The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2010-32 Screen Reader version

Consumption Responses to Permanent and Transitory Shocks to House Appreciation1

Juan Contreras
Congressional Budget Office
Joseph Nichols
Federal Reserve Board
April 7, 2010



Keywords: Life cycle, marginal propensity to consume, house prices

Abstract:

We estimate the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of permanent and transitory shocks to house price appreciation. We consider two different models under which those shocks may affect consumption. In the first one, housing is a risky asset. In the second one, housing has a role as a consumption and as an investment good. In both, changes in the rate of house price appreciation may affect nonhousing consumption. Shocks to appreciation rates may happen when increases in future house prices are expected to differ from the current ones because heterogeneity, market failures or errors in expectations. We test the implications of those models empirically using the PSID's imputed total consumption from food consumption and self-reported house values, and base our identification strategy on two sources of variation in the appreciation rate. The first source depends on the fact that home prices are far more cyclical in areas where the supply of housing is relatively inelastic. The second source is households' perceptions about which parts of shocks to appreciation rates are permanent or transitory. We model households' self-reported rate of appreciation as an AR(1) process and use both the Hodrick-Prescott and the Kalman filter to separate households' perceptions about permanent and transitory shocks to appreciation. Our results show that (1) consumption responses to house wealth shocks vary greatly by area and depend upon the area-specific levels of temporal persistence and variance of those shocks; (2) the overall MPC out of those shocks is 3.5%; (3) the MPC out of permanent shocks is between 3.4% and 9.1%; and (4) the MPC out of transitory shocks is between 0.5% and 3.3%.

JEL Classification: E21, R10, D91

1 Introduction

One of the main implications of the permanent income/life-cycle hypothesis is that households are likely to have smaller changes in consumption when they face transitory unexpected fluctuations to their total resources than when they face permanent unexpected shocks to those resources. Most empirical tests of that implication have focused on the response to income shocks, which are easier to identify than shocks to financial wealth as temporary or permanent.2 In addition, most macroeconomic models assume that the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of wealth is constant over time and across households. In this paper we use household-level data to generate separate estimates of the MPC out of permanent and out of transitory shocks to housing wealth appreciation by exploiting geographical differences in the cyclicality of house prices.3

The advantage of using housing wealth to generate our estimates of the MPC out of permanent and transitory shocks is that, unlike shocks to financial assets, the returns to housing differ greatly across households depending on where they live. In areas with significant constraints on the supply of housing, such as in coastal states, a positive demand shock is more likely to result in higher permanent prices, while in areas without such constraints such a price shock would be largely transitory, as supply increases in response to the demand shock. The resulting difference in house price dynamics is observable to both homeowners and econometricians, providing a unique opportunity to identify separately the elasticities of consumption to permanent and to transitory shocks to housing price appreciation.4

The effect of housing wealth on consumption is a vital issue for macroeconomic forecasters. Housing wealth plays a central role in the economy: Families hold almost 70 percent of their assets in the form of housing wealth, and the construction sector represents 35 percent of total gross private domestic investment, not counting the spillovers to other sectors.5 The extent to which significant housing appreciation might support higher consumption during a housing boom and the extent to which consumption might fall when the home values decline, play a vital role in forecasting macroeconomic activity.

We start by examining two different models through which housing wealth may affect consumption, other than through borrowing constraints. The first model considers housing as a risky asset, and shocks to the return of that asset (i.e. shocks to housing appreciation) have an effect on consumption. The second model considers housing as both a consumption good and an investment good and shows that, even for households not bound by borrowing constraints, shocks in the rate of housing price appreciation can also affect consumption when an increase in the house prices today is not expected to be exactly matched by the same increase in the future, resulting in differences in the user cost of housing over time and generating a wealth effect.

Shocks to appreciation rates may happen when increases in future house prices are expected to differ from the current ones because of heterogeneity, market failures or incorrect expectations. If this is the case, the wealth effect of a higher house price in the present would not be canceled out by higher housing expenses in the future. Heterogeneity in house price appreciation across regions, for example, make it feasible to take advantage of an increase in the house price in one region without the need of sacrificing housing consumption when the household expects to move to another region with cheaper houses. Market failures may cause the rents to be disconnected from the house prices, such that when house prices increase the rental price does not, resulting in a wealth effect. And incorrect expectations may cause consumers to think that house prices will keep increasing in such a way that an increase in the house price today would imply an even higher increase in the price tomorrow, generating again a wealth effect.

In the first model housing is considered a risky asset and assumed to be the only asset that agents can hold to insure against income shocks. However, returns are stochastic, adding a source of uncertainty in the household's decision problem. Our numerical simulations show that a household's MPC depends on three key variables: first, the size and nature of the appreciation shocks, that is, whether they are transitory or permanent; second, the persistence of those appreciation shocks, that is, the length of time that a shock to appreciation continue to have an effect; and third, the variance of the shock. We find that permanent shocks have a greater effect on consumption than transitory shocks and that households facing a higher variance of shocks can be expected to have a higher MPC out of both permanent and transitory shocks. A higher MPC out of permanent income shocks is a standard result in the consumption literature. Kimball (1990) found that the MPC is also an increasing function of income variation, because the increased variation increases the slope of the decision rule on consumption. That effect results from a decrease in the agent's "prudence" (that is, the strength of the precautionary saving motive measured as a function of the third derivative of the utility function). The intuition behind this result, as Kimball points out, is that in addition to loosening the budget constraint, the larger income shocks diminish the consumer's prudence in allocating resources and encourage extra consumption. The same intuition applies to our case. A positive wealth shock, which is the extension pursued in this paper, increases the buffer stock of savings and encourages higher consumption.

In the second model, when housing is considered as both a consumption and an investment good, shocks to house prices alone do not generate movements in consumption. This is consistent with some recent papers that question the causal link between changes in housing wealth and consumption. However, when house prices in the future are expected to be higher than house prices today, shocks to the rate of return on housing (i.e. house price appreciation shocks) do affect consumption. In addition, the presence of binding borrowing constraints are sufficient to establish a causal connection between housing wealth and consumption. In this model, the role of housing as collateral to relax household's borrowing constraints is explicitly considered. Even some critics of the existence of a significant housing wealth effect (such as Attanasio et al.) do find some evidence of changes in housing wealth impacting consumption through such a channel. In models without housing as collateral, an increase in house prices today simply increases the cost of housing tomorrow, with no impact on consumption.

Whether house price appreciation shocks affect consumption and whether they have permanent and transitory components are empirical questions. In a world with efficient markets, shocks to house price appreciation would be arbitraged away in the market. But in a market with frictions and heterogeneous consumers and sub-markets like the housing market, those arbitrage possibilities may take time to disappear, and price bubbles might occur, causing the shocks in price appreciation to be perceived as persistent.

In the empirical section, we use data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) to estimate the variation of shocks in housing prices across census divisions in order to test the predictions of the theory, namely, that (i) households in divisions where the shocks to home prices are more persistent over time will have a higher MPC, and (ii) households in divisions with higher volatility of prices will have a higher MPC due to a precautionary saving motive that induces an upward-sloping consumption profile.6 We impute total consumption from the PSID measure of food consumption. Our measure of home prices is the self-reported house value.

We also estimate the MPC out of permanent and transitory shocks to housing appreciation at the household level, to test the classical life-cycle permanent income hypothesis that the response to permanent shocks dominates the response to transitory shocks.7 We use two alternative statistical filters to model the process through which households can determine which part of the house price appreciation is transitory and which is permanent. The first is the Hodrick and Prescott filter (HP) (Hodrick and Prescott ,1997) filter which uses a simple method to determine which part of a series represents the trend and which represents fluctuations around that trend. The second filter we use is a Kalman filter, which represents the process by which households can learn about the rate of appreciation for their own house.

