The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2011-10 Screen Reader version

What Drives Matching Efficiency?
A Tale of Composition and Dispersion*

Regis Barnichon
Federal Reserve Board
Andrew Figura
Federal Reserve Board

Keywords: Matching function, matching efficiency, composition effect, mismatch.

Abstract:

This paper presents a framework to study movements in the matching efficiency of the labor market and highlights two observable factors affecting matching efficiency: (i) unemployment composition and (ii) dispersion in labor market conditions, the fact that tight labor markets coexist with slack ones. Using CPS micro data over 1976-2009, we find that composition is responsible for most of the movements in matching efficiency until 2006. In 2008-2009, only forty percent of an exceptionally low matching efficiency can be attributed to composition. New highly disaggregated data on vacancies and unemployment show that the unexplained decline in matching efficiency coincides with an increase in dispersion.

JEL classifications: J6, E24, E32



1 Introduction

The unemployment rate is a major indicator of economic activity. Understanding its movements is useful in assessing the causes of economic fluctuations and their impact on welfare, as well as assessing inflationary pressures in the economy. An important determinant of the unemployment rate is the ability of the labor market to match unemployed workers to jobs. If aggregate matching efficiency declines, i.e. if fewer job matches are formed each period conditional on unemployment and vacancies, the unemployment rate increases with adverse effects on welfare and possibly inflation. Further, the effects of a decline in matching efficiency on the economy will depend on the forces behind this decline. A larger share of long-term unemployed, a larger fraction of permanent layoffs, geographic mismatch, skill mismatch, or more generous unemployment benefits can all lower aggregate matching efficiency but with differing degrees of persistence.

In this paper, we study the determinants of aggregate matching efficiency fluctuations over the last four decades.

As a first pass towards capturing changes in aggregate matching efficiency, we estimate an aggregate matching function tying levels of vacancies and unemployment to the job finding rate. While the matching function appears relatively stable over time, a testimony of the success of the matching function, the regression residual, or aggregate matching efficiency, displays a cyclical pattern, increasing in the later stages of expansions, and declining in the early stages of recoveries. In the 2008-2009 recession however, the decline in aggregate matching efficiency started before the recession and was a lot more pronounced, adding an estimated  1 {\frac12} percentage points to the unemployment rate (Barnichon and Figura, 2010).

The first contribution of this paper is to present an empirical framework to study movements in aggregate matching efficiency. Under fairly general assumptions, we link movements in aggregate matching efficiency to two measurable factors: (i) composition of the unemployment pool, and (ii) dispersion in labor market conditions. First, if composition changes, and a group with a lower than average job finding probability (such as workers on permanent layoff) becomes over-represented among the unemployed, the average job finding probability will decline more than what a matching function would imply. Second, changes in the location and nature (e.g., skill requirements) of new jobs can lead to a misallocation of jobs and workers across labor markets and generate dispersion in labor market conditions as tight labor markets coexist with slack labor markets. Because of the concavity of the matching function, an increase in dispersion in labor market conditions will lower matching efficiency. Moreover, the effect of higher dispersion on matching efficiency may be exaggerated if workers can find a job outside of their local labor market (Abraham, 1991). To address this little studied issue, we introduce the concept of "permeability" between labor market segments. With higher permeability, workers are more likely to cross local labor market barriers and find a job in a different labor market segment, and dispersion has a weaker effect on matching efficiency.

The second contribution of this paper is to use matched CPS micro data on unemployment-employment transitions over four decades to estimate a model of job finding probability and to empirically relate aggregate matching efficiency to composition and dispersion. In addition, because the effect of misallocation on matching efficiency is a function of dispersion in labor market conditions across segments, it is crucial to observe segments at a high level of disaggregation in order to correctly assess the extent of dispersion. We thus separately consider shorter datasets that allow us to probe dispersion across more refined labor market segments. In particular, we present a new dataset on labor market tightness by occupation and geographic location covering a total of 564 segments, a 55-fold improvement over publicly available data such as the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS). Further, because 564 segments may still be well below the true number of segments in the US, we propose a method using UK data to scale up our measure of dispersion over 564 segments to a more realistic number of labor market segments.

Our main findings can be summarized as follows: (1) Changes in composition are important and generate non-trivial cyclical movements in matching efficiency. Because cyclical movements in composition are positively correlated with aggregate labor market tightness, regressions that do not control for composition estimate the matching function elasticity with an upward bias. (2) Movements in composition are mostly due to two factors: (i) an increase in the fraction of long-term unemployed during recessions, and (ii) a larger fraction of unemployed workers on permanent (rather than temporary) layoff during recessions. (3) Until 2006, changes in composition are responsible for most of the cyclical movements in matching efficiency, while dispersion appears to have played a modest role. (4) Since 2006, composition explains only 40 percent of a dramatic decline in matching efficiency. Instead, the unexplained decline coincides with an increase in dispersion in labor market conditions. Quantitatively, dispersion may account for a quarter, and perhaps more, of the unexplained decline in matching efficiency. (5) Extended unemployment benefits, reduced worker mobility caused by a distressed housing market or industry specific shocks do not seem to have significantly lowered matching efficiency.

This paper builds on a large literature studying the matching function (see Petrongolo and Pissarides (2001) for a review) and extends Bleakley and Fuhrer (1997) to identify changes in matching efficiency. While that latter study focuses on aggregate labor market tightness as the main explanatory variable of the aggregate job finding rate, we emphasize that the aggregate job finding probability is an average of probabilities across heterogeneous workers working in different segments of the labor market. Baker (1992) studies the role played by composition in explaining the counter-cyclicality of average unemployment duration. This paper extends Baker (1992) by presenting a model of job finding probability based on the concept of a matching function that takes into account individual characteristics as well as local labor market characteristics. Finally, the literature on mismatch has typically relied on a variety of dispersion measures (Padoa Schioppa, 1991, Layard, Nickell and Jackman, 2005) to capture the extent of misallocation of jobs and workers, and absent a unifying framework, there was no consensus on the most appropriate measure. This paper fills the gap by providing a dispersion measure, the variance of labor market tightness across labor market segments, that can be analytically related to matching efficiency and to the equilibrium unemployment rate.1

The next section takes a first pass at capturing changes in matching efficiency with an aggregate matching function regression. Section 3 presents a more refined empirical framework to identify the driving forces of matching efficiency, and Section 4 uses micro data to estimate that framework and discuss the results. Section 5 estimates the extent of dispersion across labor market conditions at a high disaggregation level and evaluates the effect on matching efficiency. Section 6 concludes.

2 A first look at changes in matching efficiency

The matching function relates the flow of new hires to the stocks of vacancies and unemployment. Like the production function, the matching function is a convenient device that partially captures a complex reality with workers looking for the right job and firms looking for the right worker. In a continuous time framework, the flow of hires can be modeled with a standard Cobb-Douglas matching function with constant returns to scale, and we can write

\displaystyle m_{t}=m_{0t}U_{t}^{\sigma }V_{t}^{1-\sigma } (1)

with  m_{t}, the number of new hires at instant  t,  U_{t} the number of unemployed,  V_{t} the number of vacancies, and  m_{0t} aggregate matching efficiency.2

Since the job finding rate  jf_{t} is the ratio of new hires to the stock of unemployed, we have  jf_{t}=\frac{m_{t}}{U_{t}} so that  jf_{t}=m_{0t}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }with  \theta =  \frac{v}{u} the aggregate labor market tightness,  u= U/LF,  v= V/LF and  LF the labor force. To identify  m_{0t}, a simple approach is thus to estimate an aggregate matching function and interpret movements in the residual as movements in matching efficiency. Specifically, we regress

\displaystyle \ln jf_{t}=(1-\sigma )\ln \theta _{t}+E_{T}\left( \ln m_{0t}\right) +\mu _{t} (2)

with E _{T}(.) denoting the average over the estimation period so that  E_{T}\left( \ln m_{0t}\right) denotes the intercept of the regression. Deviations of aggregate matching efficiency from its average level are then given by
\displaystyle \mu _{t}=\ln m_{0t}-E_{T}\ln m_{0t}. (3)

We measure the job finding rate  jf_{t} from unemployment-employment transitions from the Current Population Survey (CPS), and we use the composite help-wanted index presented in Barnichon (2010) as a proxy for vacancy posting.3 We use non-detrended quarterly data, allow for first-order serial correlation in the residual and estimate (2) over 1976-2007. Table 1 presents the results. The elasticity is estimated at 0.67. Using lagged values of  v_{t} and  u_{t} as instruments gives similar results, and the elasticity is little changed at 0.66.

Figure 1 plots the empirical job finding rate, its fitted value, and the residual of equation (2), i.e.,  \mu _{t}, the movements in aggregate matching efficiency. A first observation is that the matching function appears relatively stable over time, a corollary of the success of the matching function. However, aggregate matching efficiency displays a clear cyclical pattern, and typically lags the business cycle, increasing in the later stages of expansions, peaking in the late stages of recessions or the early stages of recoveries, and declining thereafter. In the 2008-2009 recession however, the decline in matching efficiency occurred earlier than in previous recessions and was a lot more pronounced. In the fourth quarter of 2009, the residual reached an all time low of four standard-deviations. 4 The expansion period preceding the 2008-2009 recession also appears peculiar, because the increase in matching efficiency that typically occurs before recessions was a lot more muted.

3 A framework to study movements in matching efficiency

In this section, we present a general framework to investigate the factors responsible for movements in aggregate matching efficiency. In particular, we identify two observable factors that affect aggregate matching efficiency: the composition of the unemployment pool, and the amount of dispersion in labor market conditions. The former arises if the characteristics of the unemployed change throughout the cycle, making job finding more or less likely, while the latter is caused by the concavity of the matching function and arises if tight labor markets coexist with slack labor markets.

