With for all , the probability that serves in (2) reduces to
which is independent of destination . From BEJK this also equals the sales share at each location. So average plant size (in sales revenue) at each location isFollowing the intuition about the Eaton-Kortum setup in Alvarez and Lucas (2007), the productivity at a location has an interpretation of being a function of the first-order statistic of draws from the exponential distribution. A location with productivity twice as high as another location can be interpreted as having twice as many underlying draws. With zero transportation costs, it is intuitive that a location with twice as many underlying draws will produce twice as many products.
When transportation cost is positive, the BEJK model delivers differences in average plant size across locations. Analytical results are difficult to come by, but some basic patterns can be readily discerned with numerical examples. Table 1 illustrates a numerical example with two locations. For all the parameters considered, is a factor four times larger than , so location 2 specializes in the industry to a substantial degree. We consider three possibilities for the expenditure distribution: in the first, expenditure is equal across the two locations; in the second it is three times higher in location 2; in the third it is three times higher in location 1. We also vary the distance adjustment parameter . For different levels of , we back out what the ratio must be that would result in the given values of and , and then calculate the corresponding and .
We start by discussing the equal expenditure case and for this case the targets are and . As is decreased as we move down the table (so the distance adjustment becomes more important), the productivity advantage of location 2 must be increased to hold constant the net trade between the two locations (i.e. to keep ). At the limiting case where , average size is the same in both places, , consistent with Proposition 1. For this limiting case, the expansion in revenue at location 2 comes entirely through the count margin, . As is decreased, average size in location 2 increases, so both the size margin and the count margin play a role. But even as shrinks to extreme levels (and the implied goes to extreme levels), the establishment count margin is always greater than the size margin. This result holds more generally in other numerical examples with . This discussion gives a sense of how the BEJK model has trouble accounting for large differences in average plant size across locations, particularly if transportation costs are relatively small.
If expenditure is larger in location 2 and if trade is sufficiently difficult, the size margin will be significant. It is intuitive that when trade is difficult in the BEJK model, plants in locations with high local expenditure will tend to be big, as most sales are local. As we discuss below, high local demand will not be a relevant explanation for the large average size plants to be found in industrial centers like High Point, North Carolina. These places are relatively small cities with low local demand.
We next examine the impact of a trade surge in the standardized segment on the distribution of the production of standardized goods across locations. We model trade in a simple fashion. As above, suppose there are two domestic locations. Now add a third location that we call location (China). We assume location does not have any expenditure, . Assume the transportation cost is the same from location to both domestic locations, and let . Let be the China surge parameter. It is 's competitiveness index (which is the same at locations 1 and 2). Finally, we allow for there to be a general equilibrium impact of China on the input prices at each location. Let be the input price at location given China surge , and let be the cost efficiency parameter at as a function of .
Assumption 1. Assume the wage ratio weakly decreases in and that the ratio strictly increases in .
This assumption is sensible because the industry is disproportionately represented at location 2, so any impact on wages from the imports should disproportionately affect location 2. (And increasing just means that China is becoming relatively more competitive than location 1 as increases.)
Using (3) and (2), we can write the probability that location 2 sells at 1 as
Proposition 2. Suppose: (a) there are only standardized goods (the pure BEJK model); (b) the parameters are such that location 2 is the high concentration location (formally, so ); (c) there is symmetric distance adjustment between locations 1 and 2 ( ); and (d) Assumption 1 holds. Then (i) plant size is bigger at the high concentration location ( ); and (ii) the revenue location quotient of the high concentration location strictly increases in the China surge parameter .
Proof. See Appendix A.
The expansion of the foreign location hurts sales at both locations. But in the BEJK model, it hurts sales relatively less in location 2, where the industry is concentrated. Note that taking into account general equilibrium effects through Assumption 1 makes the result stronger. Any relative input price decline at location 2 increases its domestic share.
It is straightforward to see how introducing the specialty segment changes the results. Consider first the average plant size at a location. Average plant size equals the weighted average of the mean plant size in the standardized segment and specialty segments:
Next consider the impact of the trade shock. For simplicity, assume the elasticity of substitution between the two segments equals one (Cobb-Douglas), fixing the spending shares on the two segments.4 To discuss the impact of the shock, we need to distinguish between the two models of the specialty segment offered above. We begin with the nontradable case. The emergence of the new foreign location is irrelevant for the nontradable specialty sector because the infinite transportation precludes imports from location . Suppose there are two domestic locations as in Proposition 2 and the standardized segment lies completely within location 2. The nontradable segment is distributed across the two locations following expenditure. Assume the Census combines the standardized and specialty segments into one industry. Then location 2 will be measured as specializing in the overall industry. If the average plant size of standardized plants is greater than specialty plants, then location 2 will have larger plants than the domestic average. So part (i) of Proposition 2 continues to hold. But now consider an increase in the China surge parameter for standardized goods. This displaces sales of standardized goods at location 2 but has no impact on sales of specialty goods at location 1 (the only type of products produced at 1). Location 2 with high industry concentration and the large plants loses share relative to location 1 on account of the surge from location . This is the opposite of the result for the pure BEJK model (i.e., part (ii) of Proposition 2).
In the alternative model where the specialty goods are high-end niche goods but very tradable, the outcome depends upon the emerging trade partner's ability to compete in the specialty segment as well as in the standardized segment. It is likely that the circumstances that make location a strong competitor in the standardized segment (e.g., an abundance of unskilled labor) are unrelated to its competitiveness in the specialty segment. If that is the case, the specialty segment is not affected and part (ii) of Proposition 2 will not hold in this case either.
The first part of this section discusses data sources and industry and geographic classifications. The second part provides some initial descriptive results.
We analyze the confidential micro data for two programs of the U.S. Census Bureau. In the first, the 1997 Census of Manufactures (CM), the data are collected at the plant level, e.g., at a particular plant location, as opposed to being aggregated up to the firm level. For each plant, the file contains information about employment, sales revenue, location, and industry classification.
The second data file is the 1997 Commodity Flow Survey (CFS). The CFS is a survey of the shipments that leave manufacturing plants.5 Respondents are required to take a sample of their shipments (e.g., every 10 shipments) and specify the destination, the product classification, the weight, and the value of the shipment at origin. On the basis of this probability-weighted survey, the Census tabulates estimates of figures such as the total ton-miles shipped of particular products. There are approximately 30,000 manufacturing plants with shipments in the survey.
While we have access to the raw confidential Census data, in some instances, we report estimates based partially on publicly disclosed information rather than entirely on the confidential data. These are cases where we want to report information about narrowly defined geographic areas, but strict procedures relating to the disclosure process for the micro-data-based results get in our way. In these cases, we make partial use of the detailed public information that is made available about each plant in the Census of Manufactures. Specifically, the Census publishes the cell counts in such a way that for each plant, we can identify its six-digit NAICS industry, its location, and its detailed employment size class (e.g., 1-4 employees, 5-9 employees, 10-19 employees, etc.). We use this and other information to derive sales and employment estimates for narrowly defined geographic areas. The data appendix (Appendix B) provides details.
Plants are classified into industries according to the North American Industry Classification System, or NAICS. The finest level of plant classification in this system is the six-digit level, and there are 473 different manufacturing industries at this level. When we estimate the model, we focus on a more narrow set of 172 manufacturing industries. These are industries with diffuse demand that approximately follows the distribution of population, which allows us to use population to proxy demand when we estimate the model. Specifically, through use of the input-output tables, we selected industries that are final goods for consumers. In addition, we included intermediate products used in things like construction and health services that have diffuse demand. We excluded intermediate products used downstream for further manufacturing processing. See the data appendix for additional details.
We use Economic Areas (EAs) as defined by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) as our underlying geographic unit.6 There are 177 EAs that form a partition of the contiguous United States. (We exclude Alaska and Hawaii throughout the analysis.) The BEA defines EAs to construct meaningful economic geographic units, using counties as building blocks. There are 3,110 counties in the contiguous United States that are aggregated to construct the EAs. A metropolitan statistical area (MSA) is typically an EA. In addition, rural areas not part of MSAs get grouped into an EA. As an example, the EA containing the center of the wood furniture industry in North Carolina consists of 22 counties and is called the "Greensboro-Winston-Salem-High Point, NC Economic Area." For ease of exposition, in the discussion in the text we will simply refer to this as "High Point." Finally, to calculate distances between EAs, we take the population centroids of each EA and use the great circle formula.
This subsection presents descriptive evidence that sheds light on the plausibility of our thesis. We begin by looking at a selected set of seven industries for which we are able to exploit additional information about what the plants do beyond the NAICS code. We then discuss evidence for a broader set of industries.
In 1997, the Census changed its industry classification from the SIC system to the NAICS system. Seven NAICS manufacturing industries were redefined to include plants that had previously been classified as retail under SIC. For example, under the SIC system, establishments that manufactured chocolate on the premises for direct sale to consumers were classified as retail. Think here of a fancy chocolate shop making premium chocolate by hand. These were moved into NAICS 311330, "Confectionery Manufacturing from Purchased Chocolate." This industry also includes candy bar factories with more than a thousand employees. This situation--where retail candy operations are lumped into the same industry as mass-production factories making standardized goods--epitomizes what we are trying to capture in our model. Analogous to chocolate, facilities making custom furniture and custom curtains in storefront settings were moved from retail under SIC to manufacturing under NAICS. The logic underlying these reclassifications was an attempt under the NAICS system to use a "production-oriented economic concept" (Office of Management and Budget, 1994) as the basis of industry classification. The concept is that plants that use the same production technology should be grouped together in the same industry. The previous SIC system sometimes followed this logic but was inconsistent in its application.