We then estimate the process for house price appreciation and estimate the MPC out of housing wealth. The house price appreciation process consists of two components: (1) a deterministic component that depends on the characteristics of the home, and (2) a shock to house appreciation. Our analysis focuses on the consumption responses to those appreciation shocks.8

Our main empirical results are consistent with our theoretical predictions. First, households in areas that have higher persistence in the shocks or higher variability in those shocks do in fact have a higher MPC out of housing wealth. Second, the consumption responses to permanent shocks in appreciation are higher than those to transitory shocks. Specifically, the point estimate of the MPC out of shocks to housing wealth is 3.5 percent, the the point estimate of the MPC out of permanent shocks to housing wealth is between 3.4 percent and 9.1 percent, and the MPC out of transitory shocks is between 0.5 percent and 3.3 percent, depending on how we measure the permanent and transitory shocks.

Although most papers in the housing literature have estimated an MPC out of housing that is constant across all households, our estimates for the elasticity to permanent shocks to housing wealth are nearer the higher end of the ranges estimated in these papers, and our estimates of the elasticity to temporary shocks are significantly lower. Benjamin, Chinloy, and Jun (2004) estimate an elasticity of consumption to housing wealth of 8 percent. Bostic, Gabriel, and Painter (2009) report a slightly lower estimates of 5.7 percent, using micro data from the Survey of Consumer Finances and the Consumer Expenditure Survey. They also observe that estimates for these elasticities fell from 1989 to 2001. Juster et al. (2006) use the PSID to estimate the effect of household capital gains, including gains in housing wealth, on saving and find that a dollar increase in housing gains decreases saving between 1.3 cents and 3.2 cents over a 5-year period, although their estimates are not statistically significant different from zero.

A frequent challenge for studies of the MPC out of housing wealth is the potential endogeneity between housing values, consumption and unobserved variables in the error term that may contain information about future income or wealth. The concern is that any observed correlation between increasing house prices and increasing consumption is not due to a causal link, but instead to a common factor such as expected future income shocks.9

Several papers have argued recently that once this endogeneity between consumption and housing has been accounted for, the MPC out of housing is no longer significant. Calomiris et al. (2009) take the state-level model from Case, Quigley, and Shiller (2005) and reestimate it both with lagged values of housing wealth, stock wealth, and income using those lagged values as instruments for the contemporaneous changes in the measures. They find that although the MPC out of financial wealth remains significant, the MPC out of housing wealth is no longer significant in this specification.

In a related paper, Attanasio et al. (2009) test the hypothesis that co-movements in consumption and house prices are both driven by income expectations. The authors utilize U.K. household panel data to generate estimates of expected home price changes at the divisional level using divisional measures of earnings growth and the real interest rate. They examine the correlation between the residuals from regressing log consumption on a set of demographic variables including age and the log real house prices for the region interacted with age dummies. The finding that younger households, fewer of which are homeowners, had higher correlations than older households is taken as evidence that the co-movement was not driven by wealth effects and instead represented the impact of income expectations.

Muellbauer (2009) provides a counterargument to several of these papers, in particular Attanasio et al. (2009). He uses quarterly U.K. time-series data to show that, even if households had perfect foresight into future income growth, the MPC out of housing would still be significant. He also shows that the result continues to hold when the perfect-foresight assumption is relaxed. Muellbauer reinterprets Attanasio's results, suggesting that they may reflect the impact of housing's role as collateral in relaxing borrowing constraints.

We explicitly address the concerns regarding possible endogeneity between housing and consumption. First, we use a micro panel dataset containing information on both housing and consumption, as opposed to cross-sectional data (Bover), aggregated regional data (Case, Quigley, and Shiller or Calomiris et al.), or panel consumption data combined with regional house price data (Attanasio et al.). The use of panel data allows us to include a measure of the permanent income of the household, in order to control for the extent to which both housing wealth and consumption are simply responding to differences in expected future income. In addition, this approach allows us to take advantage of the significant variation in shocks to home prices within, rather than only between, markets. This intraregional variation can account for a significant amount of the variation in house prices (see Bourassa et al. (2009) and many others). In addition, although self-reported home values may contain significant biases (see Goodman and Ittner (1992)), it is precisely the household perception of changes in home values that drives household changes in consumption, even if these perceptions prove to be incorrect.

The second significant way in which we attempt to address these concerns regarding endogeneity is by focusing on shocks in the rate of appreciation in housing, and not on shocks to housing wealth. As we show in our theoretical section, a household's consumption may respond to shocks to the appreciation rate of housing, even when shocks in the level of housing wealth would have no effect. As mentioned above, restrictions on land, either physical or via zoning, can result in more inelastic supply and greater variation in the response of appreciation rates to exogenous shocks.10

The paper is divided into six sections. Section 2 develops the theoretical arguments on when changes in house prices may affect consumption. Section 3 describes the data we use. Section 4 describes the way we model the house price appreciation process and households' expectation formation. That section also presents some evidence on the divisional variation in the trend and shocks to house prices. Section 5 presents and discusses our results on the divisional variation in the MPC out of housing wealth and on the differentiated responses to permanent and transitory shocks to housing wealth. Section 6 concludes.

2 Some theoretical background: how might shocks to house appreciation affect consumption?

2.1 Housing as a risky asset

We develop a simple model that illustrates two key implications of the life-cycle/permanent-income hypothesis. The first implication is the well-known result that households are likely to have bigger changes in consumption in response to an unexpected permanent shock to wealth than in response to an unexpected transitory shock. The second implication, which is an extension from Kimball (1990), is that higher uncertainty in the return to wealth results in higher marginal propensity to consume out of wealth. The intuition behind this second implication is less obvious than the first. In brief, higher uncertainty increases the motive for buffer stock saving, which in turn increases wealth over the life cycle, resulting in wealthier households having a corresponding higher MPC out of further changes in wealth.

In this initial exploration, we have attempted to keep our theoretical model as simple and straightforward as possible. We have left out many of the unique aspects of housing in this setting (but we retake them later), such as its presence in the utility function, the large transaction costs associated with adjusting the level of housing consumption, the use of housing as collateral, and the household's portfolio allocation between housing and financial wealth. The goal of this paper is, besides exploring the geographical variation in consumption responses, to explore the relative impact of permanent and transitory shocks to wealth. We therefore include a single asset, henceforth referred to as housing wealth, in a model that has risky returns with both permanent and transitory shocks. The nature of the shocks is the only innovation we have made to the canonical infinite-horizon consumption model with idiosyncratic income shocks and a single risky asset, which is the only source of insurance given the incomplete markets structure.

Consumption is determined by identical households that receive income shocks and cannot fully insure against them. Partial insurance is given by housing wealth, which in turn has an uncertain return  r_t. Households solve the following problem:

\displaystyle \max_{\{c_t\}_{t=0}^{\infty}}{\sum_{t=0}^{\infty}\beta^{t}U(c_t)}\quad s.t\quad a_{t+1}=(1+r_t)a_t+y_t-c_t (1)

where  a_t is housing wealth,  r_t is the rate of return on housing wealth,  y_t represents income and  c_t is consumption. The utility function is:
\displaystyle U(c)=\frac{c^{1-\gamma}-1}{1-\gamma} (2)

The stochastic income is parameterized as  y_t=\delta y_{t-1}+\mu_t, where  \mu_t\sim N(0,\sigma_{\mu}^2), and the returns to housing are parameterized as  (1+r_t)=\rho (1+r_{t-1})+\nu_t, where  \nu_t\sim N(0,\sigma_{\nu}^2). Note that in the current version of the model the shocks to income and housing wealth are completely independent. This parameterization of the returns to housing allows us to analyze a range of different cases, from purely permanent shocks ( \rho=1) to purely transitory shocks ( \rho=0).

We can then rewrite the household's optimization problem in a dynamic programming framework, with primes ("  ' ") denoting next-period variables,

\displaystyle V(y,r,a)=\max_{c}{\{U(c)+\beta E V(e',a',r')\}}\quad s.t\quad a'=(1+r)a+y-c (3)

The first order condition for consumption provides us with the classic Euler equation:
\displaystyle \quad U_c=\beta E\{U_c(c')(1+r)\} (4)

The optimal consumption rule solution consists of a decision rule for consumption as a function of housing wealth in the current period and the realizations of the shocks to income and to the return to housing wealth.

Income is parameterized following Aiyagari (1994) with  \rho=0.9 and  \sigma_{\mu}=0.4. We choose widely accepted values for  \gamma=2 and  \beta=0.88, indicating a discount rate per year of 0.96 and a model period of 3 years.