3.1 Composition and dispersion

Denote  JF_{ij,t} the job finding probability of an individual of type  j in labor market segment  i.5 A labor market segment can be defined by its geographic location, industry group or occupation group. The labor market segment  i of individual type  j can then be thought of as the labor market in which individual  j is most likely to look for work and to find a job. Typically, this will be proxied by his location and past employment history. Individual type  j is defined by a vector of  K characteristics  \left\{ x_{jt}^{k}\right\} , and labor market segment  i is characterized by its labor market tightness (or vacancy-unemployment ratio)  \theta _{it}. Because an unemployed worker may also look outside of his labor market segment, his job finding probability may also depend on the aggregate labor market tightness  \theta _{t}.6

Thus, we postulate that the job finding probability of individual type  j in labor market i can be written

\displaystyle JF_{ij,t}=JF(X_{jt},\theta _{it},\theta _{t}) (4)

so that the average job finding rate is given by
\displaystyle JF_{t}=\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i,j}\frac{U_{ij,t}}{U_{t}}JF_{ij,t}. (5)

To highlight the effects of composition and dispersion on the average job finding probability, we take a second-order Taylor of expansion of  JF_{ij,t} with respect to  \theta _{it} around  \theta _{t} and  X_{jt} around  \bar{X}=\frac{1}{T.J}\displaystyle\sum\limits_{t,j}X_{jt} with  X_{jt}=[1,x_{jt}^{1},...,x_{jt}^{K}] and  x_{jt}^{k} the  kth observable characteristics of individual  j, and we get7

\displaystyle JF_{t}=\overline{JF}_{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) +\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) +\eta _{t}. (6)

The first term in (6),  \overline{JF}_{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) =JF_{ij,t}(\bar{X},\theta _{t},\theta _{t}), is the average job finding rate absent workers heterogeneity and dispersion.

3.1.0.1 Composition:

The second term in (6),  \displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}, captures the total composition effect with  JF_{t}^{k}, the contribution of a given characteristic  k to the average job finding probability8

\displaystyle JF_{t}^{k}=\displaystyle\sum\limits_{j}\frac{U_{j,t}}{U_{t}}\left. \frac{\partial JF}{ \partial x_{jt}^{k}}\right\vert _{\theta _{t},\bar{X}}\left( x_{jt}^{k}-\bar{ x}^{k}\right) . (7)

The composition effect arises because of worker heterogeneity. If the share  \frac{U_{j,t}}{U_{t}} of a demographic group (e.g. job losers) with a lower than average job finding probability (i.e.,  \left. \frac{\partial JF}{ \partial x_{jt}^{k}}\right\vert _{\theta _{t},\bar{X}}\left( x_{jt}^{k}-\bar{ x}^{k}\right) <0) increases in recessions, then the average job finding probability will decline without any change in individuals' job finding probabilities.

3.1.0.2 Dispersion:

The third term in (6) captures the effect of dispersion in labor market conditions on the average job finding probability with

\displaystyle MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) \displaystyle = \displaystyle MM_{0}\left( \theta _{t}\right) \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i}\frac{U_{i,t}}{U_{t}}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}-1\right) ^{2} (8)
  \displaystyle = \displaystyle MM_{0}\left( \theta _{t}\right) var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) \notag (9)

and  MM_{0}\left( \theta _{t}\right) =-\frac{1}{2}\theta _{t}^{2}\left. \frac{\partial ^{2}JF_{ij,t}}{\partial \theta _{it}^{2}}\right\vert _{\theta _{t},\bar{X}}.9 Dispersion in labor market tightness across segments will negatively affect the average job finding probability if the individual job finding probability is a concave function of  \theta _{it} (as would be the case with a matching function). With  \left. \frac{\partial ^{2}JF_{ij,t}}{ \partial \theta _{it}^{2}}\right\vert _{\theta _{t},\bar{X}}<0, an increase in dispersion across labor market segments, i.e., an increase in misallocation of jobs and workers, decreases the average job finding probability. For example, if some segments (such as health care) display a relatively tight labor market and some segments (such as manufacturing) display a slack labor market, the average job finding probability will be lower than in an economy where labor market tightness is identical across segments.

3.2 Postulating a functional form for  JF_{ij,t}

To bring our framework to the data, we need to posit a functional form for the job finding probability  JF_{ij,t}. We adopt a logistic functional form

\displaystyle \ln \frac{JF_{ij,t}}{1-JF_{ij,t}}=\beta X_{jt}+\ln \frac{1-e^{m_{0}\theta _{it}^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \omega }\theta _{t}^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \left( 1-\omega \right) }}}{e^{m_{0}\theta _{it}^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \omega }\theta _{t}^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \left( 1-\omega \right) }}} +\eta _{ij,t} (10)

with  \theta _{it}=\frac{v_{it}}{u_{it}},  X_{jt}=[1,x_{jt}^{1},..,x_{jt}^{K}]  \omega  \in \lbrack 0,1], and  m_{0} a constant term. This expression has two constant terms:  m_{0} and the constant term in  X_{jt}. To enable the estimation of  m_{0} , we demean the  X_{jt} variables before estimating equation(9).

This specification has a number of advantages:

First, a logistic functional form is consistent with the fact that the job finding probability falls between 0 and 1.

Second, in the absence of worker heterogeneity (  X_{jt}=\bar{X}) and labor market dispersion (  \theta _{it}=\theta _{t}), (9) reduces to  JF_{ij,t}=1-e^{-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}, the reduced-form aggregate specification (2) with  m_{0t}=m_{0}.

Third, to relate  \theta _{it} and  \theta _{t} to the job finding probability of individual type  j, we assume that the job finding probability is a geometric average of local labor market tightness  \theta _{it} and the aggregate labor market tightness  \theta _{t}. Put differently, we allow for the possibility that a worker crosses barriers between labor market segments, so that his job finding probability is not solely a function of tightness in his local labor market. To get some intuition, consider the simpler case without worker heterogeneity. The job finding rate of a worker in segment  i becomes  jf_{it}=m_{0}\theta _{it}^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \omega }\theta _{t}^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) (1-\omega )}, i.e. a weighted (geometric) average of the segment labor market tightness and the aggregate labor market tightness. The weight  \omega \in \lbrack 0,1] captures the impermeability of the local labor market. If  \omega =1, labor market segments are impossible to cross, and aggregate labor market tightness has no impact on the local job finding rate. In contrast, if there are no barriers between labor markets,  \omega =0 , a worker's job finding rate only depends on the aggregate labor market tightness.

3.3 A decomposition of aggregate matching efficiency

Thanks to our decomposition (6), we can now link movements in aggregate matching efficiency to the composition of the unemployment pool and the amount of dispersion in labor market conditions. After some manipulation of (6) left for the Appendix,  \mu _{t}=\ln m_{0t}- E  _{T}\ln m_{0t}, the deviations of aggregate matching efficiency from its average value, can be written

\displaystyle \mu _{t}\simeq \frac{e^{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-\Delta mm_{t}+\zeta _{t}. (11)

with

\displaystyle mm_{t}=\frac{1}{2}\omega (1-\sigma )\left[ (1-\omega (1-\sigma )\left( 1-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }\right) \right] var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}\right) (12)

and  \Delta mm_{t}=mm_{t}-E  _{T}mm_{t} with E _{T}(.) denoting the average over the estimation period.

Aggregate matching efficiency  m_{0t} is a function of the distribution of individual characteristics and labor market segments' tightness. Movements in aggregate matching efficiency can be decomposed into a composition effect, the first term on the right-hand side of (10), a dispersion (or misallocation) effect, the second term, and an unexplained component (that includes the approximation error), the last term.

Expression (11) describes the effect of misallocation (also called mismatch) on aggregate matching efficiency. Three observations are worth noting. First, the effect of misallocation is roughly proportional to the variance of labor market tightness, so that one can readily estimate the effect of misallocation by looking at the dispersion in labor market conditions.10 The literature on mismatch has used various measures to quantify the effect of misallocation on the unemployment rate. For example, some use  \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i}\left\vert \frac{U_{i}}{U}-\frac{V_{i}}{V} \right\vert (e.g., Jackman and Roper 1987, Franz 1991, Brunello 1991), others unemployment rate dispersion measures  \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i}u_{i}^{2} or  \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i}\left( \frac{u_{i}}{u}\right) ^{2} (e.g., Jackman, Layard and Savouri (1991), Attanasio and Padoa Schioppa (1991)), others  \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i}\left( \frac{U_{i}}{U}\frac{V_{i}}{V}\right) ^{1/2} (Bean and Pissarides, 1991), and others  \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i}\frac{E_{i}}{E}\left( \frac{U_{i}/E_{i}}{U/E}-\frac{V_{i}/E_{i}}{V/E}\right) ^{2} (Layard, Nickell and Jackman, 1991) with  E_{i} the number of employed workers in segment  i and  E the total number of employed workers. Some measures were constructed using employment or labor force weights (but surprisingly, rarely unemployment weights), but other measures did not weight observations. While all these measures capture the extent of dispersion across labor markets, absent a unifying framework, there was no consensus on the most appropriate measure. The measure we propose has an important advantage over these other measures: It can be directly related to aggregate matching efficiency and thus to the equilibrium unemployment rate (Barnichon and Figura, 2010).11

Second, while the mismatch literature imposes tight labor market segments boundaries, our framework allows for some permeability between labor market segments. The effect of dispersion on the average job finding rate and matching efficiency depends on  \omega . For the range of plausible values for  \sigma and  m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }, the effect of dispersion increases with barriers between labor market segments (i.e. when  \omega increases) and is strongest when labor market segments' barriers are infinite. Conversely, with higher permeability, workers are more likely to cross local labor market barriers and find a job in a different labor market, and this possibility weakens the effect of dispersion on aggregate matching efficiency.

Finally, because average dispersion is positive (  var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) \geq 0,  \forall t), the effect of misallocation on aggregate matching efficiency movements  \mu _{t} is not given by  mm_{t}, the level of dispersion, but by  \Delta mm_{t}, the deviations of dispersion from its average level.

4 Empirical results

4.1 Estimation

We use matched data from the Current Population Survey (CPS) covering January 1976 to December 2007 to estimate the Unemployment-Employment (UE) transition probability for an individual  j in labor market market segment  i. We restrict the estimation to pre-2008 data so that any changes in matching efficiency post 2007 do not affect our coefficient estimates. In 1994, a major redesign of the CPS survey was implemented and introduced breaks in many important variables, such as reason for unemployment and duration of unemployment.12 To control for these breaks, we estimate separate coefficients for the pre and post redesign periods. Our whole sample contains about 1.2 million observations.