Table 2 shows the seven NAICS manufacturing industries that were affected this way. We will refer to these industries as the 1997 Reclassification Industries and sometimes as the Seven Industry Sample. All are consumer goods industries, producing some kind of candy, textiles, or furniture. We do not regard these reclassifications in 1997 as a "mistake" by the statistical authority or any kind of deviation from normal philosophy about how to aggregate plants into industries. It is infeasible for the Census to define industry boundaries at extremely narrow detail because otherwise cells become so thin in tabulations that disclosure issues preclude publication. The Census must aggregate in some way, and its general procedure is to group standardized versions and specialty versions of the same product into the same industry.
The reclassification of these plants is fortunate for our purposes as it yields additional information that can be exploited. The data for 1997 contain a plant's SIC code in addition to its NAICS code because tabulations were published both ways for this switchover year. We refer to the plants that are in retail under SIC as SIC/Retail plants and the remaining plants as SIC/Man.
The first thing to note in Table 2 is that the SIC/Retail plants are significantly smaller than the SIC/Man plants. Next look at exports by type. A well-known result due to Bernard and Jensen (1995) is that large plants are relatively likely to export compared with small plants. The consistent pattern is that the SIC/Man plants (which are large on average) have a 3 percent export share, whereas the SIC/Retail plants (which are small) don't export at all. Furthermore, we can think of retail status as an extreme form of non-exporter status; retailers (typically) do not sell to domestic destinations outside their own immediate vicinity, let alone foreign destinations. So the connection reported here between plant size, export status, and retail status can be interpreted as a variant of a well-known empirical pattern.
Suppose we take the specialty-segment-as-nontradable-good variant of our model and use SIC/Retail status as a proxy indicator for our specialty nontradable good. An immediate implication of the model is that the geographic distribution of the SIC/Retail segment will closely track the distribution of demand. The last column of Table 2 provides evidence consistent with this pattern. It reports a measure of the distribution of industry sales which shows that plants in the SIC/Retail segment tend to closely follow population (as retail does more generally), whereas plants in the SIC/Man segment tend to be geographically concentrated.
To explain the measure, recall the definition of the location quotient (7) at location for a given industry, but now use population share to approximate expenditure share in the denominator. Analogous to Holmes and Stevens (2004b), for each industry we sort locations (economic areas) by the location quotient from lowest to highest and then aggregate locations into 10 approximately equal-sized population-decile classes. This aggregation helps smooth the data. Let be the location quotient of decile . By definition, . If all sales are concentrated in the top decile, then , as 100 percent of the industry is concentrated among 10 percent of the population.
We are interested in comparing the geographic dispersion of different groups of plants within the same industry. Let index a particular group of plants. (For example, for what we do in Table 2, the index signifies whether a plant is SIC/Retail or SIC/Man.) Suppose plants located in decile of type are indexed by , and let be the sales of plant of type at decile . Let be the sales-weighted overall mean location quotient across plants from all locations of all types. Then
Hence, the mean location quotient is exactly the standard Herfindahl index of concentration, times a factor of 10. If the entire industry is concentrated in the top decile, then . If it is spread equally across the 10 deciles, then . The main interest for this subsection is the conditional mean location quotient of plants of type , Note that conditioning on type enters only through the weights; plants of all types in decile are used to define the associated with a sale.7 Conceptually, we are taking each dollar of sales in the data and associating it with the location quotient of its origin and taking means.The last column of Table 2 presents the mean location quotients conditional on SIC/Retail or SIC/Man status. There is a clear pattern in the table that the SIC/Man segments tend to have significantly higher geographic concentration than the corresponding SIC/Retail segments. Moreover, the measures for the SIC/Retail segments are close to one. For example, in the wood furniture industry, the mean is 1.17 for SIC/Retail and 4.42 for SIC/Man.
The SIC/Retail plants in these industries are clearly what we have in mind by specialty plants. But what about the many small plants in the SIC/Man segment in these industries? We address this issue for the furniture plants by exploiting unique information available for these plants. The Census of Manufactures asks a sample of plants to itemize their shipments in various product categories. In most cases, the product definitions are unrelated to the specialty product versus standardized product distinction that would be useful for our paper. However, for the furniture industries, new product definitions were created as part of the 1997 reclassification that get directly at what we want. Specifically, across all the various furniture products, a distinction is made between products that are custom made and those not custom made, and custom products are an example of what we have in mind for specialty products.8 For each plant with the requisite data, we define the custom share for the plant to be the share of product shipments in the custom category. (Not all small plants are required to fill out the detailed survey of shipments and we throw out imputed values, so our data here are for a sample of plants rather than for the universe.) Table 3 reports unweighted means of this variable for the three furniture industries from Table 2 together, and with Kitchen Cabinets separated out from Household Furniture (where Household Furniture combines Wood and Upholstered).
The first thing to note at the top of the table, where the three industries are grouped together, is that plants in the SIC/Retail category on average have a significantly higher custom share than plants in the SIC/Man category, .82 versus .42. Second, within plants classified as SIC/Man, the share falls sharply with plant size, from .59 to .30 to .09 across the three size categories.
Third, looking at the breakdown where Kitchen Cabinets are separated out, we see that Kitchen Cabinets are much more likely to be custom made than Household Furniture. This is not surprising, since a kitchen cabinet is built in and has to fit a particular spot in a kitchen. In contrast, a wood bureau or dresser can be pushed up against a bedroom wall. Note from Table 2 that Kitchen Cabinet plants tend to be smaller than Household Furniture plants. Hence, when we look at the top of the table with all the industries combined, we can see that part of the reason for the sharp decline in custom share with plant size is the industry composition effect that kitchen cabinet plants make up a disproportionate fraction of the small plants. But a key point to note is that the size relationship in the custom share persists even after controlling for industry at a narrow level. Within SIC/Man plants making kitchen cabinets, the share falls sharply from .70 to .56 to .28 across the size classes. Within SIC/Man plants making household furniture, it falls from .08 to .05 to .03.
Naturally, our interest extends beyond the seven reclassification industries in Table 2. Outside these seven industries, we do not have useful product and SIC code distinctions to work with. We do have plant size for each establishment, and our last descriptive exercise makes use of it, extending earlier results in Holmes and Stevens (2002). We break plants down into four employment size categories and calculate the conditional mean location quotient for each size category . These values are in the column labeled "Raw" in Table 4. Next we add six-digit NAICS fixed effects and report how the fitted values vary with plant size, holding industry effects fixed (at the mean level).9 These go in the column labeled "NAICS Fixed Effect."
As a reference point, we begin with the seven reclassification industries. The results are in the top panel of Table 4. In the column labeled "Raw," we see that the mean location quotient is only 1.36 in the smallest size category and rises all the way to 6.13 for the largest category. We expect that part of this relationship stems from the fact that some industries (like Kitchen Cabinets) tend to have small plants and be geographically disperse. While the inclusion of six-digit NAICS fixed effects does attenuate the relationship, it remains quite large, going from 2.46 in the smallest plant size category to 5.83 at the top. This pattern is consistent with that established in Table 2 for these industries. There, the category with large plants on average (SIC/Man) is more geographically concentrated than the category with small plants (SIC/Retail).
In the second panel we do the same exercise for the 165 other industries with diffuse demand for which we will estimate the model. The same pattern holds. Using fixed effects, the mean location quotient increases from 3.72 in the smallest plant size category to 5.41 in the largest category. The spread found here, 3.72 to 5.41 (a difference of 1.69), is half the spread of 2.46 to 5.83 (3.37) found with the seven reclassification industries. The attenuation of the effect is not surprising, as the seven are a selected sample that exemplifies the factors we are highlighting. However, the very same qualitative relationship that holds in our selected sample of seven industries also holds in the broad sample. We obtain similar results in the bottom panel for the remaining 301 industries that do not have diffuse demand.
We conclude by noting related results in Holmes and Stevens (2010b). Using CFS data and the same plant size categories as in Table 4, we show that small plants within the United States ship shorter distances than large plants. In summary, small plants tend to be more geographically diffuse, they tend to not export, and they tend to ship short distances within the United States, compared with their large plant counterparts.
This section estimates the model. The first subsection considers a constrained version of the model where the standardized-goods segment is the entire industry. This subsection serves the role of providing first-stage estimates that are used later. The next subsection brings the specialty-goods segment into the analysis.
In what we call the first-stage estimates, the model is estimated under the assumption that each six-digit NAICS is a distinct standardized-product industry, i.e., each industry has its own BEJK model parameters. This procedure pins down distance adjustment parameters that will be used throughout the paper.
For each industry , the data-generating process for the industry is summarized by a vector that parameterizes the relative cost efficiencies of the various locations and an matrix , with elements , that parameterize the distance adjustments in (3). We normalize so the sum to one across locations .
Assume the distance adjustment for industry takes the form
We have restricted attention to the 172 industries for which demand is diffuse, approximately following population. For simplicity, we assume this is exactly true, so that expenditure at location in industry is proportional to population and normalize so . The Census of Manufactures (CM) covers the universe of all plants in the United States. Subtracting out the exports of each plant, we can aggregate the plant-level sales revenue data to get , the value of domestic shipments originating at location in industry .
Other than export information, there is no destination information in the CM. However, the CFS provides survey information on shipments and their destinations that we can link to plants (and thereby determine industry). A concern we have with the CFS data is that local shipments may be overrepresented in the data. These seem too high, more than can be absorbed by local demand. We expect that sometimes shipments intended for faraway destinations get there by way of a local warehouse In cases like these, the destination found in the CFS may be the local warehouse rather than the ultimate destination. Appendix B discusses this issue further and provides some evidence on the importance of wholesaling for the manufacturing industries in our sample.