We want to know how the MPC out of housing wealth changes when the persistence parameter and the standard deviation of the shocks change, as well as how consumption responds to permanent and transitory shocks to housing wealth. Table 1 and Figure 1 show the results of the simulations and provide the main implications of the model. The MPC out of housing wealth increases with the persistence and the standard deviation of the shocks. Our simple model thus is able to recreate two key implications of the life-cycle/permanent-income hypothesis we are interested in exploring: permanent shocks to wealth induce higher consumption than transitory shocks, as does a higher variation of shocks.


Table 1. MPC as a function of Persistence  \rho and Standard deviation  \sigma_{\nu}
Standard deviation (  \sigma_{\nu}): 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05
Persistence ( \rho): 0 0.0272 0.0482 0.0706 0.0933 0.1197
Persistence ( \rho): 0.5 0.0316 0.0573 0.0838 0.1139 0.1465
Persistence ( \rho): 0.8 0.0427 0.0807 0.1313 0.1836 0.2398
Persistence ( \rho): 0.85 0.0495 0.052 0.1534 0.208 0.2779
Persistence ( \rho): 0 0.0587 0.1172 0.1828 0.2644 0.3617
Persistence ( \rho): 0.95 0.0791 0.162 0.2651 0.4191 0.473
Persistence ( \rho): 0.99 0.1804 0.3729 0.3847 0.4669 0.505

Figure 1: Theoretical MPC as a function of the persistence and variation of returns to housing
Figure 1: Theoretical MPC as a function of the persistence and variation of returns to housing.  Chart presents a 3-D surface plot of the values of the MPC, from equation (3), for a range of different values of persistence ($\rho$) and variation ($\sigma_{\nu}$) of the returns on housing.  The values plotted are from the same process that generated the values in Table 1.  The plot shows that the MPC of housing is an increasing function of both persistence ($\rho$) and  variation ($\sigma_{\nu}$) but is more sensitive to persistence.  In particular, there appears to be a sharp kink in the surface plot where $\rho = 0.8$, while the effects of $\sigma_{\nu}$ seem to be more linear.

Summarizing, according to the previous model the theoretical predictions are:

2.2 Housing as a consumption and as an investment good

This model introduces housing into the utility function, such that households perceive it as an investment and as a consumption good. We also introduce the possibility of borrowing constraints and a price of housing that is different from the numeraire in the model (which represents all other type of consumption). The model is based on Yang (2008) and Li and Yao (2007). We take the notation and the set-up of the problem from Jeske (2005) and follow closely his discussion.

In this model households derive utility from nonhousing consumption  c and housing consumption  h. They solve the following problem:

\displaystyle V(a,y)=max\{u(c,h)+\beta EV(a',y') +\mu a'\} (5)

s.t.
\displaystyle c+P_h h+b' \displaystyle = \displaystyle wy+a  
\displaystyle a' \displaystyle = \displaystyle (1-\delta)P_h h+(1+r)b'  
\displaystyle b' \displaystyle \ge \displaystyle (1-\gamma)h  
\displaystyle c,h \displaystyle \ge 0  

where  \beta is the discount rate,  y is labor productivity,  w is the wage rate,  a is assets at the beginning of the period, and  b represents other savings.  \gamma represents the portion of the home's value that the household can borrow against in the market; it may also represent the initial down payment.  P_h is the relative price of housing,  \delta represents depreciation and  \mu represents the lagrange multiplier associated with the borrowing constraint. The first order conditions of the problem are:


\displaystyle u_c(c,h) \displaystyle = \displaystyle \beta Eu_c(c',h')(1+r) + \mu (1+r)\qquad consumption (6)
\displaystyle u_c(c,h) \displaystyle = \displaystyle \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad housing (7)
    \displaystyle u_h(c,h)+\beta Eu_c(c',h')P_h'(1-\delta)+\mu P_h[(1-\delta)-(1+r)(1-\gamma)] (8)

We can combine these to get an intratemporal condition relating housing and nonhousing consumption:
\displaystyle \frac{u_h(c,h)}{u_c(c,h)}=(1-\frac{\mu}{u_c(c,h)})(1-\frac{P'_h}{P_h}\frac{1-\delta}{1+r})+\frac{\mu}{u_c(c,h)}\gamma (9)

In the equations above, one can observe that the borrowing constraint would affect consumption when the lagrange multiplier  \mu is active and the constraint is binding. This would affect both the housing and the non-housing consumption and the ratio between them.

On the other hand, increments in prices alone would not affect consumption because an increase in the house prices today implies they will also be higher tomorrow, and because prices enter as a ratio in the user cost of capital component of the equation (8) (this is, in the expression  (1-\frac{P'_h}{P_h}\frac{1-\delta}{1+r})), that term does not change. The intuition behind this result is that the wealth effect of a higher house price today is canceled out with the increase in the cost of housing today and tomorrow, so that households wouldn't change total consumption.

The conditions under which an increase in house prices do not affect consumption are rarely met. They imply homogeneous consumers and markets, perfectly competitive markets, and correct households expectations. As a result, an increase in the house price today does not necessarily mean an increase of the same amount in the future, even if household expectations about this change are in fact correct. For example, housing markets are heterogeneous and the cost of housing varies enormously from region to region as we will show later. Under those circumstances, by moving to other regions, households could consume the same amount of housing at a lower cost, realizing the wealth gains from the increase in house prices. At the same time, in a world with efficient markets, shocks in house price appreciation would be arbitraged away in the market. But in a market with frictions and heterogeneous consumers and sub-markets like the housing market, those arbitrage possibilities may take time to disappear, and price bubbles might occur, causing the shocks in price appreciation to be perceived as persistent. Because of those reasons, a change in the ratio of prices tomorrow to prices today is likely to happen, in reality affecting total consumption.

3 Data

We use data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics to analyze the house price process by census division and to calculate the MPC out of total, permanent and transitory shocks to housing appreciation.

The PSID is a longitudinal dataset of a representative sample of U.S. households and the families in which they reside. It started at 1968 with an original focus on the dynamics of poverty, having as a result a disproportionately large number of low-income households in the sample. To accomplish this goal, the survey consists of two independent samples: a cross-sectional national sample drawn by the Survey Research Center consisting of 2,930 interviews, and a national sample of low-income families from the Survey of Economic Opportunity consisting of 1,872 families. In order to obtain a representative sample, each of the individuals has a specific weight in the whole dataset. Since then, individuals belonging to those 4,800 households have been traced by the PSID whether or not they still live in the same household or with the same people. Later additions to the sample are not included in the dataset, specifically the Latino sample included after 1990. We use the data from 1970 to 1995.

Our analysis is limited to an unbalanced subsample of households from the PSID where we observe at least four pairs of subsequent survey years that contain information on both food consumption and self-reported home value. This restriction naturally excludes households that broke-up between survey years. The subsample is limited to households who own their own home, did not move between the two survey years, had two adult members, and had the same number of children in each survey year. We also screen the sample for outliers, excluding observations where the change in consumption or house value was in the upper or lower 1 percent of the sample. The resulting sample consists of 14,831 observations from 2,553 households. As is discussed in more detail below, for purposes of filtering the appreciation shocks to housing, we limit our analysis to households who do not move. The resulting sample consists of 6,959 observations from 1,667 households.

The PSID lacks information on total consumption, so we impute the level of total consumption based on the reported level of food consumption, paying attention to the critique of Attanasio and Weber (1995), who show that food consumption alone is not a good measure of consumption to estimate its responses to changes in income or other behavioral parameters. We follow Lehnert (2005), who estimates the relationship between total consumption, food away from home, and food at home from the Consumer Expenditure Survey. We use the same coefficients here, so the equation to impute total consumption is as follow:  log(total consumption)=5.4294+0.2725*log(food away from home)+0.3612*log(food at home).

4 The house price appreciation process

House prices vary significantly by division, demonstrating the well-known fact that housing markets are regional (Table 2). Our divisions are New England, Mid-Atlantic, South Atlantic, East South Central, West South Central, East North Central, West North Central, Mountain, and Pacific.