In this section, we present the individual characteristics that influence the job finding probability, discuss our method for measuring labor market tightness by segment, and present results.

4.1.0.1 1. Controlling for individual characteristics

The CPS data provides information allowing us to control for changes in the characteristics of the unemployed. We use three main types of information: demographic, reason for unemployment and duration of unemployment, and we include a set of monthly dummies to control for seasonality in job finding probabilities.13

Demographic information includes the age and sex of the unemployed individual. We model the effect of age on the job finding probability using a quadratic in age. The CPS distinguishes between 5 main reasons for unemployment: permanent layoff, temporary layoff, new labor force entrant, reentering the labor force, and quit job. We use dummy variables for each reason. The CPS records the duration (in weeks) of individuals' current spells of unemployment, which we allow to linearly affect the probability of exit.

Prior research suggests that the job finding probability declines with duration, and two reasons are often cited. First, prolonged unemployment may lower individuals' skills relative to other job seekers, making them less desirable to employers, or it may reduce their contacts in job-finding networks, making it harder to find employment. Henceforth, we describe this effect as scarring. Second, prolonged unemployment may signal that the individuals have unobserved characteristics that make it difficult to find employment. Prolonged unemployment may also capture unobserved circumstances. For instance, an individual may be looking for work in a too narrow (relative to data availabilities), and hence unobservable, labor market segment with a very low vacancy-to-unemployment ratio. As such workers remain in the unemployment pool longer, the unobserved circumstances will be correlated with unemployment duration. Thus, unobserved characteristics or circumstances may be responsible for duration's ability to predict the job finding probability.

Average unemployment duration is also likely affected by aggregate labor market conditions. When labor demand is low, it typically takes unemployed individuals longer to find jobs, and durations rise. Thus, the signal about job finding prospects from an individual's unemployment duration may be weaker when average durations are higher. To allow the signal from an individual's unemployment duration to change as aggregate conditions change, we interact an individual's duration with the average duration, which is highly countercyclical. In effect, this specification allows the slope of the relationship between job finding and duration to change as aggregate conditions change.

4.1.0.2 2. Measuring labor market tightness by segment

To estimate the effect of dispersion in  \theta _{it} on aggregate matching efficiency, we need vacancy posting data by industry and region going back to 1976. Moreover, since the effect of misallocation arises out of the concavity of the matching function, it is important to reach a good level of disaggregation as dispersion increases with the number of observed segments. Unfortunately, the two data sources with vacancy posting data, the JOLTS and the Help-Wanted Indexes (HWI) from the Conference Board do not satisfy these criteria. JOLTS is only available since December 2000, and while the JOLTS measure of job openings can be disaggregated into 10 industry groups, the survey's sample size is too small to allow for a disaggregation by regions and industries.14 The HWI can be disaggregated by regions (the nine US Census divisions), but not by industry.

Instead, we use the unemployment rate to proxy for the labor market tightness in a particular segment. Regional and industry data on vacancy posting from the JOLTS over 2000-2010 show that vacancies and unemployment rates are highly negatively correlated across regions or industries, and that  \left( \frac{u_{it}}{u_{t}}\right) ^{\alpha } is a very good proxy for  \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} with no apparent break over 2008-2009. 15 We use the CPS micro data to estimate unemployment rates for each segment. Since new entrants to the labor force cannot be easily classified in a particular industry, we use the average unemployment rate in their state of residence. While the CPS sample is large (about 60,000 households) and allows for a higher level of disaggregation over 1976-2009 than available vacancy data, we nonetheless face some limitations regarding the degree of disaggregation we can achieve. We define 150 segments based on the cross product of 50 states and three broad industry groups.16 Our three broad industry groups roughly correspond to goods producing, business/health care/educational services, and other services.17

Accordingly, we estimate the slightly modified form of equation (9)

\displaystyle \ln \frac{JF_{ij,t}}{1-JF_{ij,t}^{UE}}=\beta X_{jt}+\ln \frac{ 1-e^{m_{0}\left( \frac{u_{it}}{u_{t}}\right) ^{\gamma }\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}{e^{m_{0}\left( \frac{u_{it}}{u_{t}}\right) ^{\gamma }\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}+\varepsilon _{ijt} (13)

by maximum likelihood with  \gamma =\alpha \left( 1-\sigma \right) \omega . To be able to infer an estimate of permeability,  \omega , from our estimate  \gamma , we will posit that  \alpha =-1.5, a value in the middle of the plausible range of our estimates for  \alpha .18

4.2 Results

4.2.1 Coefficient estimates

Table 2 reports our coefficient estimates. The coefficient on the aggregate vacancy-unemployment ratio is highly significant but is lower than the coefficient estimated in Section 2 using only aggregate labor market tightness. This suggests that characteristics and/or dispersion are on average procyclical, and that failing to control for those parameters biases estimates of the aggregate matching function elasticity upward.

The impermeability coefficient of labor market segments is significantly smaller than one (  \omega =.16/(1.5\ast .28)\simeq 0.4). While barriers between labor market segments appear to be non trivial, they are also not insurmountable. As a result, the effect of labor market tightness on exit hazards within a segment (  \omega (1-\sigma )=0.16) is not as great as the effect of aggregate labor market tightness (  (1-\sigma )(1-\omega )=0.22).

Turning to individual characteristics, JF is decreasing in unemployment duration. Using (6) and (7), the coefficient on unemployment duration implies that having a spell of unemployment lasting 6 months is associated with a decrease in an individual's job finding probability of about 1-  1\frac{1}{2} percentage point. However, the coefficient on the interaction of individual and aggregate duration implies that this effect is mitigated if the average unemployment duration is also high. In other words, the slope of the relationship between job finding and unemployment duration becomes flatter in downturns. As a result, increases in duration in a cyclical downswing do not send as strong a signal about reduced job finding probabilities as in other periods because these increases reflect, in part, changes in aggregate conditions, which we have already controlled for.

The estimates of the effect of the reason for unemployment on the job finding probability are relative to that of a job leaver. The estimates reveal that it is particularly difficult for permanent job losers and new entrants to the labor force to find employment. Unsurprisingly, workers on temporary layoff have an easier time becoming reemployed. As expected, the CPS redesign, by restricting temporary layoffs to individuals expecting to be recalled within 6 months, increased the difference in exit hazards for permanently and temporarily laid off workers.

Turning to demographics, the coefficient on the male dummy indicates that males are more likely to find jobs than females. However, a comparison of the pre and post redesign coefficients shows that this relative advantage has lessened over time. The estimated coefficients on the age variables indicate that the probability of job finding initially increases and then decreases with age. In the pre redesign period, the age with the highest job finding probability is around 30. In the post redesign period, it is close to 17.

4.2.2 The effect of individual characteristics and dispersion on the job finding probability

Next, we use our decomposition (6) to estimate the effect of individual characteristics and labor market dispersion on the average job finding probability over 1976-2009. Figure 2 graphs  \left\{ JF_{t}^{k}\right\} , the contributions of characteristics -reason for unemployment, unemployment duration, demographics-, and  MM_{t}, the contribution of dispersion in labor market tightness, to  JF_{t}.

The contribution of reason for unemployment is procyclical, falling in recessions and rising in recoveries. This pattern owes, in part, to an increasing share of permanent job losers and a declining share of temporary job losers during recessions. The contribution of duration is also procyclical. Although the coefficient on the interaction term suggests that the effect of duration on job finding probabilities is reduced in recessions, longer duration always implies a lower job finding probability. This indicates that some of the increase in individual durations during cyclically weak periods reflects scarring or unfavorable unobserved circumstances.

Demographics generate a downward trend in the average job finding probability over the sample period, as the labor force ages and women's share of the labor force increases, before leveling out at the end of the sample, as the share of men in the unemployment pool increases. Consistent with Baker (1992), demographic characteristics have little influence on the cyclical behavior of the job finding probability. Finally, the effect of dispersion on the job finding probability, given by (8), is very small because the cross-sectional variance of relative labor market tightness is too small, at least for the segments we observe, for misallocation to have a noticeable effect on aggregate matching efficiency.

4.2.3 Movements in aggregate matching efficiency

Using decomposition (10), the lower panel of Figure 2 presents movements in aggregate matching efficiency, in a similar fashion to Figure 1 , but allowing for a richer specification than the reduced-form approach ( 2) from Section 2. The plain thick line is analogous to the residual of Figure 1 and shows  \mu _{t}, the total movements in aggregate matching efficiency, given by (10). The plain thin line plots  \frac{e^{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-\Delta mm_{t}, the effect of composition and dispersion on  \mu _{t}. Finally, the dotted line plots the difference between the two other lines, i.e.  \zeta _{t}, the changes in aggregate matching efficiency that cannot be accounted for by composition or dispersion.

Up until 2006, composition accounted for most of the cyclical movements in aggregate matching efficiency. Changes in composition make aggregate matching efficiency procyclical because, as noted above, (i) the fraction of long-term unemployed increases during recessions, and (ii) a larger fraction of unemployed workers is on permanent layoff during recessions. Interestingly, the muted increase in aggregate matching efficiency in the run-up to the 2008-2009 recession can also be explained by composition, with both (i) and (ii) playing a role and demographics contributing to a downward trend in matching efficiency. Prior to 1994, the ability of composition to account for matching efficiency movements is not as good, and this is probably due to the quality of the data and the loose distinction between temporary and permanent layoff before 1994.19

Since 2007, a large fraction of the decline in aggregate matching function efficiency has been due to unobserved factors. Initially, the deterioration in late 2007 and 2008 owed almost entirely to unobservable factors, as observable components were relatively constant. Thereafter, observable factors, especially unemployment duration and reason for unemployment, began to contribute to the deterioration, and this contribution has grown steadily, while the unexplained component has been relatively constant. As a result, as of 2009Q4, observable factors account for about 40 percent of the decline in aggregate matching efficiency since 2007, while unobserved factors account for the remainder.