The form of our data leads us to the following strategy for estimating and the productivity vector for each industry. We pick that perfectly match the distribution of sales at originating locations, as we directly observe the universe of sales at each location. Because of our concern about excessive local shipments, we throw out all local shipments in the CFS that are less than 100 miles and fit the conditional distribution of the longer shipments. Formally, set and let be the set of all destinations at least from an originating location . The conditional probability that an industry shipment originating in location goes to a particular destination equals
For each value of , we solve for the vector such that the predicted total sales of the industry at a given location equals total sales in the CM data. Appendix C outlines our algorithm for finding a solution to the 177 nonlinear equations for the 177 locations. We can then write the conditional probability above as a function of . We pick to maximize the conditional likelihood of the destinations observed in the shipment sample.10Table 5 reports estimates of and for several selected industries and summary statistics of the estimated parameters across the entire set of 172 industries. (See the web document, Holmes and Stevens (2010a), for detailed estimates by industry.) The reported industries are those at the 25th percentile in the distribution of the implied value of , the distance adjustment at 100 miles. The bottom industry in this dimension is "Ready-Mix Concrete," a well-known example of manufacturing industry for which shipments are overwhelmingly local. (See Syverson (2004).) For this industry and four other industries where shipments are overwhelmingly local (such as "Ice" and "Concrete Blocks"), we included shipments less than 100 miles in the estimation.11 We see in Table 5 that the estimate of for Ready-Mix Concrete is .01. For Ice (not shown in the table), and for Asphalt Paving (not shown) it equals . These industries are essentially nontradable beyond 100 miles. Butter is the 25th percentile industry. For this industry there is a high degree of tradability at 100 miles ( ), but tradability drops off steeply at 500 miles ( ). The highest-ranked tradability industry is "Other Hosiery & Sock Mills." We truncate the function at one in a few industries like this where the unconstrained value exceeds one. Imposing this constraint makes little difference; unconstrained, the distance adjustment for "Other Hosiery & Sock Mills" at 100 miles is
Table 5 also reports the mean values of the parameter estimates across all industries. On average, meaning that if we look only at the linear component of (12), the average drop-off in is .3 percent per mile. The fact that the coefficient on the quadratic term is negative adds a convexity element to the relationship; the drop-off decreases with distance at a decreasing rate.
We have also reestimated the model using the data from the 1992 Census of Manufactures. We call this the 1992 SIC sample because industry classification was based on SIC that year. We use the same selection criterion to identify industries with diffuse demand and arrive at 175 industries. The mean values of the estimates are similar to the baseline 1997 NAICS case. For those industries with no change in definition between the 1992 SIC and 1997 NAICS, there is a very high correlation in the implied values of . The CFS survey for the earlier period was a larger, better-funded survey, with many more observations. In particular, the average number of shipments used to estimate the parameters of each industry is 8,500 for the earlier period and about 4,000 in the later period. Thus, estimates for the 1992 SIC sample are more precise.
Table 5 also shows what happens to the estimates when the distance threshold for including shipments in the analysis is varied. As discussed above, CFS manufacturing shipments may overstate local shipments, as some local shipments may end up in the wholesale sector to be ultimately shipped to faroff destinations. When we set so that no observations are excluded, the average value of falls from the baseline level of .80 to . 71. With local shipments included, the model is accounting for the high relative likelihood of local sales by making transportation costs higher. If we go in the other direction and raise the cutoff to , the average value of rises from .80 to .85.
The last topic of this subsection is goodness of fit. Recall that by construction, the total shipments originating in each location in the estimated model perfectly fit the data. For a notion of goodness of fit, we look at the distance pattern of shipments. We break the shipments above 100 miles into three distance categories, (1) 100 to 500 miles, (2) 500 to 1,000 miles, and (3) over 1,000 miles. For industry , let be the share of the shipments above 100 miles that are in distance category in the data. Let be the fitted value in the estimated model. Table 6 presents descriptive statistics. In the data, on average across the industries, a share .44 of the 100-mile-plus shipments are in the 100- to 500-mile category. This figure compares to an average share of .38 in the estimated model. The model has a tendency to somewhat understate the shortest distance category and somewhat overstate the two longer distance categories. By construction, the destination of shipments in the model exactly follows the distribution of population. So locations far away from any producers will nevertheless be required in the model to receive their share of shipments. The last part of Table 6 shows that the fitted values of the model do a very good job in accounting for the cross-industry variation in the distance distribution. The slope of in a regression on is approximately one for all three categories.
We now consider the general model that includes the specialty segment. Our estimation strategy focuses on determining the specialty-segment share of plant counts in an industry, rather than the specialty-segment share of revenue. Both targets are interesting, but the first target is easier to get at, so that is where we aim for a first paper.
Specialty plants are small compared to standardized plants. Thus, the count share of the specialty segment is large compared with the revenue share. To explain our procedure, it is easiest to begin by outlining how it works in a limiting case, when the revenue share of the specialty segment is zero.12 Next we explain what we actually do, in allowing for a positive specialty-segment revenue share.
In the limiting case where the specialty-segment revenue share is zero, the first-stage procedure explained above delivers the correct estimates of the productivity vector of the standardized segment. (At this point, leaving out the superscript for industry is convenient.) This holds because the industry revenue used to construct the estimates exactly equals standard-segment revenue, for this limiting case. With estimates of and from the first stage, we can determine the plant counts for the standardized segment, subject to the scaling normalization . Recall from (4) that standardized-segment plant counts equal . Next consider plant counts for the specialty segment. In the nontradable case, using equation (5), specialty plant counts equal . In the high-end niche case, counts depend on the supply of specialty-specific factors through (6). As a first cut, assume supply is proportional to population. This delivers for this case as well. So for either case, the total number of plants in the given industry--standardized plus specialty--equals
To take (13) to the data, we introduce an error term. Suppose the observed total number of plants in the given industry at location equals the above expression plus an error term ,
We now explain the modification of the above procedure to allow for positive specialty-segment revenues. Take as given a value of specialty revenue per plant for the industry. Use , along with the estimate from above, to construct an estimate of specialty-segment revenues at location ,
Table 7 presents the results. The individual estimates are reported for the seven reclassification industries from Table 2; summary statistics are reported for the broader set of industries. We first note that allowing for the constant term makes little difference; when we reestimate (14) without an intercept, we get similar results. Next note that the coefficient estimate for specialty goods tends to be quite large. Given the scaling that the sum to one, is an estimate of the total count of specialty plants in the industry.
Define the implied specialty count share to be
Specialty count share for industry | ||
Table 8 provides more details about the distribution of the specialty count share by dividing the 172 industries into quartiles based on the specialty count share. There is no mechanical reason why the estimated coefficient for the regression (14) is necessarily positive. In fact, we can see in Table 8 that one industry comes in with a negative count share equal to -3.7 percent. There is also a second industry with a negative share equal to -3.0 percent. Aside from these two exceptions (which are approximately zero in any case), the other 170 industries all have strictly positive estimates of the specialty count share. Moreover, we can see in the table that the 25th percentile equals 57 percent; i.e., three-quarters of the industries have a specialty count share that exceeds this level. Thus, the estimates reveal that for the vast majority of industries, specialty plants make up the majority of plant counts.
The last column of Table 8 connects the estimates of specialty count shares in the model to shares of plants that are small in the data. In the data, a small plant is defined as a plant with 1 to 19 employees. We do not expect an exact correspondence between specialty plants in the model and small plants in the data; a small plant in the data could be a specialty plant, but it could also be a standardized plant with a low productivity draw. While there is not an exact correspondence, we expect that the specialty share in the model would likely move together with the small plant share in the data; Table 8 confirms this expectation. In particular, in the bottom quartile of industry specialty shares, the mean small plant share averages 48 percent, and this average increases monotonically across the quartiles to 67 percent for the top quartile.
We use the estimated model to analyze two issues. The first is the plant size/geographic concentration relationship. The second is the impact of the recent surge in imports from China.
Define a high-concentration industry location to be one where the revenue location quotient is above 2 and where the location has at least 5 percent of the industry's revenues. Across the 7 reclassification industries, there are 23 different high-concentration industry locations. These locations are listed in Table 9, sorted for each industry by descending sales quotient. The breakdown into the count and size quotient is also reported. (Recall .) It is clear from inspection of the data that the size margin plays an important role in contributing to how an industry expands at a location. Consider the wood furniture industry in the High Point area, where the revenue quotient is 27.7. The breakdown is . Thus, average plant size in the area is 6.6 times the national average. A high contribution from the size margin holds for virtually all of the 23 individual industry locations listed in Table 8. Over these 23 cases, the size quotient on average is 5.4, compared with an average count quotient of 4.3.
The last two columns contain fitted values of the size quotient for the constrained model with only a standardized segment (the BEJK model) and the full model that includes the specialty segment.15 From the theoretical discussion in Section 2, we know that when transportation costs are not zero (and making further assumptions about the distribution of demand), the BEJK model implies that average plant size is bigger in locations that specialize in an industry. With only three exceptions, we see in Table 9 that this qualitative pattern holds for the fitted BEJK model. However, the BEJK model fails quantitatively, as the predicted size differences are small. The count margin is doing the main work of driving variations in , just like in the numerical examples of the BEJK model in Table 1. When we turn to the full model and allow for the specialty segment, the predicted size quotients are much larger and close to what they are in the data (though still smaller). The average size quotient in the full model equals 4.0, compared with an average of only 1.3 in the constrained model. These differences between the full and the constrained model are driven by compositional differences across locations between standardized and specialty goods in the full model. In fact, if we look only at the standardized segment in the full model, the size distribution is virtually identical to what it is in the constrained model.