Table 2 shows that the Pacific division has the highest average and median prices, followed by New England, and the West and East South Central divisions have the lowest average and median prices. Prices are most volatile in the Pacific and New England divisions, and least volatile in the West North central division.

In the same table, one can observe that house price appreciation also varies significantly by division. The average nominal house price appreciation between 1975 and 1995 was 6.9 percent, but the median was 3.1 percent and the standard deviation was of 19 percent. This rate of appreciation is slightly higher than that observed by the widely used FHFA repeat-sales house price index, which had an average year-to-year change of 5.7 percent over the same time period. Our results indicate a very skewed house price appreciation across divisions. Once more, the Pacific division reported the highest average appreciation, but the East North Central division had the highest median. The smallest increase in house prices was observed in the Mountain division, and the biggest variation in across house appreciation rates was in the East South Central division.


Table 2. Basic statistics price and appreciation
Division Price: Average Price: Median Price: Std. dev. Appreciation: Average Appreciation: Median Appreciation: Std. dev.
National 54832 40000 48775 0.0689 0.0309 0.1938
New England 75238 50000 69710 0.0617 0.0159 0.1873
Mid-Atlantic 55861 45000 43799 0.0756 0.0390 0.1837
South Atlantic 53341 40000 45265 0.0641 0.0149 0.1986
East South Central 38228 30000 28132 0.0700 0.0264 0.2224
West South Central 37414 30000 27157 0.0669 0.0000 0.2163
East North Central 47999 40000 33818 0.0663 0.0435 0.1841
West North Central 40987 37000 24644 0.0658 0.0351 0.1944
Mountain 46588 45000 25568 0.0577 0.0119 0.1831
Pacific 88500 65000 76992 0.0809 0.0395 0.1848
Note: All prices are in nominal dollars.

4.1 The house price model

We define returns to housing for individual  i in time  t as  (1+r_{i,t})=RH_{i,t}=\frac{p_{i,t}}{p_{i,t-1}}, where  p_{i,t} is the house price at time  t. In this case, returns to housing have a trend  g(X_{i,t}) that depends on a vector of house characteristics  X, and a shock component denoted by  e_{i,t}:

\displaystyle RH_{i,t} = g(X_{i,t}) +e_{i,t} (10)

The  X vector here consists of the number of rooms in the house and a time trend variable. We do not include any information about the homeowner in this estimation. We estimated this model separately for each census division. We explore using alternative data sources that contained more extensive information on the physical characteristics of the home, such as the American Housing Survey (AHS). The estimated shocks from that analysis were similar to those generated using the equation above with the PSID data. We decided that the consistency of using the same dataset to estimate both the house price and the MPC models outweighed the additional informational content on house characteristics available in the AHS.

Shocks to house price appreciation were on average negative, although very small (0.1 percent). New England had on average the most negative shocks to house appreciation, but the variation was highest among households living in the East South Central division (see Table 3).


Table 3. Appreciation shocks ( e_{i,t})
Division Average Median Std. dev.
National -0.001 -0.031 0.192
New England -0.027 -0.051 0.181
Mid-Atlantic -0.003 -0.040 0.184
South Atlantic -0.001 -0.030 0.197
East South Central -0.001 -0.034 0.223
West South Central 0.018 -0.015 0.216
East North Central 0.001 -0.025 0.183
West North Central -0.003 -0.027 0.192
Mountain -0.004 -0.028 0.179
Pacific -0.002 -0.043 0.182

We further decompose the shock term from equation (10) into permanent and transitory shocks to housing wealth as follows:

\displaystyle e_{i,t} = h_{i,t}+\nu_{i,t}\quad with \quad h_{i,t}=\rho^p h_{i,t-1}+\epsilon_{i,t} (11)

where  h_{i,t} represents the permanent component of the shock with  \rho^p as a persistence parameter, and  \epsilon_{i,t} as the permanent shock with  \epsilon\sim N(0,\sigma_{\epsilon}^2);  \nu_{i,t} is the transitory shock with  \nu\sim N(0,\sigma_{\nu}^2). We identify the permanent and transitory shocks by using two different filtering process: the Kalman filter and the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

4.2 A simple decomposition of trend vs. cycle in house prices

We first use a simple filter to separate the permanent and the transitory shocks to house prices, that proposed by Hodrick and Prescott (1997) to separate trends from cycles in the business cycle literature. This filter is widely used in macroeconomics with time-series data, but to our knowledge this is the first application to panel data. The objective of the filter is to separate the components of the process  e_{i,t} = h_{i,t}+\nu_{i,t}, by minimizing the following expression:  \min_{\langle h_{i,t}\rangle_{t=1}^T} \{ \sum_{t = 1}^T {(e_{i,t} - h_{i,t})^2 } + \lambda \sum_{t = 2}^{T - 1} {[(h_{i,t+1} - h_{i,t}) - (h_{i,t} - h_{i,t-1} )]^2 }\}, where  \lambda is a penalty parameter. The first term penalizes the variance of the transitory component  \nu_{i,t}=e_{i,t}- h_{i,t}, while the second term penalizes the variations in the growth rate of the trend component. As  \lambda approaches 0, the trend component becomes equivalent to the original series, whereas  \lambda approaches infinity,  h_{i,t} approaches the linear trend. Large values of  \lambda are commonly used for monthly data (around 100,000). For annual data, values between 6 and 14 are used. The reason for these choices is that the higher the value of  \lambda, the greater the weight in minimizing the variations in the growth rate of the trend (noisy data).

We use annual data from the PSID and choose a value of 10 for  \lambda. We first estimate a hedonic regression for the rate of appreciation of housing based on housing valuations in the PSID to obtain the component  g(X_{i,t}). We then run the residuals from this regression,  e_t, through an HP filter to separate the individual-level shocks into their permanent and transitory components. Using these measures of transitory and permanent shocks, we calculate the average level and variance by division of the permanent shocks and the variance of the transitory shocks.11

According to this decomposition (Table 4), the average national permanent shocks to house price appreciation is about 1 percent, with a standard deviation of 7.9 percent. The distribution is very skewed, and the median is only 0.4 percent. On the other hand, the standard deviation of the transitory shocks is 17 percent, much higher than the variance of the permanent shocks. On average, transitory shocks are very small (as they should be), on the order of 0.1 percent, perhaps reflecting some measurement error bias. The division with the highest permanent average shock is the West South Central division, followed by the Pacific division. The West South Central division also has the highest dispersion in permanent shocks, followed again by the Pacific division. The dispersion in the transitory shocks is more even across divisions, although the East South Central division has a slightly higher value than other divisions.


Table 4. HP filter decomposition of appreciation shocks (  e_{i,t} = h_{i,t}+\nu_{i,t})
Division Permanent ( h_{i,t}): Average Permanent ( h_{i,t}): Median Permanent ( h_{i,t}): Std. dev. Transitory( \nu_{i,t}): Average Transitory( \nu_{i,t}): Median Transitory( \nu_{i,t}): Std. dev.
National 0.011 0.004 0.079 -0.008 -0.016 0.170
New England 0.002 0.002 0.075 -0.022 -0.026 0.158
Mid-Atlantic 0.009 0.000 0.073 -0.010 -0.022 0.168
South Atlantic 0.010 0.005 0.079 -0.004 -0.014 0.175
East South Central 0.011 0.005 0.082 0.001 -0.015 0.196
West South Central 0.025 0.015 0.093 -0.001 -0.015 0.188
East North Central 0.006 0.004 0.065 -0.003 -0.013 0.162
West North Central 0.014 0.004 0.074 -0.013 -0.017 0.173
Mountain 0.010 0.002 0.085 -0.007 -0.017 0.155
Pacific 0.015 0.006 0.090 -0.017 -0.022 0.156

We next obtain the persistence parameter by regressing the individual permanent shocks on its lags, and the variance of the permanent shocks is given by the expression  \sigma_{\epsilon}^2=\sigma_{h}^2 (1-\rho^2). Results are shown in Table 5. At the national level, the persistence parameter is around 0.8 and the standard deviation is 7.9 percent. New England and the Mid-Atlantic divisions have the highest persistence in house shocks appreciation, and the Mountain division has the lowest. Consistent with previous results, the West South Central division has the highest variation in permanent shocks.