After controlling for dispersion and observed characteristics, the unexplained decline in matching efficiency amounts to about 0.15 log points in end 2009, compared to 0.20 log points (Figure 1) using a reduced-form regression (2) that only conditioned on aggregate labor market tightness. It is perhaps surprising that the difference between these two numbers is not larger given that changes in the composition of the unemployed have led to a deterioration in matching efficiency and are responsible for 40 percent of the total decline. The reason is that the deterioration in matching efficiency caused by changes in observed characteristics is in line with what one would have predicted conditioning on aggregate labor market tightness. As a result, these effects were already captured (in a reduced form sense) by the aggregate matching function regression. As mentioned above, the coefficient in the aggregate regression is larger than in a regression using micro data, because it reflects the correlation between aggregate labor market tightness and the characteristics of the unemployed.

4.2.4 Digging further: matching efficiency in the 2008-2009 recession

To try to understand the unexplained portion of the recent decline in aggregate matching efficiency, we explore several other estimation specifications.

4.2.4.1 Allowing for a break after 2007

First, we estimate (12) over 1976-2009 and allow for breaks in the coefficients on the right-hand-side variables after 2007. Specifically, each right-hand-side variable is interacted with a dummy variable equal to 1 after 2007. If the deterioration in matching efficiency is related to a larger contribution of permanent job losers or older workers, for example, then the post-2007 coefficients on permanent job loss or age should change to reflect this fact. If, however, the deterioration is not related to the observed characteristics of the unemployed, then it will be reflected by changes in the coefficients of the aggregate matching function.

Table 3 shows our estimation results, while Figure 3 shows the contributions of the right-hand-side variables after allowing for a break in the post 2007 coefficients. The deterioration in matching efficiency appears mostly as a higher aggregate elasticity (from 0.28 to 0.36) and as a larger effect of unemployment duration. As shown in Figure 3, the increase in unemployment duration has been associated with a large decrease in matching efficiency. The coefficient on the interaction between average duration and individual duration has decreased significantly post 2007. Whereas in previous recessions, the contribution of individual duration to a reduction in job finding was attenuated (because it likely reflected aggregate labor market conditions, already controlled for, rather than individual circumstances) in the most recent recession, this was not the case and the effect of duration on matching efficiency was stronger. Changes in other characteristics have had little effect.

The lower panel of Figure 3 repeats the lower panel of Figure 2, which shows the explained and unexplained components of the deterioration in matching efficiency, except that Figure 3 includes in the explained component the part explained by a break in post-2007 coefficients. The explained component now accounts for somewhat more (50 versus 40 percent) of the deterioration in matching efficiency. Moreover, the fraction of explained variation seems to grow overtime, due largely to the duration component. This pattern suggests that duration is capturing the effect of unobserved circumstances, rather than scarring, on the job finding probability. Indeed, if unobserved circumstances lowered the job finding probability of some individuals, the contribution of the unexplained component to lower matching efficiency would be large initially. But with time, it would fade as the (increasing) unemployment duration of the affected individuals began to capture the effect of the unobserved circumstances. This pattern is not what one would expect, however, if scarring were the explanation for the explanatory power of duration.

4.2.4.2 The effect of extended emergency unemployment benefits

Next, we study whether the increases in the maximum length of eligibility for unemployment insurance, which went into effect at the onset of the recession, have had any effect on worker's search intensity and thus on matching efficiency. To identify the effect of extended and emergency unemployment benefits (EEB) on job finding probabilities, we follow a strategy used by Kuang and Valletta (2010) who note that job losers are predominantly eligible for unemployment insurance (UI) benefits while job leavers and new labor force entrants are not. While Kuang and Valletta (2010) study the effect of EEB on unemployment durations, we identify the effect of EEB on the job finding probability by interacting a job loser dummy with a post-2008 dummy (the period when EEB was in full effect) in our regression (12). We find that EEB has little effect on job finding probabilities.20 The coefficient on the interaction between the job loser dummy and the post 2008 dummy is nearly identical to that on the interaction between the other unemployed dummy and the 2008 dummy.

4.2.4.3 Is the deterioration in matching efficiency concentrated by sector or region?

Next, we look at whether the deterioration in matching efficiency has been concentrated by industry or by location.21 To do so, we estimate two separate specifications of (12), where we interact a post-2007 dummy with, respectively, dummies for an individual's last industry of employment, and dummies for an individual's current state of residence. If the deterioration in matching efficiency is concentrated, then there will be significant differences in the interaction coefficients across industries or states. One can think of these interaction terms as shifts in local labor market or industry Beveridge curves.

Turning first to concentration by industry, we find that there is no significant difference across our three broad industry categories. The coefficients on the post-2007 interaction terms are almost identical, and the decline in matching efficiency appears to be present in all industry groups.

In contrast, there are statistically significant differences in the deterioration in matching efficiency across states. However, there is no apparent pattern to the differences. The top 5 states (in terms of deterioration) are (in order) Florida, South Carolina, New Hampshire, Minnesota, and Missouri. The presence of Florida is perhaps unsurprising as that state has suffered a large drop in home prices and a large number of foreclosures. The drop in home prices may have increased the number of homeowners who are underwater on their mortgages and therefore less mobile than other households. At the same time, large numbers of foreclosures may signal the presence of many homeowners with scarce financial resources and little ability to borrow, which might also impede mobility. Still, three other states often mentioned with Florida as states with particularly bad housing markets, Nevada, Arizona and California, are not in the top 10 (Nevada is 14th, Arizona 18th and California 28th), and the remaining states in the top 5 have no apparent similarities.22

4.2.4.4 Discussion

From these results we take away two main conclusions. First, many of the popular explanations for the deterioration in aggregate matching efficiency find little support in the data. For example, some observers have speculated that job finding difficulties of unemployed workers from the construction industry, which was particularly hard hit in the last recession, were behind the deterioration in matching efficiency. We find the deterioration in matching efficiency to be widespread across industries, consistent with Barnichon, Elsby, Hobijn and Sahin's (2010) findings based on JOLTS data that the decline in the vacancy yield is relatively broad-based across industries. Other observers suggested that underwater mortgages and their detrimental effect on mobility were responsible for the deterioration in match efficiency. Although Florida, a state with particularly hard hit real estate markets, did appear to suffer particularly large deteriorations in matching efficiency, three other states with problem real estate markets--Nevada, Arizona and California--did not. More generally, the geographic distribution of match efficiency did not suggest real estate, or any other factor, as a single cause. Finally, the advent of EEB does not appear responsible for the deterioration in matching efficiency, although it does appear to have dissuaded some individuals from dropping out of the labor force.

Second, much of the deterioration in aggregate matching efficiency seems to be associated with long-duration spells of unemployment. Moreover, the timing pattern of the decline in efficiency, in which the fraction of the decline that is unexplained has rapidly decreased over time, suggests that unobserved characteristics, rather than scarring, explain the correlation between duration and deterioration in matching efficiency. These unobserved characteristics could be related to a mismatch between workers' skills and location and the skills/location required by available jobs. Although we have found little evidence of misallocation, our dispersion measure has been highly aggregated, and dispersion may be occurring at a much more disaggregated level. We explore this possibility in the next section.

5 More evidence on dispersion

Our empirical exercise has so far relied on the unemployment rate by state and industry to proxy for labor market tightness and capture the extent of dispersion across labor market segments. In this section, we instead use direct measures of vacancy posting, and, using three different datasets, we consider three measures of dispersion: (i) dispersion by industry, (ii) dispersion by region, and (iii) dispersion by occupation and geographic location.

Available dispersion measures are confronted with two limitations. First, not all hires occur with the formal posting of a vacancy, and the fraction of informal hiring is not necessarily identical across occupation, industry or geographic location. As a result, dispersion in labor market tightness need not solely capture misallocation of jobs and workers but also the fact that some segments have a higher level of informal hiring than others. Second, the level of disaggregation allowed by direct measures of labor market tightness is probably too coarse to capture the full extent of dispersion. To address these two measurement issues, we rely on a simpler framework which abstracts from worker heterogeneity and allows us to (i) estimate the fraction of informal hiring by segment, and (ii) use UK data to infer the extent of dispersion at a very fine level of disaggregation.

5.1 A simpler empirical framework

To explore whether dispersion can account for the 0.15 log points decline in matching efficiency not accounted for by composition, we simplify our empirical framework by considering the case without worker heterogeneity but using the elasticity estimated after controlling for composition, i.e.,  \sigma =0.72. Without worker heterogeneity, the job finding rate in segment  i absent worker heterogeneity is given by

\displaystyle jf_{it}=m_{0}\theta _{it}^{\omega (1-\sigma )}\theta _{t}^{(1-\omega )(1-\sigma )} (14)

and the effect of dispersion on aggregate matching efficiency movements is given by
\displaystyle \Delta mm_{t}\simeq \frac{1}{2}\omega (1-\sigma )(1-\omega (1-\sigma ))\left[ var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) -\text{E}_{T}var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) \right] . (15)

5.2 Data on labor market tightness by segment

We consider three datasets. First, the JOLTS measure of job openings can be disaggregated into 10 industry groups over 2000-2010.23 Second, the Conference Board Help-Wanted Index originally proxied for the number of help-wanted advertisements in 51 major newspapers. While the print index is not disaggregated by industries, the index can be disaggregated by region, and an index of newspaper help-wanted advertising for the nine US census divisions is available. These newspaper indexes have become increasingly unrepresentative with the advent of online advertising, and the Conference Board began collecting data on online job posting in 2005.24 By splicing the regional print help-wanted indexes with online job openings by regions as in Barnichon (2010), we build composite indexes of print and online vacancy posting for the nine US census divisions over 2000-2010.

Third, since November 2006, the Conference Board has published the number of help-wanted online ads by state and occupation, as well as the number of ads by metropolitan statistical areas (MSA) and occupation. The coverage of these two datasets is unique as it allows us to build a direct counterpart of  \frac{v_{it}}{u_{it}} at a high level of disaggregation. To the best of our knowledge, these datasets are the first ones to contain information on vacancy posting in the US by occupation and geographic location. Moreover, we expand the coverage of each dataset by combining the state-level information with the MSA-level information to produce series of vacancy posting by occupation and geographic areas across the US. With 50 states and 52 MSAs, we get a total of 94 geographic areas. 25 The Conference Board reports online ads for six occupation groups.26 After combining these vacancy series with the number of unemployed by geographic area and occupation estimated from the CPS, we can survey the extent of dispersion over  94\ast 6=564 labor market segments during the 2008-2009 recession.