Next consider the broader set of industries (the 165 remaining diffuse demand industries). We see in Table 9 that the same pattern holds with these industries as holds with the 7 reclassification industries. The mean size quotient is 5.3, so the size margin plays a big role in how locations specialize in an industry. The mean fitted value of the BEJK model of 1.3 is way off. The corresponding mean in the full model, at 3.3, is still too small but gets much of the way there. The industry-location level observations in Table 9 suggest some skewness in the distribution of the size quotients, so it is of interest to also look at the median. The median size quotient in the full model of 2.5 is close to the median of 2.6 in the data.
Imports from China have surged in a number of manufacturing industries in recent years. This subsection identifies a set of "China surge" industries.16 For this set of industries, the subsection examines how the geographic distribution of production in the United States has shifted in response. It compares the results to the prediction of the constrained model that does not allow for the specialty segment (i.e., the pure BEJK model). The constrained model is inconsistent with what actually happened. In contrast, the full model with the specialty segment fits the data. The last part of the subsection uses the full model to estimate the specialty count share in 2007 and compares the estimates to 2007. In the China surge industries, there is a dramatic decline in standardized segment plant counts.
We classify an industry as having a China import surge if the industry experienced a 25 percentage point increase in overall imports as a share of shipments over the period 1997 to 2007 and if China's share of total imports in the industry as of 2007 exceeds 40 percent.17 Of the 172 industries for which we have model estimates, there are 17 China surge industries, and they are listed in Table 10. The overall import share of these 17 industries rose on average from 34 percent in 1997 to 70 percent in 2007. The share of imports from China increased from 26 to 61 percent over this same period. Employment declined 66 percent on average over the period. In the infant apparel industry, employment declined an astonishing 97 percent.
It is useful to have a comparison group of industries that (1) unlike the China surge industries have not been negatively affected by imports but (2) are similar to the China surge industries in being tradable within the United States. We use food (NAICS = 311) and beverage (NAICS = 312) industries for this purpose. As shown in the bottom row of Table 9, imports in these industries are relatively small. On average, employment increased by 5 percent for these industries over the time period.
The last two columns of Table 10 report mean plant-level employment by industry for each year. Mean plant employment fell dramatically. On average across all the China surge industries, it fell from 63 to 30 employees per plant. In infant apparel, it fell from 178 to 11. A decrease in average plant size from an import surge is consistent with our theory, which emphasizes the displacement of large mass-production plants by Chinese imports. The pattern is also consistent with the standard theory. The efficient plants--which would have been large without the China surge--survive the China surge but at a smaller output level. (Inefficient plants that would have been small without the surge shut down.) To evaluate what our theory adds to the analysis, we need to look at more detailed implications.
We take our first-stage model estimates for 1997 of the pure BEJK model of the standardized sector for each of these industries and simulate the impact of a large import shock on the distribution of domestic production in 2007. As discussed in the theory section, the transportation cost from China is assumed to be the same to all domestic locations. For each industry , we set the China surge parameter for 1997 and 2007 to and
For the sake of illustration, it is useful to start with a detailed discussion of the wood furniture industry in High Point. Recall from above that in 1997, the sales revenue location quotient equaled in High Point. Using the estimates of the BEJK model from stage 1 for 1997, to simulate the impact of a China surge equal to (15), and plugging in 2007 population values, results in a predicted value of for 2007 at High Point. This predicted increase in our estimated model with 177 locations goes the same way as the theoretical result in Proposition 2 for the special case with only two domestic locations. The pure BEJK model is predicting that locations with large plants and large domestic market share increase domestic share after a shock. The opposite actually happened. The revenue quotient for High Point fell from 28.4 to 12.8, meaning High Point's share of the domestic market fell by more than half. Panel A of Table 11 provides cell counts by plant size for the wood furniture industry that gives more details about the collapse between 1997 and 2007. The table makes clear that the collapse of the industry is at the high end of the size distribution. Looking at the United States as a whole, we see that 48 plants in 1997 have more than 500 employees, and that number falls to only 20 for 2007. In contrast, for the smallest size category, there is virtually no change. Now look the counts for just High Point to get a sense of the disproportionate way that, in the 1997 data, large plants are concentrated in High Point. In particular, 14 out of 48 U.S. plants with 500 or more employees are in High Point for 1997, but only 51 out of 3,091 plants with less than 20 employees. Finally, observe the huge losses in large plants at High Point from 1997 to 2007.
To examine the broader set of China surge industries, we find the equivalent of High Point for these other industries. Define the 1997 Primary Location to be the location with the highest 1997 location sales quotient, of those locations with at least 5 percent of 1997 sales. Table 12 restates the variables just discussed for wood furniture and then presents the summary statistics about these same variables for the other industries. For the China surge industries, simulating the BEJK model for 2007 leads to a predicted increase on average of the revenue quotient from 26.9 to 29.4. (If we look at the 17 individual industries, there are only 2 exceptions going the other way.) What actually happened is that the sales revenue location quotients fell dramatically, on average, from 26.9 to 12.2. (If we look at the industries individually, there is only one exception to this pattern.) When we look at the detailed size distribution information for all the China surge industries in Panel B of Table 11, we see the same thing is true with the broader set of industries as holds for just wood furniture. The big plants are collapsing and the primary locations are bearing the brunt of this collapse. Note in particular that the primary locations had 33 plants with more than 500 employees in 1997, but by 2007 this count had plunged to only 3 plants.
We address an issue regarding the definition of the primary location. It is defined as the location of first rank in its relative market share as of 1997. A number one location can only go down in the ranking. In particular, we expect the well-understood mechanism of "regression to the mean" to play some role, given the normal ebb and flow of market shares across locations. To gain some perspective on its contribution, we similarly define primary locations in the food and beverage comparison industries. Just as is the case for the China surge industries, average plant size is quite high for the food and beverage industries at the primary locations. Also, the average sales revenue quotient is similarly quite high (37.4 in the food and beverage industries, 26.9 in the China surge industries). Even though these industries were not actually affected by imports, we can use the estimated model to simulate a hypothetical China surge. For these industries, the predicted BEJK sales revenue quotients indeed increase on average at the primary locations, just as they do for the China surge industries. As we would expect from regression to the mean, in the data there is actually a decline, from 37.4 to 31.6. The decline is relatively small, only 16 percent, compared with the average 59 percent decline for the China surge industries. We get the same conclusion if we look at the median instead of the mean. We conclude that the sharp observed fall at the primary locations of the China surge industries extends substantially beyond anything we would expect to see from regression to the mean, in the normal ebb and flow of market shares.
We next look at what happens in big cities. Big cities are interesting to look at because in recent decades, in a relative sense, they have not been the home of large mass-production factories (which have instead concentrated in small factory towns like High Point). Given the demand for specialty goods in large cities and given the supply of unique skills in big cities that can serve as inputs for specialty goods, a priori we expect that as China knocks out standardized goods in places like High Point, the industry will shift toward specialty goods made in big cities. To examine this issue, we combine the 20 largest economic areas by population into one group and calculate the various quotients for the group as a whole. (We get similar results for other groupings of large cities.) Table 13 is the analogue of Table 12, with the big city aggregate serving as the location of interest instead of the primary location. Note that big city plants do indeed tend to be small, with , on average across the industries. As of 1997, sales were slightly underrepresented in big cities, . The BEJK model predicts no change going into 2007. What actually happened is that the sales quotient increased in the big city aggregate, rising to , to become over-represented. (Looking at the individual industries, we can see that there are only 3 exceptions to this pattern of the 17 industries.) By contrast, in the food/beverage comparison group, nothing is happening.
Thus, the predictions of the pure BEJK model for changes in sales share are inconsistent with the data. Turning now to predictions of the general model that allows for the specialty segment, we first reiterate that we have not estimated a model of the division of revenue between the two segments. Rather, our estimated model is one of plant counts for the two segments. We will use the estimated model to examine predictions about changes in plant counts from a China surge. Before doing that, we note that our general model with specialty goods is consistent with the qualitative patterns about changes in sales revenues across locations just documented. Primary industry locations with large plants like High Point are in decline in terms of sales share because these locations specialize in the standardized goods that China sells. Locations with small plants, including large cities, are in relative ascent because these locations specialize in specialty goods that are poor substitutes for what China is selling.
Table 14 reports our results, comparing the predictive power for plant counts of the pure BEJK model and our general model. As in Tables 12 and 13, to calculate the fitted values for 2007, we take the estimated models for 1997 and plug in the China surge (15) as well as the 2007 population values. Panel A looks at the primary locations. Analogous to what happens in Table 12 with sales revenue shares, the pure BEJK model fails with plant counts as well. The model predicts too many plants at the primary locations (i.e., plants are too small), but in addition predicts the count shares at these locations will increase from the China surge, while in actuality they decreased significantly. The predictions of the general model are roughly in line with what happened. Across the China surge industries, the count quotients decrease on average from 6.8 to 5.5 (a decline of 1.3 points), while in the data the decrease is from 5.8 to 3.9 (a decline of 1.9 points). Panel B considers a prediction exercise that looks at all 177 Economic Areas together. For each industry, we regress the change in count quotient for location on the predicted changes for both models. For the pure BEJK model, the slope in the regression is actually slightly negative as changes tend to go in the opposite direction from what the pure BEJK model predicts. In contrast, for the general model the slope is close to one. (It equals .93 for wood furniture and averages .89 across all 17 industries.) This is what we get when we do this exercise on the industries actually experiencing a China surge. For the food and beverage industries, which didn't actually experience such a surge, we get a range of noisy values that on average are relatively close to zero.