Table 5. Persistence and variance of permanent shocks using HP filter
(  h_{i,t}=\rho^p h_{i,t-1}+\epsilon_{i,t})
Division Persistence ( \rho) Std. dev.(  \sigma_{\epsilon})
National 0.811 0.079
New England 0.940 0.075
Mid-Atlantic 0.870 0.073
South Atlantic 0.711 0.079
East South Central 0.863 0.082
West South Central 0.785 0.093
East North Central 0.840 0.065
West North Central 0.787 0.074
Mountain 0.704 0.085
Pacific 0.849 0.090

4.3 A learning process for the trend vs. cycles in house prices

We next model household learning as a process in which households observe their own house prices and know the conditions of the market, but cannot distinguish between the permanent and the transitory component of price shocks. In the process we model, households know the underlying parameters of the house price process from the beginning, learn about the permanent and transitory components of the observed house price over time, and update their beliefs each period to predict the next observation.

In our second model, we parameterize further the shocks to the house price process, in terms of the appreciation rate, as follows:

\displaystyle e_{i,t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle h_{i,t}+\nu_{i,t} (12)
\displaystyle h_{i,t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \rho h_{i,t-1}+\epsilon_{i,t} (13)
\displaystyle \left[ \begin{array}{c} \nu_{i,t}\\ \epsilon_{i,t} \end{array}\right] \displaystyle \sim \displaystyle N\left( 0,\left[\begin{array}{cc} \sigma_{\nu}^2&0\\ 0&\sigma_{\epsilon}^2 \end{array}\right] \right) (14)

where  e_{i,t} is the observed shock to price appreciation by household  i at time  t, with permanent component  h_{i,t} and transitory component  \nu_{i,t}. The permanent component follows an AR(1) process with persistence parameter  \rho. The permanent shocks are represented by  \epsilon_{i,t} and the transitory shocks by  \nu_{i,t}, each distributed normally with mean 0 and variance  \sigma_{\epsilon}^2 and  \sigma_{\nu}^2, respectively.

We need to know the parameters governing the house price process that are known to the household in order to determine the permanent and transitory components of the shock. In particular, we need to obtain estimates of the variances of the transitory and permanent shocks.

One approach to determining the initial parameter values is to use the permanent and transitory shocks produced by the HP filter. We can directly observe the variance of the HP transitory shocks, and using an AR(1) process we can estimate the persistence and variance of the permanent shocks. This assumes that households could use the entire history of HP-filtered shocks to determine the initial parameter values for the Kalman learning process.

In a second approach, we use a minimum distance (MD) procedure to solve for the variances and the persistence parameter (that is, to solve for the vector  \theta=[\rho, \sigma_{\nu}, \sigma_{\epsilon}]). The MD estimation procedure is widely used in the estimation of the income process.12 Following Chamberlain (1984), in a panel of dimension  NT, with  i=1...N individuals and  t=1...T periods, this procedure consists in choosing  \hat{\theta} to minimize the distance between the sample mean of the moments  w_i,  \bar{w}=N^{-1}\sum_{i=1}^N w_i and the theoretical moments  g(\theta):

\displaystyle \min_{\theta}[\bar{w}-g(\theta)]'A_N[\bar{w}-g(\theta)] (15)

Altonji and Segal (1996) recommend the use of an identity matrix for  A_N. The variance-covariance matrix of  \hat{\theta} is given by  \Lambda=(G'G)^{-1}G'\Delta G(G'G)^{-1}, where  G=\frac{\partial g(\theta)}{\partial {\theta}} and  \Delta is the covariance matrix  \Delta=WW' with  W=[w_1,w_2...w_N].

The moments conditions we use are the following:

\begin{displaymath}\begin{array}{ccc}var(\hat{e}^i_t)&=&\frac{\sigma_{\epsilon}^2}{1-\rho^2}+\sigma_{\nu}^2\\ cov(\hat{e}^i_t,\hat{e}^i_{t+1})&=&\frac{\rho \sigma_{\epsilon}^2}{1-\rho^2}\ cov(\hat{e}^i_t,\hat{e}^i_{t+2})&=&\frac{\rho^2 \sigma_{\epsilon}^2}{1-\rho^2} \end{array}\end{displaymath}     (16)

Using this procedure, we obtain a point estimate for the persistence of the permanent shock to housing prices of  \rho=.9645; we also obtain the variance of the permanent shocks to housing  \epsilon=.0589, and the variance of the transitory shocks to housing  \nu=.0008. If we run the same model with the appreciation instead of the level, we get  \hat{\rho}=.2787,  \hat{\epsilon}=.8659 and  \hat{\nu}=.648.

Having determined the parameter values that describe the house price process, we can turn to the learning process that households face to determine the permanent and transitory shocks to their wealth. The first possible learning process (and the simplest) assumes that households know the price process (12)-(14). In this case households form expectations about the decomposition of the permanent and transitory shocks to house prices with the information they have at time  t. Their information set is given by  I=e_t, e_{t-1},e_{t-2},.... Equations (12) and (13) give the measurement equation:

\displaystyle \hat{e}_{i,t}=\rho h_{i,t-1}+\epsilon_{i,t}+\nu_{i,t} (17)

which describes the relationship between the observed variable  \hat{e}_{i,t} and the unobserved variables  h_{i,t-1}, \epsilon_{i,t} and  \nu_{i,t}. The transition or state equation shows the evolution of the unobserved variables and is given by equation (13) and the shock process (14).

In matrix form, the measurement equation is given by:

\displaystyle \hat{e}_{i,t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \boldmath {Z \alpha_{t}}  
\displaystyle \hat{e}_{i,t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left[\rho\quad 1\quad 1\right]\left[\begin{array}{c} h_{i,t-1}\\ \epsilon_{i,t}\\ \nu_{i,t} \end{array}\right]  

and the transition equation in matrix form is given by:

\displaystyle \boldmath {\alpha_{i,t}}\quad \displaystyle = \displaystyle \boldmath {\qquad T \quad\quad \alpha_{i,t-1}\qquad+ \qquad R \qquad\eta_{i,t}}  
\displaystyle \left[\begin{array}{c} h_{i,t} \\ \nu_{i,t}\end{array}\right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left[\begin{array}{cc} \rho & 0\ 0&0\end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{c} h_{i,t-1} \ \nu_{i,t-1}\end{array}\right]+\left[\begin{array}{cc} 1 & 0\ 0&1\end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{c} \epsilon{i,t} \ \nu_{i,t}\end{array}\right]  

with  \eta_t\sim N(0,Q) and  Q=\left[\begin{array}{cc}\sigma_{\nu}^2&0\\ 0&\sigma_{\epsilon}^2\end{array}\right].

The optimal estimator of  \alpha_{t} considers all the information in  I_t and is given by  \hat{\alpha}_t=E[\alpha\vert I_t]. The optimal estimator that minimizes the mean squared error is linear and given by

\displaystyle \hat{\alpha}_{t}=[I-PZ'(ZPZ')^{-1}Z]\hat{\alpha}_{t\vert t-1}+[PZ'(ZPZ')^{-1}]\hat{p}_{i,t} (18)

where  I is an identity matrix and  P=E[(\alpha_t-\hat{\alpha}_t)(\alpha_t-\hat{\alpha}_t)']=TPT'-TPZ(ZPZ')^{-1}ZPT'+RQR' is the covariance matrix of the estimator. In addition,
\displaystyle \hat{\alpha}_{t\vert t-1}=T\hat{\alpha}_{t-1} (19)

Table 6 shows the decomposition of the shocks using the Kalman filter using the permanent and transitory shocks produced by the HP filter as initial values. The permanent shocks to house appreciation are smaller than in the case of the HP filter (0.1 percent), and the dispersion is higher for the permanent shocks than for the transitory shocks. However, the West South central division again shows the highest average permanent shocks, and this time the second-highest dispersion of the permanent shocks, and the East South central division has the highest dispersion of the transitory shocks.