One concern about using vacancy data by segment is that some segments may have a higher share of informal hiring. For example, it is likely that a lot of hiring in construction occurs without the formal posting of a vacancy. While the aggregate vacancy-unemployment ratio from Conference Board data averaged 1.1 in 2006, the vacancy-unemployment ratio averaged 0.5 in construction and maintenance but about 4 in management and business/financial. Similarly, because a broad industry group may contain industries with different levels of informal hiring, the levels of job openings may not be comparable across regions with different industry specializations. For example, labor market tightness in services is on average three times higher in Denver than in New York. Similarly, rural areas and urban areas need not display the same fraction of informal hiring.

Because of such differences in informal hiring, dispersion in observed labor market tightness need not solely capture misallocation of jobs and workers but also the fact that some segments have a higher level of informal hiring than others. Formally, informal hiring is akin to measurement error in vacancy posting, as we do not measure  \theta _{it} but  \tilde{\theta} _{it} with  \theta _{it}=\alpha _{i}\tilde{\theta}_{it} and  \alpha _{i} the share of formal hiring.27 With  \theta _{t}=\sum_{i}\frac{U_{it}}{U_{t}}\theta _{it} , we then get  \theta _{t}=\alpha _{0t}\tilde{\theta}_{t} with  \alpha _{0t}=\sum_{i}\frac{V_{it}}{V_{t}}\alpha _{i}. According to (14), the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency is thus a function of  var\left( \frac{\alpha _{i}}{\alpha _{0t}}\frac{\tilde{\theta}_{it}}{\tilde{ \theta}_{t}}\right) .

To estimate  \frac{\alpha _{i}}{\alpha _{0t}} for each dataset, we use data on the job finding rate by segment. Taking the log of  jf_{it}=m_{0}\theta _{it}^{\omega (1-\sigma )}\theta _{t}^{(1-\omega )(1-\sigma )} for segment  i and an arbitrarily chosen segment 1, we can back-out  \ln \frac{\alpha _{i}}{\alpha _{1}} from the regression

\displaystyle \ln jf_{it}-\ln jf_{1t}=\omega (1-\sigma )\ln \frac{\alpha _{i}}{\alpha _{1}} +\omega (1-\sigma )\left( \ln \tilde{\theta}_{it}-\ln \tilde{\theta} _{1t}\right) +\xi _{t} (16)

where we take the log-difference between two segments to remove the non-observable parameter  \alpha _{0t}. We then obtain  \frac{\alpha _{0t}}{ \alpha _{1}} from  \frac{\alpha _{0t}}{\alpha _{1}}=\sum_{i}\frac{U_{it}}{ U_{t}}\frac{\alpha _{i}}{\alpha _{1}}, and we get  \frac{\alpha _{i}}{ \alpha _{0t}}=\frac{\alpha _{i}}{\alpha _{1}}/\frac{\alpha _{0t}}{\alpha _{1} }. For the online help-wanted ads by occupation and geography, the level of disaggregation is such that the sample size of the CPS is a limitation and the monthly measures of the job finding rate and unemployment over 564 segments are noisy. We thus use variables at their average values over 2006-2010 and, assuming a value for  \omega (1-\sigma ) (we take  \omega =0.4 and  \sigma =0.72), we can compute  \frac{\alpha _{i}}{\alpha _{1}} from (14).28

5.3 Dispersion measures

Figure 4 plots the dispersions in labor market tightness over 2000-2010 using our three data sources. JOLTS data indicate that dispersion across ten industry groups increased in the 2008-2009 recession by about twice as much as during the 2001 recession, but that it receded in 2009. Dispersion across the 9 census divisions also rose in the 2008-2009 recession, but the increase started in late 2006, earlier than for sectoral dispersion. In comparison, the increases in regional dispersion in the 2001 recession were small.

Dispersion by geography and occupation shows a clear increase in the 2008-2009 recession, and Figure 4 shows that the behavior of the series matches very well with the behavior of the unexplained component of Figure 2 . In fact, the correlation between the two series is high at 0.82. Over 2007-2008, the increase in dispersion coincides with the decline in match efficiency, while composition was flat (Figure 2). In 2009, both dispersion and the unexplained component of matching efficiency peaked before declining slightly.

Geography/occupation dispersion was constant in 2009 while both dispersion across regions and dispersion across industry groups declined. These different results highlight the importance of looking simultaneously at geography and occupation or industry when studying the effect of dispersion. Thus in the rest of the paper, we will concentrate on dispersion by geography and occupation, which we think provides the most accurate description of dispersion in labor market conditions.

5.4 Inferring the true amount of dispersion from UK data

Because the effect of dispersion arises out of the concavity of the matching function, it is crucial to reach a good level of disaggregation. Our highest level of disaggregation covers only 564 labor market segments, probably a small amount compared to the true number of segments in the US. As Shimer (2007) emphasized, the Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) counts about 800 occupations, and there are 362 metropolitan statistical areas and 560 micropolitan statistical areas, so a total of about 740,000 labor market segments.29

Thus, we now present a method using UK data to scale up our measure of dispersion over 564 segments to a more realistic number of labor market segments. Define an elementary labor market segment as the smallest segment in which the matching function is still well described by (13). We will refer to an elementary segment as a unit. The effect of misallocation on matching efficiency is thus given by the dispersion in labor market conditions across such units. We cannot observe labor market tightness at the unit level. Instead, we observe  \bar{\theta}_{jt}=\frac{1}{m} \sum\limits_{j_{k}\in I_{j}}\theta _{_{j_{k}}t}, the average value of the  \theta _{i}s over segment  j, consisting of m  \equiv \frac{\bar{N} }{N} units indexed by  I_{j}=\{j_{1},..,j_{m}\}\subset \lbrack 1,\bar{N}] with  \bar{N} the total number of units and  N the number of observed (larger) segments. Thus, we cannot measure  var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}\right) , the dispersion over the  \bar{N} units, but we can measure  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) , the variance in labor market tightness over  N larger segments with n  \equiv \frac{N}{\bar{N}}\leq 1.30

To relate these two quantities and get an estimate of  var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}\right) from  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) , we turn to UK data. Unlike the US, the UK public employment office collects vacancies by occupation and geography at very different levels of disaggregation, from low levels of disaggregation to very high levels of disaggregation (as high as 80,000 segments). These numbers can in turn be matched to the number of job seekers' allowance claimants to construct measures of labor market tightness across various occupation and geographic segments.31 With these data, we can then establish an empirical "scaling law"that captures how  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) increases when we raise the number of observations  Nand consider smaller labor market segments.

The UK data by occupation are available at the one- to four- digits SOC levels, consisting of respectively 9, 25, 81 and 353 groups, and we use data by geographic region at three disaggregation levels; government office regions (11 segments), Job Center plus Districts (48 segments), and Travel to Work Areas (232 segments). Thanks to these different levels of disaggregation, we can probe how  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) varies as we increase the precision of observations from  N=N_{occ}\ast N_{geo}=9\ast 11=99 segments to  353\ast 232=81,896 segments. To increase the sample size, we took averages of unemployment and vacancy data over the whole sample period July 2006-July 2010.32

A simple theoretical framework left for the Appendix shows that we could expect a relation of the form

\displaystyle var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) =var\left( \frac{ \theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) f(n_{geo},n_{occ}) with \displaystyle n_{geo}=\frac{N_{geo}}{\bar{N}_{geo}},n_{occ}=\frac{N_{occ}}{\bar{N}_{occ}} (17)

with  f(n_{geo},n_{occ})\leq 1,  f(.) increasing and  f\rightarrow 1 when  (n_{geo},n_{occ})\rightarrow (1,1), and where  f(.) can be assumed to be time invariant.

Empirically, a power law  \ln var_{n}(\frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}} )=\ln a_{0}+a_{1}\ln n_{geo}+a_{2}\ln n_{occ} fits the UK data extremely well with an  R^{2} of 0.98 (Table 4).33 This encouragingly suggests that one need not probe the data at a very high level of disaggregation to estimate the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency, but can instead use  f(n_{geo},n_{occ})=n_{geo}^{a_{1}}n_{occ}^{a_{2}} to scale up our estimate  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) . To illustrate the empirical relation, Figure 5 plots the relationship between the total number of observed segments and  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) as we increase the number of occupation categories from 9 (comparable with the 6 occupations observed using Conference Board data) to 353, and holding the number of geographic areas constant at 48 (comparable with the 94 areas observed using Conference Board data).

Assuming that  f(.) is similar in the UK and in the US (i.e. that the scaling law parameters  a_{1} and  a_{2} are not country specific) 34 and given an estimate of the number of labor market units  \bar{N}_{geo} and  \bar{N} _{occ}, we can use the UK scaling law to build an estimator of  var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) :

\displaystyle \widehat{var}_{n}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) \equiv \frac{ var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) }{ f(n_{geo},n_{occ})}. (18)

Assuming that there are 353 distinct occupations in the US and 232 geographic segments, probably a conservative estimate given Shimer's (2007) aforementioned observation and the fact that the US is, geography-wise, much larger than the UK, we get that  f(\frac{94}{232},\frac{6}{353})\simeq 1/20 , so that an increased in measured dispersion in online HWI from 0.25 to 0.5 between November 2006 and December 2009 for ( N_{occ}=6,  N_{geo} =94) translates into an increase from 5 to 10 when ( N_{occ}=353,  N_{geo} =232).

5.5 Effects of dispersion on matching efficiency

To translate our estimated increase in dispersion into lower matching efficiency, we need to address one final issue. The previous section suggests that the increase in dispersion in labor market conditions lead to a high value of  var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}\right) at about 10 in 2009. With such high dispersion, the Taylor expansion (14) need not provide a good approximation of the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency.