Taking the results of Table 14 as a validation of our general model, our final exercise uses 2007 data to estimate specialty and standardized plant counts for that year and compares these with the 1997 estimates. The results are in Table 15.19 We begin as before with a discussion of wood furniture. For 1997, we estimate there are 697 and 3,150 plants in the standardized and specialty segments of this industry, or shares of 18.1 and 81.9 percent, respectively. For 2007, the respective counts are 213 and 3,215, or 6.2 and 93.8 percent. Thus, according to these estimates, the standardized segment collapsed to about a third of its initial plant counts, while the specialized segment remained relatively stable. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis of this paper.
For the China surge industries overall (Panel B of Table 15), there is a collapse of the standardized segment to about one-third of its prior level, similar to the wood furniture case. The specialty segment also decreases, but at a much lower rate than the standardized segment. The situation is quite different with the food and beverage industries, which has experienced little in the way of import competition. The standardized segment has actually increased somewhat in plant counts. Finally, when we look at the remaining industries, there is a downward trend in standardized plant count share. But the impact is small compared with what is happening to the China surge industries.
This paper develops a model in which industries are made up of mass-production factories making standardized goods and specialty plants making custom or niche goods. The paper uses a combination of confidential and public Census data to estimate parameters of the model and, in particular, produces estimates of plant counts in the specialty and standardized segments by industry. The estimated model fits the observed plant size/geographic concentration relationship relatively well. The estimates reveal that, for those industries that have been heavily affected by a surge of imports from China, there has been a dramatic decline in plant counts for the standardized segment, while the specialty segments have been relatively stable. The paper also shows that for the China surge industries, locations with large concentrations of the industry and large plants, like High Point, North Carolina, have declined relative to the rest of the country. These results are consistent with the hypothesis that products made in China are close substitutes to the products of big plants (like those in High Point), and not so close substitutes to the products of the small plants that are diffuse throughout the country. The results are inconsistent with standard theories that assert that small plants are just like large plants, except for having a low productivity draw.
In our theory, if a plant in the United States is huge, it is a signal that the plant is potentially vulnerable to competition from China. A huge plant is likely making something that can be traded across space--something that can be put in a container and shipped--as a local market would not likely be able to absorb all the output of a given huge plant.
To make progress, the paper proceeds under the abstraction that each plant is in one of two discrete categories: standardized or specialty. To illustrate these categories, the paper gives the example of a furniture factory with more than a thousand employees and an Amish shop employing a few skilled craftsmen. In future work, allowing for a continuum of possibilities in between the limiting two-type case would be useful. The logic of our ideas, which is put in sharp relief with our focus on the limiting case, should extend to more general approaches. That is, a comparison of a megafactory with a tiny Amish shop highlights forces that in principle are operative--albeit at a reduced extent--in a comparison of a 200-employee plant with a 50-employee plant.
Appendix A: Proof of Proposition 2
For now assume is constant, so is constant. Since strictly increases and since a proportionate change in , , and leaves the the same, without loss of generality assume is constant in .
Letting , for this special case we can write the probability that location sells to location as
, |
where the expressions for and are analogous. Since
, it follows that
. The ratio of sales between the two locations is
To prove part (ii), we need to show the ratio is increasing in , for fixed and . From inspection of (16), this holds if
or which holds since and .The last step of the proof is to take into account that the relative wage is weakly decreasing in . This implies that is weakly increasing in . Since without loss of generality, we can assume is constant in , and since we have proven in (16) is increasing in for fixed and , it is sufficient to show in (16) is increasing in for fixed and . This follows from straightforward calculations. Q.E.D.
Appendix B: Data
This section of the appendix discusses various topics regarding the data. We have posted on the web a supplementary document, Holmes and Stevens (2010a), that contains links to data sets and supplementary tables. In particular, we post the first-stage and second-stage model estimates for all 172 NAICS industries for which we have estimated the model.
A. Joint Use of Confidential and Public Data
The Census cannot disclose results that could potentially compromise the confidentiality of the Census data. In particular, statistics at a high level of geographic and industry detail are problematic for getting through the disclosure process.
It is useful to be able to simulate the estimated model outside a secure Census facility. This makes it possible to easily replicate findings of the paper. It also makes it possible to make tables of the predictions of the model at narrow geographic and industry detail. To accomplish this goal, we made joint use of confidential and publicly available data. First, we used the confidential micro CFS data to estimate the parameters of the distance adjustment function for each industry . The release of these aggregate industry variables posed no disclosure risk. Second, we used publicly available data to estimate the distribution of industry revenue across locations and then used these revenue estimates to estimate the productivity vector for each industry.
To construct public revenue estimates by location, we begin with the 1997 Location of Manufacturing plants (LM) data series. The LM data are public data of cell counts by industry, county, and narrowly defined employment size categories (1-4, 5-9, 10-19, 20-49, 50-99, 100-249, 250-499, 500-999, 1,000-2,499, 2,500 and above). This is file E9731e2 from the 1997 Economic Census CD (U.S. Bureau of the Census (2001)). These cell counts are not considered a disclosure, and no information is held back. Thus, for each of the 362,829 plants in the Census of Manufactures, we have as public data the plant's county, industry, and detailed employment size category. We produce an estimate of average sales revenue conditioned on industry and employment size, and assign this to each plant as an estimate of its sales.20 We then aggregate up the plant-level sales estimates to the BEA Economic Area level for each industry to obtain estimates of the location-level data needed to implement the second stage of our procedure. We found that in running the second-stage procedure, it made little difference when we used the estimated revenue data instead of the actual revenue data. For 2007, we use the analogous cell count data from County Business Patterns, and we use the same mapping between sales estimate and employment size category that we use for 1997.
B. Choice of Diffuse Demand Industries
We use the U.S. Benchmark Input-Output Accounts for 2002 (Stewart, Stone, and
Streitwieser (2007)) to classify industries. We first define a set of downstream demand (or "use") of goods that we categorize at "local demand." These are all uses in the following categories: structures, transportation, retail trade, information (publishing), finance, insurance, real estate,
services, personal consumption expenditures, fixed private investment, and government services. Then for each commodity, we determine which of these deliver 75 percent or more of their sales to the local demand categories. We define these to be the diffuse demand industries. We also include
borderline cases of Surgical and Dental Equipment (NAICS 339112) and Dental Equipment (NAICS 339114).
C. More Information about Data Sources Used in the Tables
Table 2. The cell counts that cross-classify the 1997 Census plants by NAICS and SIC use public data files E97B1 and E97B2 distributed at the Census web site. These files report employment by SIC and NAICS, from which mean plant size by SIC/NAICS was derived. The confidential micro data were used to calculate export shares and mean plant sales location quotients in the table.
Tables 3 through 6. These tables use the confidential micro data at the Census. Population at the EA level was calculated using Census county-level estimates for 1992 and 1997 (and below for 2007) and aggregating up to the EA level.
Tables 7 through 9 and 11 through 15 use publicly available data as discussed in Part A above.
Table 10 uses import information posted by the U.S. International Trade Commission at its web site. (For two furniture industries, NAICS 337122 and 337125, we used revised figures reported at the web site of the International Trade Administration.) Imports are "Customs Value of U.S. Imports for Consumption." The variables are reported at the six-digit NAICS level, though in some cases the five-digit level is used. Imports are reported as a share of the domestic shipments plus imports, where domestic shipments equal the product shipments in the given six-digit NAICS product for the given Economic Census year (1997 or 2007).
D. Local Shipments and Wholesaling
When estimating the model in the first stage, we condition on sales being greater than 100 miles. Here we discuss the issue of "excess local shipments" in a little more detail. Table A1 reports the distribution of shipment shares by distance category, both in the data and in the estimated models, conditioned on shipments above 100 miles. It is like Table 6 before, except it includes a breakdown by industries according to the estimated distance adjustment, i.e., for industry .21 We see in the conditional distribution a tendency for the model to overstate distance shipped, compared with the data. However, for the most part, the discrepancy is moderate.
Table A2 uses the same estimated model (the model optimized to fit the conditional distribution) and reports how things look in the unconditional distribution. A large discrepancy in the under 100 miles category is readily apparent. In particular, consider the highest industries, the ones that are most tradable. In the fitted model, local shipments less than 100 miles are predicted to be only 5 percent of sales, but in fact make up 19 percent of sales, a difference of almost a factor of four. In the limiting case where there is no discount adjustment (i.e., at all distances), a plant's shipments to a particular location should be proportionate to the location's population. That is, the share of shipments going less than 100 miles should equal the share of the U.S. population within 100 miles. Many of the high industries, like clothing, tend to be outside the major population centers, and that is why predicted shipments within 100 miles is so low for these industries.
In working with the CFS data, Hillberry and Hummels (2008) observe the prevalence of local shipments and, as an explanation, emphasize the role that intermediate goods might play. For some immediate goods, it may be efficient to ship to nearby downstream manufacturing plants for further processing. In our case, we have selected out--through our use of the input-output tables--those manufacturing industries that tend to ship downstream to other manufacturing plants. So the point about intermediate goods has less relevance for us than it would be without that selection.
We believe the wholesaling sector plays some role in the story. Shipments leaving plants may make stops at nearby warehouses before arriving to their ultimate destination, which may be thousands of miles away. In such a case, the shipment distance is recorded at less than 100 miles, rather than the true distance.