Table 6. Kalman filter decomposition of appreciation shocks
Division Permanent: Average Permanent: Median Permanent: Std. dev. Transitory: Average Transitory: Median Transitory: Std. dev.
National 0.001 -0.022 0.154 0.000 -0.001 0.042
New England -0.019 -0.045 0.147 -0.003 -0.002 0.039
Mid-Atlantic 0.000 -0.030 0.150 -0.001 -0.001 0.041
South Atlantic 0.002 -0.022 0.155 -0.001 -0.001 0.043
East South Central 0.001 -0.026 0.176 0.001 -0.002 0.053
West South Central 0.020 -0.011 0.173 0.003 0.000 0.047
East North Central 0.002 -0.016 0.144 0.000 -0.001 0.040
West North Central -0.002 -0.018 0.156 -0.002 -0.002 0.043
Mountain -0.003 -0.023 0.151 0.002 -0.001 0.035
Pacific -0.001 -0.035 0.152 -0.001 -0.002 0.040

5 Consumption and housing wealth: Empirical issues and identification strategy

We test in this section whether shocks to house appreciation affect nonhousing consumption. As discussed in section 2.2, a shock to housing wealth alone should not necessarily affect nonhousing consumption, because it implies a change in future housing prices as well, leaving the ratio of future to current prices constant, and according to equation (8), only movements in this ratio affect consumption. A shock to house price appreciation should affect consumption because it implies a change in the return on a risky asset, because it affects the ratio of housing to nonhousing consumption and because it relaxes the households borrowing constraints.

We test a version of the Euler equation (4) and (6), where borrowing constraints explicitly affect consumption.13 This is especially important in the case of housing, because one of the main roles housing has in consumption is to serve as collateral.

We can take the first order condition for consumption in equation (4) and derive a log-linearized Euler equation that we can then estimate assuming a CRRA utility function.14 Considering this equation, the model we estimate is:

\displaystyle \Delta log(C_{i,t})=\alpha\Delta log(V_{i,t})+Z_{i,t}+u_{i,t} (20)

where  C_{i,t} denotes the real food consumption of household i in t,  V_{i,t} denotes the real value of the house, and  Z_{i,t} denotes a vector of additional household-level variables. The coefficient  \alpha gives the elasticity of food consumption out of housing wealth.

The vector  Z_{i,t} is included to control for household-specific effects. We include the size of the family, and the age and the age squared of the household's head to control for household composition. We include a dummy variable for households whose head completed college, and another for households whose head did not complete high school to control for education effects, as well as a dummy variable for black heads of households. The vector  Z_{i,t} also includes a set of variables to control for year and divisional fixed effects. We control for the impact of income changes on consumption by including the change in the log of family income. Theory indicates that consumption will respond to changes in shocks to permanent income. In fact, some of the criticism by Calomiris et al. and Attanasio et al. is based on the fact that shocks to permanent income should influence both current consumption and house prices in the same manner. In order to control for those factors, we include a measure of the household's permanent income, following Lehnert (2005), defined as the average change in log income for that household from 1968 to 1997.

The MPC is defined as the estimated elasticity times the average ratio of total consumption to house value:

\displaystyle MPC=\hat{\alpha}\frac{1}{N}\sum_{i=1}^N \frac{C_i}{V_i} (21)

Our identification strategy uses variation across census divisions in house price appreciation to identify how movements in that variable across households affect consumption changes. Our panel data configuration allows us to control for the effects of correlation between the error terms and to separate a causal effect, given the cross-sectional variation due to geographical location. Importantly, we focus on the shocks to house appreciation and not on house price shocks alone for the reasons mentioned in the theoretical section.

As was mentioned in the introduction, some recent papers (Attanasio et al. (2009), Calomiris et al (2009)) have argued against a causal link between consumption and housing wealth, and instead proposed that the observed correlation between the variables is due to a common third factor such as expected permanent income. This argument relies on the standard Euler equation specification in which changes in consumption should not respond to expected changes in the information set households use to decide consumption. In that sense, a change in housing wealth would imply a change in permanent income, with consequent effects on consumption. Our specification controls for a variable that includes permanent income. Moreover, as Muellbauer (2009) argues, even if the argument by Attanasio et al. and Calomiris et al. is true, the relaxation in the borrowing constraints because of higher house prices would imply higher consumption for some consumers. We test this possibility by running an instrumental variable procedure, instrumenting current shocks to house price appreciation with the lag of those shocks. Although the results are statistically weaker, we obtain a similar quantitative effect with a level of significance of 10%.15

5.1 Divisional variation in the MPC and effect of persistence and variance of wealth shocks in consumption

Table 7 reports estimates of the MPC out of housing wealth by census division. Although this initial exercise makes no attempt to explore the connection between the MPC and the nature of the shocks to housing, it does demonstrate the extent to which the MPC out of housing does vary geographically. Households in New England, the South Atlantic, the Pacific, and the East North Central divisions will consume about 2.5 percent to 3.0 percent of any increase in housing wealth, while households in the West South Central, West North Central, and Mountain states do not seem to significantly adjust their consumption at all in response to changes in home values. Households in the East South Central division have the highest estimated MPC out of housing wealth, at 8.0 percent. We are somewhat suspicions of this estimate, given its significant difference from estimates in other divisions and the fairly small sample size in the division (842 observations, the third smallest). Relatively small sample sizes also prevent us from generating estimates of the MPC out of housing wealth for smaller geographical areas. Attempts to generate state-level estimates resulted in significant elasticities for only 5 of the 35 states in our sample.

It is interesting to note that we observe significantly more dispersion across census divisions among the elasticity estimates than among the estimates of the MPC out of housing wealth. This relates to one of our initial hypotheses. The elasticity of consumption to housing wealth will be higher in areas with more cyclical changes in house prices due to relatively inelastic housing supply. It is precisely these areas that also have higher housing values, and thus lower ratios of consumption to house value. As a result, two of the divisions with the most cyclical house prices (New England and the Pacific) have some of the highest elasticity estimates (5.98 percent and 5.27 percent, respectively) and lowest ratios of consumption to house value (53.2 percent and 47.2 percent, respectively). The result is a certain convergence in our estimates of the MPC out of housing wealth across divisions. As noted before, the East South Central division remains an outlier, with the highest elasticity estimate (9.16 percent) and the highest ratio of consumption to house value (86.7 percent).


Table 7. Marginal Propensity to Consume out of Housing Wealth by Division
Division Elasticity Imputed C/V MPC
New England 0.0598 *
(0.0370)
0.5318 3.17%
Mid-Atlantic 0.0189
(0.0230)
0.6128 1.16%
South Atlantic 0.0388 ***
(0.0147)
0.8134 3.16%
East South Central 0.0916 ***
(0.0293)
0.8671 7.94%
West South Central 0.0251
(0.0232)
0.8155 2.05%
East North Central 0.0419 **
(0.0209)
0.6310 2.64%
West North Central 0.0148
(0.0218)
0.6646 0.98%
Mountain 0.0210
(0.0453)
0.9953 2.09%
Pacific 0.0527 **
(0.024)
0.4720 2.49%
Note: The standard deviations are presented in parentheses. *** represents significance at the 1% level, ** represents significance at the 5% level and * represents significance at the 10% level.

The divisional variation in the consumption elasticity of housing wealth allows us to test some of the implications of the model, namely, that the higher the persistence, the higher the consumption elasticity of housing wealth; and that the higher the variance, the higher the consumption elasticity of housing wealth. We perform this test using the elasticity estimates instead of the MPC estimates to take advantage of the greater variation across divisions of the elasticity estimates.


Table 8. Correlation of Consumption Elasticity of Housing Wealth to Persistence and Variance of House Price Process by Division
  Persistence Permanent Variance Transitory Variance
Including East South Central 0.5406 0.2767 0.0572
Excluding East South Central 0.6855 0.7238 -0.6265
Note: The standard deviations are presented in parentheses. *** represents significance at the 1% level, ** represents significance at the 5% level and * represents significance at the 10% level.