Instead, we resort to numerical simulations to calculate the exact effect of dispersion on matching efficiency. If the job finding rate in segment  i is described by (13),  mm, the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency is given by the difference in the average job finding rate when  \frac{\theta _{i}}{\theta } always equals 1 and when  \frac{\theta _{i}}{\theta } is distributed with variance  \sigma _{\theta }^{2}. Specifically,

\displaystyle mm=\ln \sum_{i}\frac{U_{i}}{U}m_{0}\theta _{i}^{\omega (1-\sigma )}\theta ^{(1-\omega )(1-\sigma )}-\ln m_{0}\theta ^{1-\sigma } (19)

and we calculate  mm=mm(\sigma _{\theta }^{2}) by positing that  \ln \frac{ \theta _{i}}{\theta }\sim N(\frac{-\ln \left( 1+\sigma _{\theta }^{2}\right) }{2},\ln \left( 1+\sigma _{\theta }^{2}\right) ), so that E  \frac{\theta _{i}}{\theta }=1 and var(  \frac{\theta _{i}}{\theta })=  \sigma _{\theta }^{2}. Figure 6 shows how changing  \sigma _{\theta }^{2} affects  mm and aggregate matching efficiency. Moreover, because it is difficult to estimate the permeability of labor market segments, Figure 6 also plots the effect of  \omega on the relationship between dispersion and matching efficiency. That way, we can report the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency for different values of  \omega .

With the variance of  \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} increasing from about 5 in November 2006 to about 10 in December 2009, misallocation can explain 26 percent (0.04 log-points out of the 0.15 unexplained log-decline in  jf, cf. Figure 2) of the decline in matching efficiency when  \omega =0.4, about 36 percent (.055 log points) when  \omega =0.6 , and about 20 percent (.03 log-points) when  \omega =0.3.35 As a very conservative estimate, we can take the increase in dispersion from online HWI at face value (an increase from 0.25 to 0.5) and not use the UK scaling law. In that case, dispersion accounts for about 10 percent (0.015 log-points) of the unexplained decline in matching efficiency (using  \omega =0.4).

Thus, we conclude that an increase in labor market dispersion likely led to a noticeable decline in matching efficiency, though a significant fraction of the overall decline remains unexplained.36

5.6 Taking stock

It is difficult to estimate the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency because data on vacancies and unemployment at high levels of disaggregation are not available. However, with some assumptions, one can use the available data to estimate the effect of dispersion at high levels of disaggregation. These assumptions are: (1) most of the differences in matching efficiency across segments are due to different fractions of informal hiring, (2) the UK scaling relationship linking  var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}\right) , the actual dispersion in labor market conditions, to  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{jt}}{\theta _{t}}\right) , the dispersion measured over a number of larger segments, is time invariant and can be applied to the US. Given these assumptions, it is likely that greater dispersion has accounted for a substantial portion -about a quarter but possibly more- of the unexplained drop in matching efficiency over the past three years.

6 Conclusion

In this paper, we study the determinants of aggregate matching efficiency fluctuations over the last four decades.

Under fairly general assumptions, we link movements in aggregate matching efficiency to two measurable factors: (i) composition of the unemployment pool, and (ii) dispersion in labor market conditions. We also show that the effect of misallocation on aggregate matching efficiency is a function of the dispersion in conditions across labor markets segment and of the segments' permeability. While a number of dispersion measures have been proposed in the literature, our framework provides a dispersion measure -the variance of labor market tightness- that can be analytically related to matching efficiency and to the equilibrium unemployment rate.

Using CPS micro data over 1976-2009, we find that changes in composition of the unemployment pool generate non-trivial procyclical movements in matching efficiency, implying that estimates of the aggregate matching function elasticity are biased upwards. Until 2006, the composition of the unemployment pool (mostly the share of job losers on permanent layoffs and the share of long-term unemployed) is responsible for most of the cyclical movements in matching efficiency, while dispersion in labor market conditions appears to have played a modest role. Since 2006, composition explains only 40 percent of a dramatic decline in matching efficiency. Instead, the behavior of the unexplained decline is highly (negatively) correlated with dispersion in labor market conditions. Quantitatively, misallocation of workers and jobs may account for a quarter, and perhaps more, of the unexplained decline. We also test a number of popular explanations but find no evidence that matching efficiency was affected by the extension of unemployment coverage, by a " house-lock"or by industry specific shocks.

A remaining question is what accounted for the remaining unexplained decline in matching efficiency. An obvious possibility, given the difficulty to assess dispersion at high levels of disaggregation, is that our UK scaling law lead us to understate the extent of the increase in dispersion and hence the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency. Another possibility, not tested in this paper, is that part of the decline in matching efficiency was caused by a compositional change in vacancy posting. For example, because the construction sector has a high fraction of informal hiring (and hence an apparently high matching efficiency), a decline in the fraction of construction ads among vacancies will lower matching efficiency. However, Barnichon, Elsby, Hobijn and Sahin (2010) do not find that vacancy composition significantly contributed to the decline in the vacancy yield. A related hypothesis raised by Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger (2010) is that firms vary recruiting intensity during recessions. Despite the fact that our empirical framework does not allow for varying recruiting intensity, it can successfully capture job finding probability movements over 1976-2006. This suggests that aggregate labor market tightness (or sectoral tightness) can proxy for varying recruiting intensity over that period. Thus, if the recent unexplained decline in matching efficiency was caused by lower recruiting intensity, this would imply that recruiting intensity was exceptionally low in the current recession. Assessing this hypothesis would be an interesting goal for future research.


Bibliography

Abraham K. "Mismatch and Labour Mobility: some final remarks,"in Mismatch and Labor Mobility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Attanasio O. and F. Padoa Schioppa. "Regional Inequalities, migration and mismatch in Italy, 1690
-86," in Mismatch and Labor Mobility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Baker M. "Unemployment Duration: Compositional Effects and Cyclical Variability,"American Economic Review, 1992.
Barnichon R. "Building a composite Help-Wanted index,"Economics Letters, 2010.
Barnichon R., M. Elsby, B. Hobijn, A. Sahin. " Which Industries are Shifting the Beveridge Curve? Working Paper, 2010.
Barnichon R. and A. Figura. "What Drives Movements in the Unemployment Rate? A Decomposition of the Beveridge Curve,"FEDS Working Paper, 2010.
Bean C. and C. Pissarides. "Skill shortages and structural unemployment in Britain: a (mis)matching approach,"in Mismatch and Labor Mobility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Bleakley H. and J. Fuhrer. Shifts in the Beveridge Curve Job Matching, and Labor Market Dynamics,"New England Economic Review, 1997.
Brunello G. "Mismatch in Japan,"in Mismatch and Labor Mobility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Davis S., J. Faberman and J. Haltiwanger. "The Establishment-Level Behavior of Vacancies and Hiring," NBER Working Paper, 2010.
Elsby M., B. Hobijn and A. Sahin. "The Labor Market in the Great Recession,"Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1-48, 2010.
Farber H "Job Loss and Unemployment in the 21st Century: the Great Recession in Labor Market Perspective," Industrial Relations Section , Princeton University Working Paper,560, 2010.
Franz W. "Match and mismatch on the German labour market,"in Mismatch and Labor Mobility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Fujita S. "Effects of the UI Benefit Extensions: Evidence from the Monthly CPS,"Philadelphia Fed Working Paper 10-35, 2010.
Jackman R. and S. Roper. "Structural Unemployment,"Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 49(1), 9-36, 1987.
Jackman R., R. Layard, and S. Savouri. " Mismatch: a framework for thought,"in Mismatch and Labor Mobility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Layard R. S. Nickell, and R. Jackman. Unemployment: Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market, 2nd Edition, Oxford University Press, 2005.
Kaplan G. and S. Schulhofer-Wohl. "Interstate migration has fallen less than you think: Consequences of hot deck imputation in the Current Population Survey,"Working Paper, 2010.
Katz Lawrence, and Bruce Meyer. "The Impact of the Potential Duration of Unemployment Benefits on the Duration of Unemployment,"Journal of Public Economics, 41 pp. 45-72, 1991.
Kuang K. and R. Valletta. "Extended Unemployment and UI Benefits,"FRBSS Economic Letter, 2010.
Meyer Bruce. "Unemployment Insurance and Unemployment Spells,"Econometrica, 58:4, pp. 757-82, 1990.
Moffitt Robert. "Unemployment Insurance and the Distribution of Unemployment Spells,"Journal of Econometrics, 28, pp. 85-101, 1985
Molloy R., C. Smith and A. Wozniac. "Internal Migration in the US: Updated Facts and Recent Trends," mimeo, University of Notre Dame, 2010.
Padoa Schioppa F. Mismatch and Labor Mobility, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Petrongolo B. and C. Pissarides. "Looking into the black box: A survey of the matching function,"Journal of Economic Literature, 39: 390-431, 2001.
Pissarides C. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd ed, MIT Press, 2000.
Sahin A. J. Song, G. Topa, and G. Violante. " Mismatch in the Labor Market: Evidence from the UK and the US," mimeo, 2010.
Shimer R. "Mismatch,"American Economic Review, 97(4):, 1074
-1101, 2007.


A second-order Taylor expansion of the job finding probability

Rewriting (9), the individual job finding probability is given by

\displaystyle JF_{ij,t}=\frac{\left( 1-e^{m_{0}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) ^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \omega }\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\right) e^{\beta X_{jt}}}{e^{m_{0}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) ^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \omega }\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}+\left( 1-e^{m_{0}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) ^{\left( 1-\sigma \right) \omega }\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\right) e^{\beta X_{jt}}}+\eta _{it}.    