Table A3 provides evidence on the relevance of the wholesale sector, for our sample of manufacturing industries. The CFS is a sample of shipments leaving both manufacturing plants and wholesale plants. To link manufacturing shipments with wholesale shipments, we exploit the product-level information available in the CFS. Each shipment in the 1997 CFS is classified by SCTG product code.22 Define the ton-miles of a shipment to be the shipment's weight times its distance. For each SCTG product, we estimate the share of ton-miles originating out of wholesale plants rather than manufacturing plants. Next, for each NAICS industry, we use the manufacturing plants in the CFS to estimate the revenue share across different SCTGs. Finally, we use the SCTG sales shares to weight the SCTG-level ton-mile shares, to produce a NAICS-level Ton-Mile Wholesale Share. On average across the sample industries, about a quarter of ton-miles go through the wholesale sector. When we repeat the exercise for the 1992 SIC sample industries, the results are virtually the same.23 We conclude that for our sample industries, the wholesale sector plays a large enough quantitative role for it to potentially be a factor in accounting for why there are more local shipments than are predicted by the model.
Appendix C: First-Stage Estimation Algorithm
We provide a detail about the first-stage estimation algorithm. As explained in the text, conditioned on the parameters of the distance discount, we solve for a vector of cost efficiencies to exactly match the distribution of sales revenues across locations. From the equations derived earlier, total sales revenue at location equals
where the depend upon held fixed here. Given the , , , we need to find a vector , with the normalization , that solves these equations.Define by and . Define the mapping
If we find a such that for all , then the output equations all hold.Note first that is strictly increasing. Note second that is bounded above by
which is the limit of as goes to infinity. Suppose we have a point . Define the sequence by , and . Since is monotonically increasing and is bounded from above, this sequence converges to a solution.To run the algorithm, we need a starting point . In our estimation, the following procedure worked for finding a starting value. Without loss of generality, we label locations for a particular industry so that location 1 has the maximum sales revenue share, . Then we set for some small .
If is convex, then any solution is unique. We have shown that is convex for or locations.
Distance Adjustment:
|
Equal Size Locations
( (=.40 and =1.60):
|
Equal Size Locations
( (=.40 and =1.60):
|
Equal Size Locations
( (=.40 and =1.60):
|
Location 2 Larger
(3 (=.31 and =1.23):
|
Location 2 Larger
(3 (=.31 and =1.23):
|
Location 2 Larger
(3 (=.31 and =1.23):
|
Location 1 Larger
( = 3 (=.57 and =2.29):
|
Location 1 Larger
( = 3 (=.57 and =2.29):
|
Location 1 Larger
( = 3 (=.57 and =2.29):
|
1.000 | 4.00 | 1.60 | 1.00 | 12.00 | 1.23 | 1.00 | 1.33 | 2.29 | 1.00 |
0.990 | 4.00 | 1.60 | 1.00 | 11.94 | 1.23 | 1.00 | 1.34 | 2.29 | 1.00 |
0.950 | 4.00 | 1.59 | 1.01 | 11.71 | 1.22 | 1.01 | 1.37 | 2.30 | 0.99 |
0.900 | 4.01 | 1.58 | 1.01 | 11.43 | 1.22 | 1.01 | 1.41 | 2.32 | 0.99 |
0.800 | 4.06 | 1.56 | 1.03 | 10.91 | 1.20 | 1.02 | 1.50 | 2.35 | 0.97 |
0.600 | 4.32 | 1.52 | 1.05 | 10.18 | 1.16 | 1.06 | 1.76 | 2.42 | 0.94 |
0.500 | 4.62 | 1.50 | 1.07 | 10.07 | 1.14 | 1.08 | 1.97 | 2.45 | 0.93 |
0.200 | 8.28 | 1.44 | 1.11 | 13.87 | 1.05 | 1.17 | 4.00 | 2.53 | 0.90 |
0.100 | 15.41 | 1.43 | 1.12 | 23.88 | 1.03 | 1.20 | 7.63 | 2.54 | 0.90 |
0.010 | 150.05 | 1.43 | 1.12 | 225.22 | 1.02 | 1.21 | 75.01 | 2.55 | 0.90 |
0.001 | 1501.20 | 1.43 | 1.12 | 2257.89 | 1.02 | 1.21 | 750.11 | 2.55 | 0.90 |
NAICS Industry Classification | Classification Based on SIC | Number of Plants | Mean Plant Employ. | Export Share | Mean Location Quotient |
Chocolate Candy | SIC/Retail | 440 | 8 | .00 | 1.01 |
Chocolate Candy (NAICS 311330) | SIC/Man | 421 | 70 | .03 | 4.87 |
Nonchocolate Candy | SIC/Retail | 349 | 4 | .00 | 1.01 |
Nonchocolate Candy (NAICS 311340) | SIC/Man | 276 | 88 | .03 | 4.61 |
Curtains | SIC/Retail | 1,085 | 4 | .00 | 1.54 |
Curtains (NAICS 312121) | SIC/Man | 999 | 21 | .03 | 3.22 |
Other Apparel | SIC/Retail | 724 | 3 | .00 | 1.71 |
Other Apparel (NAICS 315999) | SIC/Man | 966 | 25 | .03 | 2.67 |
Kitchen Cabinets | SIC/Retail | 2,055 | 5 | .00 | 1.25 |
Kitchen Cabinets (NAICS 337110) | SIC/Man | 5,908 | 15 | .01 | 2.14 |
Upholstered Household Furniture | SIC/Retail | 576 | 5 | .00 | 1.52 |
Upholstered Household Furniture (NAICS 337121) | SIC/Man | 1,130 | 77 | .03 | 7.20 |
Wood Household Furniture | SIC/Retail | 815 | 6 | .00 | 1.17 |
(NAICS 337122) | SIC/Man | 3,035 | 41 | .03 | 4.42 |
Source: Authors' calculations with confidential Census data and public Census tabulations.
Classification | Number of Sample Plants | Mean Custom
Share |
SIC/Retail | 102 | .82 |
SIC/Man | 2,944 | .42 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 1-19 | 1,628 | .59 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 20-99 | 877 | .30 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 100 and above | 437 | .09 |
Classification | Number of Sample Plants | Mean Custom
Share |
SIC/Retail | 48 | .87 |
SIC/Man | 1,854 | .64 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 1-19 | 1331 | .70 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 20-99 | 426 | .56 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 100 and above | 97 | .28 |
Classification | Number of Sample Plants | Mean Custom
Share |
SIC/Retail | 54 | .78 |
SIC/Man | 1,090 | .05 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 1-19 | 297 | .08 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 20-99 | 451 | .05 |
Within SIC/Man by Emp. Size: 100 and above | 340 | .03 |
Plant Size Category | Number of Establishments | Mean
Location Quotient: Raw |
Mean
Location Quotient: NAICS Fixed Effect |
All | 18,585 | 4.32 | 4.32 |
1-19 | 15,687 | 1.36 | 2.46 |
20-99 | 2,073 | 2.62 | 3.03 |
100-499 | 690 | 4.18 | 3.97 |
500+ | 135 | 6.13 | 5.83 |
Plant Size Category | Number of Establishments | Mean
Location Quotient: Raw |
Mean
Location Quotient: NAICS Fixed Effect |
All | 130,986 | 4.86 | 4.86 |
1-19 | 91,608 | 1.73 | 3.72 |
20-99 | 28,291 | 2.37 | 4.01 |
100-499 | 9,533 | 3.75 | 4.60 |
500+ | 1,554 | 6.68 | 5.41 |
Plant Size Category | Number of Establishments | Mean
Location Quotient: Raw |
Mean
Location Quotient: NAICS Fixed Effect |
All | 211,945 | 5.13 | 5.13 |
1-19 | 134,044 | 1.86 | 3.67 |
20-99 | 54,705 | 2.79 | 4.14 |
100-499 | 20,101 | 4.38 | 4.91 |
500+ | 3,095 | 6.92 | 5.82 |
Source: Authors' calculations with confidential Census data.
Parameter Estimates
(s.e. in Parentheses): |
Parameter Estimates
(s.e. in Parentheses): |
Implied Value of (dist) by dist: 100 miles | Implied Value of (dist) by dist: 500 miles | Implied Value of (dist) by dist: 1,000 miles | No. of CFS Shipments Used for Estimate | |
Ready-Mix Concrete (Minimum) | .0523
(.0004) |
0 | .01 | .00 | .00 | 37,875 |
Creamery Butter
(25 percentile) |
.0030
(.0003) |
-8.0E-07
(1.1E-07) |
.74 | .27 | .11 | 586 |
Wood Television Cabinets
(50 percentile) |
.0019
(.0003) |
-6.4E-07
(1.6E-07) |
.83 | .45 | .28 | 546 |
Surgical Appliance & Supplies
(75 percentile) |
.0008
(.0001) |
-1.8E-07
(0.3E-07) |
.92 | .69 | .52 | 11,670 |
Other Hosiery & Sock Mills
(Maximum) |
0 | 0 | 1.00 | 1.00 | 1.00 | 2,967 |
Baseline Estimates
(Mean over 172 Industries) |
.0030
(.0002) |
-5.0E-07
(0.7E-07) |
.80 | .48 | .33 | 3,968 |
The constraint = 0 is imposed for this industry.
This estimate is at the constraint that (dist)1.
Parameter Estimates
(s.e. in Parentheses): |
Parameter Estimates
(s.e. in Parentheses): |
Implied Value of (dist) by dist: 100 miles | Implied Value of (dist) by dist: 500 miles | Implied Value of (dist) by dist: 1,000 miles | No. of CFS Shipments Used for Estimate | |
1992 SIC (175 Industries)
with |
.0030
(.0001) |
-5.9E-07
(0.4E-07) |
.78 | .43 | .28 | 8,500 |
1997 NAICS (172 Industries)
with |
.71 | .30 | .16 | |||
1997 NAICS (172 Industries)
with |
.85 | .57 | .42 |
For these alternative specifications that vary , we did not run the individual industry estimates through the Census disclosure process. Rather, we took only the means of (100), (500), and (1000) through the disclosure process.