Table 8 reports estimates of the correlation between the elasticity estimates in Table 7 and the estimates of the persistence and variances of the appreciation shocks from Tables 4 and 5. These results are roughly consistent with the theoretical model. The degree of persistence in house appreciation shocks is positively correlated with higher consumption elasticities of housing wealth. Divisions with higher degrees of permanent variance also have higher consumption elasticities of housing wealth, consistent with the theoretical implications. The negative correlation between the elasticity estimates and the transitory variance runs counter to our theoretical results, but might represent the role of housing as collateral and the household's fear of a large transitory shock temporarily pushing home equity negative and thus limiting their mobility.

The results based on these divisional estimates of the MPC come with some significant caveats. We base this analysis on a very small sample size, with degrees of freedom of only 7 or 8. As was mentioned above, attempts to increase the sample size by generating elasticity estimates at the state level proved problematic. We are also limited by the number of observations in each division, which results in rather large standard deviations for our elasticity estimates. We were unable to reject the hypothesis that the elasticity estimates across divisions were statistically equal from each other, and were only able to show that the MPC estimates for the East South Central and South Atlantic divisions were statistically significantly different from those for the other divisions. The inability to find statistically significantly differences in the MPC across divisions in part reflects the small sample size for the divisional estimates.

5.2 MPC out of transitory and permanent shocks to housing wealth

Table 9 reports the main results of the paper: (1) The total elasticity is about 5%, is statistically significant different from zero, and corresponds to a MPC out of total wealth of 3.5%, (2) The consumption responses to permanent shocks to house price appreciation are generally higher than those to transitory shocks. In particular, the MPC out of permanent shocks to housing wealth is between 3.5 and 9.2 cents for a 1-dollar shock increase in house price appreciation, and in the case of responses to transitory shocks, the MPC is between 0.5 and 3.7 cents.

The difference between the MPC out of permanent and transitory shocks is by far the greatest when the HP filter is used. This method does not assume any learning process, and the ability to differentiate permanent and transitory shocks over time does not change. When we assume a Kalman learning process and take the parameters for the house price process from the HP filter, transitory shocks have no effect on consumption. When we assume a Kalman learning process with the underlying parameters derived from GMM, households lose their ability to identify the permanent and transitory shocks and treat them the same.16 The MPC obtained using the Kalman filter is very similar in the case of the temporary and permanent shocks and for the total shock. This suggest that households are not able to identify transitory or permanent shocks if we assume that they start with no prior assumptions based on actual observations of the house price process.

Our results in the case of the total shocks are somewhat lower but in line with previous estimates, like those of Benjamin, Chinloy, and Jun (2004) (8%) or Bostic, Gabriel, and Painter (2009) (5.7%). Our estimates for the elasticity to permanent shocks to housing wealth are nearer the higher end of the ranges estimated in previous studies, while our estimate of the elasticity to temporary shocks are significantly lower.


Table 9. MPC out of transitory and permanent shocks to housing
  Elasticity: Total Elasticity: Permanent Elasticity: Transitory MPC: Total MPC: Permanent MPC: Transitory
Total Shocks 0.05099
(0.01487)
    0.035    
HP Filter   0.13323
(0.0597)
0.04768
(0.01958)
  0.092 0.033
Kalman filter using parameters from HP filter   0.04998
(0.02975)
0.00834
(0.14491)
  0.034 0.005
Kalman filter using parameters from GMM   0.05124
(0.02579)
0.05404
(0.02579)
  0.035 0.037
Note: The standard deviations are presented in parentheses.

6 Conclusions

The goal of this paper was to take advantage of the geographical variation in house price processes to identify how the MPC varies by census division and how it differs between permanent and transitory shocks. We developed some simple theoretical models that show how the MPC is increasing with the degree of persistence and the variance of the house price shocks, and how consumption may respond to housing appreciation shocks. Using food consumption from the PSID, we found empirical evidence to support this theoretical conclusion, and we showed how the MPC out of housing appreciation shocks varies by division. Finally, we estimated the MPC separately out of permanent and transitory shocks to housing wealth appreciation under different learning regimes.

A recent criticism of the finding of a significant MPC out of housing has been the possibility that observed correlations between changes in consumption and housing wealth are not causal, but are in response to some common factor, such as changes in expected future income. We addressed these concerns in a variety of ways, such as including measures of permanent income in the model specification, using instrumental variables to test the robustness of our results, utilizing the great intraregional variation in self-reported individual home values, and focusing on shocks to the appreciation rate of housing and not the level of housing wealth. Our theoretical results show that such appreciation shocks do impact current-period consumption, even if shocks to housing wealth would not, and in the absence of binding collateral constraints.

Our estimates of the elasticity of consumption to housing wealth by division showed significant variation. New England and the Pacific regions have some of the highest estimates of elasticity, while the estimates were insignificant in much of the middle of the country. We also observed a significant positive correlation between estimates of the persistence and permanent variance of the house price processes and the elasticity estimates, consistent with our theoretical results.

We then used two statistical filters to separate the individual shocks to home appreciation in the PSID as a way of modeling households' expectations. We found that the MPC out of permanent shocks was higher than that out of transitory shocks. The gap was greatest for the shocks identified with the HP filter. When we used the parameters from the HP filter to represent a household's prior knowledge for a Kalman filter, we found that the MPC from the transitory shocks was no long significant. When we instead used the GMM method to identify the parameters for the Kalman filter, the MPCs out of the permanent and transitory shocks were close to equal. Estimates of the MPC out of permanent shocks to housing are significant for all specifications and range from 3.4% to 9.2%. The estimates of the MPC out of transitory shocks are more dependent on the assumptions made regarding household's expectations.

Bibliography

Aiyagari, S. Rao. "Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Savings" Journal of Political Economy 103(6), pp., 1158-75, December 1994.
Altonji, Joseph G., and Lewis M. Segal. "Small-Sample Bias in GMM Estimation of Covariance Structures," Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 14(3), pp. 353-66, July, 1996.
Attanasio, Orazio, Renata Bottazzi, Hamish Low, Lars Neisham and Matthew Wakefield. "Explaining Life-Cycle Profiles of Home-Ownership and Labour Supply." Computing in Economics and Finance No. 511, Society for Computational Economics, 2006.
Attanasio, Orazio, Laura Blow, Robert Hamilton and Andrew Leicester."Booms and Busts: Consumption, House Prices, and Expectations." Economica 76(301), pp. 269-302, 2009.
Attanasio, Orazio P and GuglielmoWeber. "Is Consumption Growth Consistent with Intertemporal Optimization? Evidence from the Consumer Expenditure Survey," Journal of Political Economy 103(6), pp., 1121-57, 1995.
Benjamin, John D., Peter T. Chinloy, and G. Donald Jun. "Real Estate Versus Financial Wealth in Consumption." Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 29(3), pp. 341-54, 2004.
Bostic, Raphael, Stuart Gabriel, and Gary Painter. "Housing Wealth, Financial Wealth, and Consumption: New Evidence From Micro Data." Regional Science and Urban Economics 39(1), pp. 79-89, January, 2009.
Bourassa, Steven, Donald Haurin, Jessica Haurin, Martin Hoseli, and Jian Sun. "House Price Changes and Idiosyncratic Risk: The Impact of Property Characteristics." Real Estate Economics v37(2:99), pp. 259-78, 2009.
Bover, Olympia. "Wealth Effects on Consumption: Microeconometric Estimates from a New Survey of Household Finances." CEPR Discussion Paper No., 5874, October 2006.
Buiter, Willem. "Housing Wealth Isn't Wealth". NBER Working Paper No., 14204, July 2008.
Calomiris, Charles, Stanley D. Longhofer, and William Miles. "The (Mythical?) Housing Wealth Effect." NBER Working Paper No., 15075, June 2009.
Campbell, John Y., and João F. Cocco. "How Do House Prices Affect Consumption? Evidence From Micro Data." Journal of Monetary Economics 54, pp. 591-621, 2007.
Case, Karl E., John M. Quigley and Robert Shiller. "Comparing Wealth Effects: The Stock Market Versus the Housing Market." Advances in Macroeconomics 5(1), pp. 1-34, 2005.
Chamberlain, G., "Analysis of Covariance with Qualitative Data," Review of Economic Studies 47, pp. 225-238, 1980.
Chamberlain, G. "Panel Data," In Z. Griliches and M. Intriligator (Eds) Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 2, Chapter 22, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1984
Flavin, Marjorie, and Takashi Yamashita. "Owner-Occupied Housing and the Composition of the Household Portfolio." American Economic Review 92(1), pp. 345-62, 2002.
Goodman, John L. and John B. Ittner. "The Accuracy of Home Owners' Estimates of House Value." Journal of Housing Economics 2, pp.339-57, 1992.
Guvenen, Fatih."An Empirical Investigation of Labor Income Processes." Review of Economic Dynamics 12(1), pp. 58-79, 2009.
Hodrick, Robert, and Edward C. Prescott "Postwar U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29, pp. 1-16, 1997.
Jeske, Karsten. "Macroeconomic Models with Heterogeneous Agents and Housing." Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, 4th quarter, 2005.
Juster, F. Thomas, Joseph O. Lupton, James P. Smith, and Frank Stafford. "The Decline in Household Saving and the Wealth Effect." The Review of Economics and Statistics 88(1), pp. 20-27, January, 2006.
Kimball, Miles S. "Precautionary Savings and the Marginal Propensity to Consume." NBER Working Paper No., 3402, July 1990.
Lettau, Martin and Sydney Ludvigson. "Understanding Trend and Cycle in Asset Values: Reevaluating the Wealth Effect on Consumption." NBER Working Paper No., 9848, 2003.
Lehnert, Andreas. "Housing, Consumption, and Credit Constraints." Working paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, 2005.
Li, Wenli, and Rui Yao. "The Life-Cycle Effect of House Price Changes." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39(6), pp. 1375-09, September, 2007.
Luengo-Prado, Maria Jose, and Bent E. Sorensen. "What Can Explain Excess Smoothness and Sensitivity of State-Level Consumption?" The Review of Economics and Statistics 90(1), pp.65-80, October, 2008.
Muellbauer, John. "Household Decision, Credit Markets and the Macroeconomy: Implications for the Design of Central Bank Models." Working paper, University of Oxford, June, 2009.
Storesletten, K, C. Telmer, and A. Yaron. "Cyclical Dynamics in Idiosyncratic Labor-Market Risk." Journal of Political Economy 112(3), pp. 695-717, June, 2004.
Skinner, J. S. "Is housing wealth a sideshow?" In Advances in the Economics of Aging, National Bureau of Economic Research Report, pp. 241– 68, 1996.
Yang, Fang. "Consumption Over the Life Cycle: How Different is Housing?." Review of Economic Dynamics 12(3), pp.423-43, 2008.