Expanding with respect to  X_{jt} around  \bar{X} and  \theta _{it} around  \theta _{t} to a second-order,  JF_{t} becomes
\displaystyle JF_{t}=\overline{JF}_{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) +\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) +f_{t}+\eta _{t}    

with
\displaystyle JF_{t}^{k} \displaystyle = \displaystyle e^{-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\left( 1-e^{-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\right) \displaystyle\sum\limits_{j}\frac{U_{j,t}}{U_{t}}[\beta _{k}\left( x_{jt}^{k}-\bar{x}^{k}\right) -\frac{1}{2}\left( 1-2e^{-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\right) \beta _{k}^{2}\left( x_{jt}^{k}- \bar{x}^{k}\right) ^{2}  
    \displaystyle +\frac{1}{2}\displaystyle\sum\limits_{l\neq k}\left( 1-2e^{-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\right) \beta _{k}\left( x_{jt}^{k}-\bar{x}^{k}\right) \beta _{l}\left( x_{jt}^{l}-\bar{x}^{l}\right) ]  

the (second-order) composition effect from characteristic  k on the average job finding rate,
\displaystyle MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) =MM_{0}\left( \theta _{t}\right) \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i}\frac{U_{i,t}}{U_{t}}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}-1\right) ^{2}    

the term capturing the effect of dispersion on the average job finding rate with  MM_{0}\left( \theta _{t}\right) =\frac{1}{2}\left( \sigma +(1-\sigma )m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }\right) m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }e^{-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }} and
\displaystyle f_{t}=\omega (1-\sigma )\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i,j}\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}\frac{U_{ij,t}}{ U_{t}}m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }\left( 2m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }-1\right) \left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}-1\right) \beta _{k}\left( x_{jt}^{k}-\bar{x}^{k}\right) .    

capturing the interaction of composition and dispersion.37

Decomposing movements in aggregate matching efficiency

To establish a link between aggregate movements in matching efficiency and changes in composition and dispersion, we write the job finding rate  jf_{t} as a function of the job finding probability  JF_{t}, and use (6) to get

\displaystyle jf_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle -\ln \left( 1-JF_{t}\right)  
  \displaystyle = \displaystyle -\ln \left( 1-\left( \overline{JF}_{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) +\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) +\eta _{t}\right) \right)  
  \displaystyle = \displaystyle -\ln \left( 1-\overline{JF}_{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) \right) -\ln \left( 1-\frac{1}{1-\overline{JF}_{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) }\left( \displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) +\eta _{t}\right) \right)  
  \displaystyle \simeq \displaystyle \overline{jf}\left( \theta _{t}\right) +\frac{1}{1-\overline{JF} _{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) }\left( \displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) +\eta _{t}\right)  

with  \overline{jf}\left( \theta _{t}\right) \equiv -\ln \left( 1-\overline{ JF}_{t}\left( \theta _{t}\right) \right) .

Using the functional form (9), we have  \overline{jf}\left( \theta _{t}\right) =m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }, and taking the log of the previous expression gives us

\displaystyle \ln jf_{t} \displaystyle \simeq \displaystyle \ln m_{0}+(1-\sigma )\ln \theta _{t} \notag (20)
    \displaystyle +\ln \left( 1+\frac{e^{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\left( \displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) +\eta _{t}\right) \right) \notag (21)
  \displaystyle \simeq \displaystyle \ln m_{0}+(1-\sigma )\ln \theta _{t} \notag (22)
    \displaystyle +\underset{A_{t}}{\underbrace{\frac{e^{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}{ m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\left( \displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) +\eta _{t}\right) }} (23)

where for the last expression, we used the fact that  m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }e^{-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}\gg \displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} \right) +\eta _{t}. Expression (19) has the same form as our aggregate regression (2).

Thus, the deviations of aggregate matching efficiency from its average level can be written

\displaystyle \mu _{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \ln m_{0t}-E_{T}\ln m_{0t}  
  \displaystyle = \displaystyle \ln jf_{t}-(1-\sigma )\ln \theta _{t}-E\displaystyle _{T}\left( \ln jf_{t}-(1-\sigma )\ln \theta _{t}\right)  
  \displaystyle \simeq \displaystyle A_{t}-E\displaystyle _{T}A_{t} using (19)  
  \displaystyle \simeq \displaystyle \frac{e^{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma } }\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k}-\Delta mm_{t}+\zeta _{t}  

with  mm_{t}=\frac{e^{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}}{m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }}MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) and  \Delta mm_{t}=mm_{t}-E  _{T}mm_{t}.38 Using the expression for  MM_{t}\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) , the effect of dispersion on matching efficiency movements is then given by
\displaystyle \Delta mm_{t}\simeq \frac{1}{2}\omega (1-\sigma )\left[ (1-\omega (1-\sigma )\left( 1-m_{0}\theta _{t}^{1-\sigma }\right) \right] \left[ var\left( \frac{ \theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) -\text{E}_{T}var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}\right) \right] .    

Appendix

Not for publication


Table A1: Proxying  \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}} with  \left( \frac{u_{it}}{u_{t}}\right) ^{\alpha }

Dependent variable:  \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}  \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}  \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}  \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}
Sample (quarterly frequency) Data source 2000-2010 JOLTS Industry groups 2000-2009 JOLTS US Census Regions 2006-2010 Conference Board Occupations 2006-2010 Conference Board State/MSA regions
 \alpha -1.34*** -1.32*** -1.71*** -1.29***
 \alpha standard error (0.03) (0.11) (0.08) (0.02)
Number of observations 1170 444 234 3510
R {}^{2} 0.76 0.73 0.89 0.83

Note: Standard-errors are reported in parentheses. All panel regressions include industry or region fixed effects. The first two regressions include a quadratic trend. The first two columns use vacancy measures from the JOLT, and the last two columns use data on online advertising from the Conference Board.


Table A2: Effects of EEB on UE and UN transition probabilities in the 2008-2009 recession

  UE probability UN probability
Job loser -0.12 -0.22
Job loser standard error (0.02) (0.02)
Non job loser -0.16 -0.05
Non job loser standard error (0.02) (0.02)

Note: The two rows report the coefficients on the interaction term between a post-2008 dummy and, respectively, a job loser and non-job loser dummy. In the first column, the dependent variable is the UE transition probability, and in the second column, the dependent variable is the UN transition probability.


Table A3: Coefficients on post-2007 last industry of employment dummy

Industry Coefficients
Goods production -0.11
Goods production standard error (0.02)
Professional services -0.13
Professional services standard error (0.02)
Sales and other services -0.12
Sales and other services standard error (0.02)
No industry (new entrant) -0.15
No industry (new entrant) standard error (0.04)

Note: Except for the industry dummy, the regression is identical to Table 3. Other coefficients are little changed and are available upon request.

Table A4: Coefficients on post-2007 state of residence dummy

State of residence Coefficients State of residence Coefficients
FL -0.41 KS -0.16
SC -0.37 CA -0.15
NE -0.3 IL -0.15
MN -0.29 HI -0.15
MO -0.28 IA -0.15
UT -0.28 KY -0.15
AL -0.27 TN -0.12
NH -0.27 VA -0.11
IN -0.26 RI -0.11
OR -0.25 WY -0.09
AR -0.25 SD -0.08
OH -0.25 PA -0.08
MI -0.24 MS -0.07
NV -0.22 VT -0.07
GA -0.22 CT -0.07
MA -0.21 ND -0.01
OK -0.21 NY -0.01
AZ -0.2 ID 0
DE -0.2 TX 0
ME -0.19 NJ 0.01
MD -0.18 DC 0.02
NC -0.16 LA 0.06
CO -0.16 AK 0.06
WI -0.16 WV 0.06
WA -0.16 NM 0.14
MT -0.16    

Note: Except for the state of residence dummy, the regression is identical to Table 3. Other coefficients are little changed and are available upon request.

Table A5: List of geographic areas

AK FL LA WA SD
Other, AK Jacksonville, FL New Orleans, LA Other, WA Other, SD
AL Miami, FL Other, LA Seattle-Tacoma, WA TN
Birmingham, AL Orlando, FL MA/RI WI Memphis, TN
Other, AL Other, FL Boston, MA Milwaukee, WI Nashville, TN
AR Tampa, FL Other, MA/RI Other, WI TD
Other, AR GA Providence, RI WV Other, TD
AZ Atlanta, GA MD Other, WV TX
Other, AZ Other, GA Baltimore, MD WY Austin, TX
Phoenix, AZ HI Other, MD Other, WY Dallas, TX
Tucson, AZ Honolulu, HI ME NH Houston, TX
CA Other, HI Other, ME Other, NH Other, TX
Los Angeles, CA IA MI NM San Antonio, TX
Other, CA Other, IA Detroit, MI Other, NM UT
Riverside, CA ID Other, MI NV Other, UT
Sacramento, CA Other, ID MN Las Vegas, NV Salt Lake City, UT
San Diego, CA IN/IL/KS/MO Minneapolis-St. Paul, MN Other, NV VA
San Francisco, CA Chicago, IL Other, MN OK Other, VA
San Jose, CA Indianapolis, IN MS Oklahoma City, OK Richmond, VA
CO Kansas City, MO Other, MS Other, OK Virginia Beach, VA
Denver, CO Other, IN/IL/KS/MO MT OR VT
Other, CO St. Louis, MO Other, MT Other, OR Other, VT
CT KY/OH NC/SC Portland, OR  
Hartford, CT Cincinnati, OH Charlotte, NC PA/NJ/NY  
Other, CT Cleveland, OH Other, NC/SC Buffalo, NY  
DC Columbus, OH ND New York, NY  
Washington, DC Louisville, KY Other, ND Other, PA/NJ/NY  
DE Other, KY/OH NE Philadelphia, PA  
Other, DE   Other, NE Pittsburgh, PA  
      Rochester, NY  