Statistic Reported: | Category 1
100distance500 |
Category 2
500distance1,000 |
Category 3
1,000distance |
Mean across industries (data) | .44 | .30 | .25 |
Mean
across
industries (model) |
.38 | .33 | .30 |
Regression of
(data) on (model): Intercept |
.05
(.02) |
-.03
(.02) |
-.03
(.01) |
Regression of
(data) on (model): Slope |
1.04
(.04) |
.99
(.07) |
.96
(.03) |
Regression of
(data) on (model): |
.81 | .55 | .83 |
Number of Observations | 167 | 167 | 167 |
Regression Results
(s.e. in Parentheses): Constant
|
Regression Results
(s.e. in Parentheses): Slope (spec)
|
Regression Results
(s.e. in Parentheses): Slope (stan)
|
Regression Results
(s.e. in Parentheses): |
Estimated Specialty Count Share (Percent) | |
Reclassification Industries: Chocolate Candy
(NAICS 311330) |
.4
(.2) |
621.6
(52.3) |
76.7
(13.0) |
.69 | 80.9 |
Reclassification Industries: Nonchocolate Candy
(NAICS 311340) |
.1
(.1) |
487.7
(31.2) |
61.3
(7.7) |
.79 | 80.3 |
Reclassification Industries: Curtains
(NAICS 312121) |
-.9
(.3) |
2184.4
(56.5) |
20.0
(7.7) |
.92 | 97.0 |
Reclassification Industries: Other Apparel
(NAICS 315999) |
-1.8
(.4) |
1302.6
(114.4) |
266.1
(19.9) |
.89 | 62.9 |
Reclassification Industries: Kitchen Cabinets
(NAICS 337110) |
1.4
(1.2) |
5939.6
(231.2) |
185.5
(19.1) |
.89 | 78.2 |
Reclassification Industries: Upholstered Household Furn.
(NAICS 337121) |
-1.4
(.5) |
980.0
(96.6) |
247.2
(8.0) |
.88 | 49.4 |
Reclassification Industries: Wood Household Furn.
(NAICS 337122) |
-1.2
(.8) |
3355.9
(138.8) |
254.8
(23.1) |
.85 | 81.9 |
Means of 7 Reclassification Industries | -.5
(.5) |
2124.5
(103.0) |
158.8
(14.1) |
.85 | 75.8 |
Means of 165 Remaining Diffuse Demand Industries | -.3
(.2) |
636.6
(40.3) |
86.7
(6.8) |
.71 | 66.0 |
Quartile | Model
Summary Statistics of Specialty Count Share: Minimum |
Model
Summary Statistics of Specialty Count Share: Maximum |
Model
Summary Statistics of Specialty Count Share: Mean |
Data
Mean Small Plant Count Share in Percent (Small Plants Have 19 Employees or Less) |
1 | -3.7 | 57.2 | 35.7 | 47.7 |
2 | 58.2 | 72.0 | 64.8 | 53.8 |
3 | 72.0 | 81.9 | 77.6 | 63.0 |
4 | 81.9 | 101.2 | 87.6 | 67.0 |
Industry: BEA Economic Area | Revenue Share | Data: | Data: | Data: | BEKJ
Only Model
|
Full Model
|
Chocolate Candy (NAICS 311330): Harrisburg, PA | .07 | 9.2 | 1.4 | 6.4 | 1.3 | 4.2 |
Chocolate Candy (NAICS 311330): Nashville, TN | .06 | 6.6 | .8 | 7.9 | 1.4 | 3.8 |
Chocolate Candy (NAICS 311330): Chicago, IL | .15 | 4.1 | 1.2 | 3.6 | 1.4 | 3.0 |
Chocolate Candy (NAICS 311330): Philadelphia, PA | .08 | 3.3 | 2.1 | 1.6 | 1.2 | 2.5 |
Chocolate Candy (NAICS 311330): San Francisco, CA | .08 | 2.3 | 1.5 | 1.6 | 0.4 | 1.3 |
Nonchocolate Candy (NAICS 311340): Grand Rapids, MI | .07 | 11.2 | 1.2 | 9.2 | 1.3 | 4.5 |
Nonchocolate Candy (NAICS 311340): Chicago, IL | .24 | 6.8 | 1.5 | 4.6 | 1.4 | 3.8 |
Nonchocolate Candy (NAICS 311340): Atlanta, GA | .07 | 3.5 | .8 | 4.5 | 1.2 | 2.5 |
Curtains (NAICS 312121): San Antonio, TX | .07 | 10.3 | .6 | 16.8 | 0.6 | 7.0 |
Curtains (NAICS 312121): Raleigh-Durham, NC | .09 | 10.1 | 1.1 | 8.9 | 1.3 | 8.3 |
Curtains (NAICS 312121): Charlotte, NC | .06 | 7.6 | 1.7 | 4.5 | 1.3 | 6.7 |
Curtains (NAICS 312121): Boston, MA | .07 | 2.5 | 1.4 | 1.8 | 1.0 | 2.4 |
Other Apparel (NAICS 315999): New York, NY | .28 | 3.5 | 2.6 | 1.4 | 1.4 | 2.3 |
Other Apparel (NAICS 315999): Los Angeles, CA | .16 | 2.5 | 2.1 | 1.2 | 0.9 | 1.5 |
Kitchen Cabinets (NAICS 337110): Harrisburg, PA | .05 | 7.4 | 1.7 | 4.4 | 2.9 | 5.5 |
Kitchen Cabinets (NAICS 337110): Dallas, TX | .05 | 2.4 | 1.0 | 2.4 | 1.0 | 1.8 |
Upholstered Household Furn. (NAICS 337121): Tupelo, MS | .21 | 107.4 | 43.4 | 2.5 | 1.5 | 2.9 |
Upholstered Household Furn. (NAICS 337121): Charlotte, NC | .19 | 23.2 | 11.3 | 2.1 | 1.8 | 3.3 |
Upholstered Household Furn. (NAICS 337121): Knoxville, TN | .09 | 22.2 | 2.6 | 8.6 | 1.7 | 3.1 |
Upholstered Household Furn. (NAICS 337121): High Point, NC | .12 | 19.2 | 11.0 | 1.8 | 1.7 | 3.2 |
Wood Household Furn. (NAICS 337122): High Point, NC | .17 | 27.7 | 4.2 | 6.6 | 1.6 | 6.9 |
Wood Household Furn. (NAICS 337122): Charlotte, NC | .13 | 15.5 | 2.9 | 5.4 | 1.5 | 5.8 |
Wood Household Furn. (NAICS 337122): Toledo, OH | .05 | 13.5 | .8 | 17.5 | 1.2 | 4.8 |
Summary Statistics: 7 Reclassification
Industries: = 23 Industry Locations: Mean |
.11 | 14.0 | 4.3 | 5.4 | 1.3 | 4.0 |
Summary Statistics : 7 Reclassification
Industries: = 23 Industry Locations: Median |
.08 | 7.6 | 1.5 | 4.5 | 1.3 | 3.2 |
Summary Statistics: 165 Remaining
Diffuse Demand: = 566 Industry Locations: Mean |
.11 | 18.3 | 5.9 | 5.3 | 1.2 | 3.3 |
Summary Statistics: 165 Remaining
Diffuse Demand: = 566 Industry Locations: Median |
.09 | 9.3 | 2.9 | 2.6 | 1.1 | 2.5 |
Import Share of Shipments
(Percent): 1997 |
Import Share of Shipments
(Percent): 2007 |
China Share of Imports
(Percent): 1997 |
China Share of Imports
(Percent): 2007 |
Employment Growth
1997-2007 (Percent) |
Mean Plant
Employment: 1997 |
Mean Plant
Employment: 2007 |
|
Industry: Curtains | 8 | 56 | 38 | 65 | -47 | 12 | 9 |
Industry: Other Household Textile Prod. | 22 | 68 | 25 | 49 | -51 | 64 | 36 |
Industry: Women's Cut & Sew Dress | 29 | 67 | 21 | 55 | -71 | 37 | 22 |
Industry: Women's Cut & Sew Suit | 48 | 92 | 19 | 49 | -91 | 46 | 17 |
Industry: Infants' Cut & Sew Apparel | 60 | 99 | 08 | 62 | -97 | 178 | 11 |
Industry: Hat, Cap, & Millinery | 44 | 80 | 26 | 67 | -74 | 44 | 30 |
Industry: Glove & Mitten | 58 | 88 | 50 | 63 | -78 | 49 | 26 |
Industry: Men's & Boys' Neckwear | 25 | 56 | 02 | 59 | -67 | 40 | 37 |
Industry: Other Apparel | 39 | 80 | 35 | 64 | -75 | 14 | 12 |
Industry: Blankbook, Loose-leaf Binder | 18 | 47 | 43 | 52 | -51 | 59 | 42 |
Industry: Power-Driven Handtool | 28 | 56 | 18 | 46 | -56 | 77 | 48 |
Industry: Electronic Computer | 12 | 49 | 00 | 56 | -68 | 179 | 75 |
Industry: Electric Housewares & Fans | 52 | 78 | 48 | 76 | -54 | 124 | 77 |
Industry: Wood Household Furniture | 29 | 62 | 18 | 46 | -51 | 33 | 18 |
Industry: Metal Household Furniture | 29 | 55 | 37 | 85 | -48 | 54 | 36 |
Industry: Silverware & Plated Ware | 44 | 91 | 31 | 73 | -82 | 39 | 11 |
Industry: Costume Jewelry & Novelty | 31 | 68 | 31 | 67 | -63 | 16 | 10 |
Industry: Mean of China Surge Industries ( = 17) | 34 | 70 | 26 | 61 | -66 | 63 | 30 |
Industry: Mean of Food/Beverage
Comparison Group Industries ( = 35) |
8 | 11 | 02 | 7 | 5 | 84 | 81 |
Sources: See Data Appendix.