Footnotes

1. Comments are welcome at: [email protected] and [email protected]. The analysis and conclusions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Congressional Budget Office or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The authors would like to thank Thomas Davidoff, James Follain, Jon Huntley, Jeff Kling, Andreas Lehnert, Ben Malin, Ben Page, Bill Randolph, Andrew Stocking, and the participants at the 2007 Mid-Year AREUEA, 2007 Inform Outlook, and 2008 SGE meetings. Return to Text
2. For example, Lettau and Ludvigson (2003) find that in the aggregate data, consumption responds to permanent shocks but not to transitory changes shocks in aggregate wealth. They also determine that most of the aggregate variation in wealth is transitory. Campbell and Cocco (2007) use UK data to analyze the response of consumption to anticipated and unanticipated changes in housing prices using pseudo panel techniques and a life-cycle model to calculate the bias of the endogeneity problems and the nonrandomness of the control (renters) and treatment groups (homeowners), which have different characteristics that are hard to observe. They find that predictable changes in house prices are correlated with predictable changes in consumption, in particular for older households and for households facing binding borrowing constraints. Return to Text
3. We define the marginal propensity to consume out of shocks to housing wealth as the marginal increase in consumption that follows a marginal increase in house price appreciation. Return to Text
4. Some papers have exploited the geographical variation in housing prices at a more aggregate level, not with micro data, and without differentiating between permanent and transitory shocks, as we do in this paper. Case, Quigley, and Shiller (2005) estimate state-level correlations between changes in real consumption and real housing wealth on a per capita basis and find some significant variations. In fact, their measures of this correlation are positively correlated with our measures of the size and persistence of permanent shocks to housing appreciation, providing additional support to our findings in this paper. Return to Text
5. Flavin and Yamashita (2002) and BEA NIPA accounts for 2006. Return to Text
6. Luengo-Prado and Sorensen (2008) estimate the MPC out of current and lagged income for U.S. states using a panel of state consumption and income data, and find that the MPC out of current income is higher in states where income is more persistent and lower in agricultural states, but cannot identify clearly whether the state's income variance affects consumption. Return to Text
7. In principle, we could run the analysis to obtain state-level MPCs, but we found that the smaller state-level sample sizes significantly affected the precision of the estimates. Return to Text
8. Lehnert (2005) estimates measures of the MPC out of housing conditional on household characteristics. Using the PSID, he finds that the MPC out of housing is higher for younger households and for households approaching retirement. Skinner (1996) also uses the PSID and finds a small but statistically significant effect of housing wealth on consumption. Return to Text
9. Bover (2006) attempts to control for this using a detailed cross-sectional financial survey from Spain, by instrumenting housing wealth using geographical variation in house prices and an indicator variable for households that inherit housing. The author interprets the resulting estimates of the MPC out of housing, 1 to 2 percent, as representing solely changes in precautionary saving given the barriers to the extraction of housing equity in Spanish credit markets. Return to Text
10. We also test a specification that uses instrumental variables; although the statistical significance is weaker (10% vs 5%), the quantitative results are very similar. Return to Text
11. By definition, the average transitory shock is zero. Return to Text
12. The procedure was first proposed by Chamberlain (1980, 1984). For applications see, for example, Storesletten, Telmer and Yaron (2004) and Guvenen (2007). Return to Text
13. To estimate the MPC out of housing wealth, we need to estimate the marginal change in consumption ( dC) when housing wealth changes marginally, that is, when the house price changes marginally ( dV) in a panel composed of households i in time t. Without imposing much structure, the options are (i) to estimate the regression in levels,  C_{i,t} = \beta * V_{i,t} +u_{i,t}, such that the  MPC=\hat{\beta}; (ii) to estimate the regression in logs,  log C_{i,t} = \alpha* log V_{i,t} +u_{i,t}, such that the  MPC=\hat{\alpha}\frac{1}{N}\sum_{i=1}^N \frac{C_i}{V_i}, where the coefficient  \alpha is the elasticity of consumption with respect to the house value; (iii) to estimate the equation in differences,  \Delta C_{i,t}= \alpha \Delta V_{i,t} +u_{i,t}; and (iv) to estimate the equation in log differences,  \Delta log(C_{i,t})= \alpha \Delta log V_{i,t}. In cases (iii) and (iv), the MPC is calculated in the same way as in case (ii). We use the last option because the first difference in logs helps to minimize the effect of possible autocorrelation (unit root) in the error terms, is the specification tied to the Euler equation from the consumer problem and the log transformation reduce the effect of heteroskedasticity and outliers. Return to Text
14. With utility function  U(c)=\frac{c_{t}^{1-\gamma}-1}{1-\gamma}, we can derive the equation
\displaystyle \Delta log(C_{t+1})=\frac{1}{\gamma}[E_t log(1+r_{t+1})+log (\beta)]+\frac{\gamma}{2}var_t(\Delta log(C_{t+1})-\frac{1}{\gamma}log(1+r_{t+1}))+\epsilon_{t+1}    

The variance term is proxied in the empirical implementation by changes in income. This is often one of the explanations given for the failure of orthogonality tests in consumption (where changes in income are not correlated with changes in consumption). Return to Text
15. We ran a specification that instrumented the house price appreciation shocks with their lags and obtain an elasticity of consumption to changes in house appreciation of 0.048, with a standard deviation of 0.028, similar quantitatively to the elasticity that we obtain otherwise (0.039 with a standard deviation of 0.08). Return to Text
16. Alternative results, not shown, found that when we included in the sample households who moved multiple times, and therefore had to restart the learning process with each move, none of the filtered shocks were significant. Clearly the ability of and time provided to a household to parse these observed shocks to housing matter to estimating the MPC of those shocks. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text