Footnotes

* We thank Shigeru Fujita, Bart Hobijn, Rob Valletta, William Wascher and seminar participants at the Chicago Fed, the National Bank of Hungary, the New York Fed and the San Francisco Fed. We thank Peter Chen for excellent research assistance. The views expressed here do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors are our own. Return to Text
1. In recent work, Sahin, Song, Topa, and Violante (2010) address the issue with a different approach, by constructing mismatch indices based on a theoretical framework of mismatch. Return to Text
2. The Cobb-Douglas matching function is used in almost all macroeconomic models with search and search and matching frictions (e.g., Pissarides, 2001). Return to Text
3. A measurement issue is that vacancies are not only filled from the unemployed pool (U) but also from the employment pool (E) and individuals outside the labor force (NLF). As a robustness check, we proceeded as in Blanchard and Diamond (1989) and estimated a regression over 1994-2009 of the sum of E-U flows, NLF-E flows and E-E flows (Fallick and Fleischman, 2004) on vacancies and the number of unemployed and individuals outside the labor force willing to work. The behavior of  m_{0t} was broadly unchanged. Return to Text
4. Elsby, Hobijn and Sahin (2010) report a similar finding using the unemployment outflow rate, and Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger (2010) also report a dramatic decline in the vacancy yield using JOLTS data. Return to Text
5. The job finding rate  jf and the the job finding probability  JF can be related from  jf=-\ln \left( 1-JF\right) . Return to Text
6. Two other plausible determinants of the job finding probability are the search intensity of workers and the recruiting intensity of firms. These parameters can easily be incorporated in our framework, but we preferred to leave them out for two reasons. First, such concepts are difficult to implement empirically as measuring workers' search intensity or firms' recruiting intensity is notoriously difficult (See Davis, Faberman and Haltiwanger, 2010 for promising work in this direction). Second, as we report below, our framework without varying search/recruiting intensities can successfully capture job finding probability movements over 1976-2006. This suggests that aggregate labor market tightness (or sectoral tightness) can proxy for varying intensities and that our framework provides a good reduced-form approximation of a model of job finding probability with varying intensities. After 2006, varying intensities could have played a larger role, and we separately estimate the effect of extended unemployment benefits on workers' search intensity. Return to Text
7. The cross-order term between  X_{jt}-\bar{X} and  \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}-1 is omitted and only described in the Appendix. This is done for clarity of exposition as that term is empirically very small at the level of disaggregation permitted by our data on labor market segments. Return to Text
8. We omitted the second-order term for clarity of exposition, but incorporated the (small) second-order term in all our calculations. Return to Text
9. The term corresponding to  \theta _{it},  \displaystyle\sum\limits_{i,j}\frac{U_{j,t}}{ U_{t}}\left. \frac{\partial JF}{\partial \theta _{it}}\right\vert _{\theta _{t},\bar{X}}\left( \theta _{it}-\theta _{t}\right) , is nil because  \theta _{t}=\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i,j}\frac{U_{ij,t}}{U_{t}}\theta _{it}. Return to Text
10. The coefficient of proportionality does depend on  \theta _{t} but its effect is small. Return to Text
11. See also the recent work by Sahin, Song, Topa, and Violante (2010) who develop mismatch indices based on a theoretical framework of mismatch. Return to Text
12. See, for example, Polivka and Miller (1998). Return to Text
13. We also experimented with education level and race/ethnicity but found that these characteristics play little role in the cyclicality of matching efficiency, consistent with the findings of Baker (1992). We thus omitted these characteristics for clarity of exposition. Return to Text
14. The JOLTS is produced by the BLS and contains monthly data on job openings from 16,000 establishments since December 2000. Return to Text
15. Formally, we used JOLTS and Conference Board vacancy data by region or industry to regress  \ln \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}=\alpha \ln \frac{ u_{it}}{u_{t}}+\beta . The regression results are shown in Table A1 in the Appendix. Return to Text
16. At the level of disaggregation permitted by the CPS, initial regressions and dispersion indexes by industry or state suggest that state differences in unemployment have much stronger effects on job finding probabilities than differences across industries. Therefore, we allow for as much state-level unemployment variation as possible. Return to Text
17. Defining segments by occupation rather than industry does not qualitatively change our results. The industry groups are (1) manual workers-agriculture, mining, construction, manufacturing, transportation and public utilities, (2) professional workers-finance, professional and business services, health care and education, information and public sector, and (3) service workers-retail and wholesale trade, leisure and hospitality services, other services. Return to Text
18. The value of  \alpha only matters for our estimate of  \omega . Using the extreme values of 1.7 and 1.3 makes little difference to our conclusions, with  \omega ranging from 0.35 to 0.45. Return to Text
19. The CPS redesign, by restricting temporary layoffs to individuals expecting to be recalled within 6 months, made the distinction a lot sharper (as seen from the evolution of the coefficient on temporary layoffs pre and post-1994 in Table 2), which certainly improved our measure of composition. Return to Text
20. The results are reported in Table A2 in the Appendix. Our results do not necessarily contradict Kuang and Valletta's findings or Moffitt (1985), Katz and Meyer (1990) and Meyer (1990) conclusion that extending benefits does increase unemployment duration. The reason is that unemployment duration is determined by the unemployment-employment (UE) transition rate  \emph{and} by the unemployment-nonparticipation (UN) transition rate. In the Appendix, we also estimate a logistic regression for the UN transition probability after controlling for characteristics of the unemployed. We do find a significant effect of EEB on UN transitions as job losers' probability of remaining in the labor force increased significantly more than the UN probability of other unemployed after 2008. See also Fujita (2010) who uses a different identification scheme than Kuang and Valetta and finds that EEB significantly lowered male workers' job finding probability in the 2008-2009 recession. Return to Text
21. The results are shown in Table A3 and Table A4 in the Appendix. We also looked at education groups. While higher educational attainment is generally associated with higher job finding probabilities, the change in job finding probability after 2007 was fairly widespread. All categories except the least educated (less than high school degree) and the most educated (graduate degree) suffered significant declines in job finding probabilities. Return to Text
22. Farber (2010), Molloy, Smith and Wozniac (2010) and Kaplan and Schulhofer-Wohl (2010) also find little evidence that a "house-lock" is impeding migration or driving up unemployment. Return to Text
23. These groups are Trade (wholesale and retail), Information, Construction, Manufacturing, Professional/Business Services, Education and Health, Leisure and Hospitality, Financial Activities, Transportation. Return to Text
24. The online data collected by the Conference Board correspond to the number of new, first-time online jobs and jobs reposted from the previous month on more than 1200 major Internet job boards. These data provide a direct measure of online job posting. Return to Text
25. More specifically, we proceed as follows: when a state comprises  n MSAs, we decompose the number of ads for that state into  n+1 geographic areas. The additional area is the difference between total ads in the state and the total number of ads across the MSAs from that state. We obtain less than 50+52 areas because some MSAs span different states (such as New York City). When this is the case, we group these states together. The additional area is then the difference between total ads in those states and the total number of ads in the MSAs of those states. A list of the geographic areas is presented in Table A5 in the Appendix. Return to Text
26. These groups are Management & Business/Financial, Professional & Related, Services, Sales & Office, Construction & Maintenance, Production & Transportation. They correspond to the SOC high level aggregations, except Management & Business/Financial and Professional & Related which split the high-level aggregation group "Management, Business, Science and Arts" into two subgroups. Return to Text
27. We assume that, apart from measurement error, there are no differences in matching efficiency across occupation and geographic area so that  m_{i}=m_{0},  \forall i (an assumption we implicitly made in Section 3 with our functional form (9)). With different matching efficiency levels, (13) becomes  jf_{it}=m_{i}\alpha _{i}^{\omega (1-\sigma )} \tilde{\theta}_{it}^{\omega (1-\sigma )}\alpha _{0t}^{\left( 1-\omega \right) (1-\sigma )}\tilde{\theta}_{t}^{(1-\omega )(1-\sigma )}. With  \alpha _{i} and  m_{i} both affecting matching efficiency in observationally equivalent, it is not possible to disentangle the two phenomena from information on the job finding rate and measured labor market tightness alone. Return to Text
28. Using a different value for  \omega makes little difference to our results. Return to Text
29. 740,000 is an extreme example used for illustration as dispersion across that many segments would exaggerate the effect of mismatch. When the set of classifications is too fine, the boundaries between segments are less clearly defined, and workers are more likely to cross segments to find a job. Return to Text
30. As we refine the level of disaggregation and n=  \frac{N}{\bar{N}}\rightarrow 1,  var_{n}\left( \frac{\bar{\theta}_{j}}{\theta _{t}}\right) \rightarrow var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) . Return to Text
31. See Sahin, Song, Topa, and Violante (2010) for a detailed study of mismatch in the UK. Return to Text
32. We do not use data prior to May 2006 because of a break in methodology. Return to Text
33. Estimating the scaling law using only yearly data (and leaving out the highest disaggregation levels  N_{occ}=353) gives similar  a_{1} and  a_{2} but different intercepts  a_{0}, supporting our assumption that  f(.) is time invariant. Return to Text
34. In the Appendix, we show that one can apply the UK scaling law to US data if the average correlation in labor market conditions within an occupation group and/or a geographic area is similar in both countries. Return to Text
35. While these numbers are derived using  \bar{N} _{occ}=353 and  \bar{N}_{geo} =232, in practice, for  \bar{N} large enough, the choice of  \bar{N} makes little difference to our conclusion. Doubling the number of units (i.e., setting  \bar{N} _{occ}=706 and  \bar{N}_{geo}=464) only increases the contribution of misallocation from 26 to 27 percent, while halving  \bar{N} only decreases it to 24 percent. Return to Text
36. Note that our calculation implicitly assumed that the estimated value of  var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{ \theta _{t}}\right) in November 2006 corresponds to E  _{T}var\left( \frac{\theta _{it}}{\theta _{t}}\right) , the average dispersion level over 1976-2007. This seems plausible given that Figures 1 and 2 show that aggregate matching efficiency was at its average level in late 2006, suggesting that dispersion was at its average level. Interestingly, if the average level of dispersion is given by the November 2006 reading of 5, this implies that, on average, dispersion in labor market conditions depresses the US job finding rate by about 15 percent (using  \omega =0.4 and Figure 6). Return to Text
37. This effect comes from the concavity of the matching function, as above average workers would have a stronger positive impact on matching efficiency than below average workers if above average workers were located in looser labor markets. Interestingly, this also implies that matching efficiency is lower when workers with above average characteristics are concentrated in tighter labor markets. Return to Text
38. For the last expression, we assumed that E  _{T}\displaystyle\sum\limits_{k}JF_{t}^{k} is small, which is empirically the case since the second-order approximation of  JF_{t}^{k} is very small and since we demeaned the  X_{jt} variables before estimating (9) so that the first-order term of  JF_{t}^{k} is nil. Return to Text
39. The condition to use the UK law (21) with US data becomes more stringent as N increases. Since only the average correlation enters (21), one only needs that, within a segment of size  n=\frac{\bar{N}}{N }, the average correlation between units is identical in the US and the UK. But as  N increases to  \bar{N}, the number of units which one takes the average gets smaller, and the condition is more restrictive. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text