Employment Size Class | Plant Size
Cell Counts in United States: 1997 |
Plant Size
Cell Counts in United States: 2007 |
Plant Size
Cell Counts in Primary Location (High Point): 1997 |
Plant Size
Cell Counts in Primary Location (High Point): 2007 |
1 to 19 | 3,091 | 3,079 | 51 | 29 |
20 to 49 | 323 | 278 | 9 | 6 |
50 to 99 | 165 | 95 | 6 | 5 |
100 to 249 | 130 | 68 | 8 | 3 |
250 to 499 | 78 | 28 | 13 | 7 |
500 to 999 | 36 | 15 | 9 | 3 |
1,000 and above | 12 | 5 | 5 | 0 |
Source: The cell counts are based on public tabulations from the Census discussed in Appendix B. The High Point, NC Area consists of the BEA Economic Area containing High Point, NC (consisting of 22 counties). For each industry, the Primary Location is the Economic Area with the highest sales revenue location quotient, among locations with at least 5 percent of U.S. sales.
Industry or Industry Group | 1997 Data: | 1997 Data: | 2007: BEJK
China Surge
|
2007: Data
|
Wood Furniture in High Point, NC | 6.6 | 27.7 | 28.4 | 12.8 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): Mean | 7.9 | 26.9 | 29.4 | 12.2 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): Medan | 3.8 | 19.6 | 21.7 | 5.3 |
Food/Beverage
Comparison Group ( = 34): Mean |
5.9 | 35.3 | 36.7 | 29.8 |
Food/Beverage
Comparison Group ( = 34): Median |
3.3 | 19.0 | 21.1 | 12.3 |
Note: 1997 primary industry location is location with highest of those locations with at least 5 percent of industry sales.
Industry or Industry Group | 1997 Data: | 1997 Data: | 2007: BEJK
China Surge
|
2007: Data
|
Wood Furniture | .45 | .44 | .42 | .57 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): Mean | .78 | .97 | .97 | 1.08 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): Median | .79 | .87 | .87 | 1.06 |
Food/Beverage
Comparison Group ( = 35): Mean |
.94 | .91 | .90 | .90 |
Food/Beverage
Comparison Group ( = 35): Median |
.93 | .89 | .89 | .90 |
Note: The 20 largest economic areas by population are grouped into one aggregate big city area. The statistics reported in the table are calculated for the big city area being treated as a single location.
Panel A: Summary Statistics for Count Quotients of Primary Location of Industry
Industry or Industry Group | Data
|
Data
|
Pure BEJK Model
|
Pure BEJK Model
|
General Model with Specialty Segment
|
General Model with Specialty Segment
|
Wood Furniture in High Point ( = 1) | 4.2 | 2.3 | 17.7 | 22.0 | 4.0 | 3.0 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): Mean | 5.8 | 3.9 | 24.5 | 28.6 | 6.8 | 5.5 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): Median | 4.2 | 2.9 | 17.0 | 17.5 | 4.8 | 3.5 |
Food/Beverage
Comparison Group ( = 34): Mean |
10.6 | 10.7 | 30.0 | 34.8 | 13.4 | 10.9 |
Food/Beverage
Comparison Group ( = 34): Median |
4.8 | 4.2 | 15.4 | 17.7 | 5.3 | 3.8 |
Panel B: Prediction Regression Results, on for the Two Models
Industry or Industry Group | Mean Slope
(Mean std. err.) |
Mean |
Wood Furniture ( = 1): Pure BEJK Model | -.27
(.06) |
.096 |
Wood Furniture ( = 1): General Model with Specialty Segment | .93
(.17) |
.140 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): Pure BEJK Model | -.06
(.18) |
.036 |
China Surge Industries ( = 17): General Model with Specialty Segment | .89
(.32) |
.084 |
Food/Beverage Comparison Group ( = 35): Pure BEJK Model | .17
(.15) |
.043 |
Food/Beverage Comparison Group ( = 35): General Model with Spec. Seg. | .33
(.32) |
.046 |
Note: Each regression used to construct results in Panel B has 177 Economic Area observations. Observations are weighted by 1997 population. The table reports means across the industries for each group of industries.
Panel A: Wood Household Furniture (1 Industry)
Plant Counts (Number): 1997 | Plant Counts (Number): 2007 | Shares (Percent): 1997 | Shares (Percent): 2007 | |
Standardized | 697 | 213 | 18.1 | 6.2 |
Specialty | 3,150 | 3,215 | 81.9 | 93.8 |
Total | 3,847 | 3,428 | 100.0 | 100.0 |
Panel B: All China Surge Industries (17 Industries)
Plant Counts (Number): 1997 | Plant Counts (Number): 2007 | Shares (Percent): 1997 | Shares (Percent): 2007 | |
Standardized | 3,783 | 1,371 | 29.1 | 15.7 |
Specialty | 9,207 | 7,380 | 70.9 | 84.3 |
Total | 12,990 | 8,751 | 100.0 | 100.0 |
Panel C: Food and Beverage Industries (35 Industries)
Plant Counts (Number): 1997 | Plant Counts (Number): 2007 | Shares (Percent): 1997 | Shares (Percent): 2007 | |
Standardized | 4,234 | 5,390 | 27.4 | 32.7 |
Specialty | 11,216 | 11,092 | 72.6 | 67.3 |
Total | 15,450 | 16,482 | 100.0 | 100.0 |
Panel D: Remaining Diffuse Demand Industries (120 Industries)
Plant Counts (Number): 1997 | Plant Counts (Number): 2007 | Shares (Percent): 1997 | Shares (Percent): 2007 | |
Standardized | 31,969 | 26,568 | 26.1 | 23.5 |
Specialty | 90,388 | 86,432 | 73.9 | 76.5 |
Total | 122,357 | 113,000 | 100.0 | 100.0 |
Number of Industries | Distance Shipped: 100 to 500 | Distance Shipped: 500 to 1,000 | Distance Shipped: Over 1,000 | |
Industry Grouping: Data, All Sample Industries | 172 | 0.43 | 0.30 | 0.26 |
Industry Grouping: Model, All Sample Industries | 172 | 0.38 | 0.33 | 0.30 |
Industry Grouping: Data, (100).5 | 15 | 0.89 | 0.09 | 0.03 |
Industry Grouping: Model, (100).5 | 15 | 0.77 | 0.17 | 0.06 |
Industry Grouping: Data, .5 (100) .75 | 31 | 0.57 | 0.27 | 0.16 |
Industry Grouping: Model, .5 (100) .75 | 31 | 0.48 | 0.31 | 0.20 |
Industry Grouping: Data, .75 (100) .9 | 73 | 0.41 | 0.32 | 0.27 |
Industry Grouping: Model, .75 (100) .9 | 73 | 0.35 | 0.34 | 0.31 |
Industry Grouping: Data, .9 (100) | 53 | 0.34 | 0.32 | 0.34 |
Industry Grouping: Model, .9 (100) | 53 | 0.28 | 0.34 | 0.38 |
Number of Industries | Distance Shipped: Under 100 | Distance Shipped: 100 to 500 | Distance Shipped: 500 to 1,000 | Distance Shipped: Over 1,000 | |
Industry Grouping: Data, All Sample Industries | 172 | 0.27 | 0.32 | 0.22 | 0.19 |
Industry Grouping: Model, All Sample Industries | 172 | 0.11 | 0.34 | 0.29 | 0.27 |
Industry Grouping: Data, (100).5 | 15 | 0.65 | 0.31 | 0.03 | 0.01 |
Industry Grouping: Model, (100).5 | 15 | 0.39 | 0.47 | 0.10 | 0.04 |
Industry Grouping: Data, .5 (100) .75 | 31 | 0.33 | 0.39 | 0.18 | 0.11 |
Industry Grouping: Model, .5 (100) .75 | 31 | 0.14 | 0.42 | 0.27 | 0.18 |
Industry Grouping: Data, .75 (100) .9 | 73 | 0.22 | 0.32 | 0.25 | 0.21 |
Industry Grouping: Model, .75 (100) .9 | 73 | 0.08 | 0.33 | 0.32 | 0.28 |
Industry Grouping: Data, .9 (100) | 53 | 0.19 | 0.28 | 0.26 | 0.28 |
Industry Grouping: Model, .9 (100) | 53 | 0.05 | 0.26 | 0.33 | 0.36 |
Industry Grouping | 1997 NAICS
Industry Sample: Number of Industries |
1997 NAICS
Industry Sample: Mean of Ton-Mile Wholesale Share (Percent out of 100) |
1992 SIC
Industry Sample: Number of Industries |
1992 SIC
Industry Sample: Mean of Ton-Mile Wholesale Share (Percent out of 100) |
All Sample Industries | 172 | 24.4 | 175 | 24.2 |
By value of (100) for industry: Below .50 | 15 | 15.6 | 14 | 11.4 |
By value of (100) for industry: From .50 to .75 | 31 | 15.0 | 35 | 18.2 |
By value of (100) for industry: From .75 to .90 | 73 | 27.1 | 88 | 27.3 |
By value of (100) for industry: Above .90 | 53 | 28.7 | 38 | 27.3 |