The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2012-37 Screen Reader version

Term Structure Modelling with Supply Factors and the Federal Reserve's Large Scale Asset Purchase Programs*

Canlin Li1 and Min Wei2
Preliminary; Comments Welcome


First version: January 20, 2012
This version: May 30, 2012


Keywords: Yield curve, preferred habitat, supply effects, factor models; state-space models; large-scale asset purchases (LSAP)

Abstract:

This paper proposes and estimates an arbitrage-free term structure model with both observable yield factors and Treasury and Agency MBS supply factors, and applies it to evaluate the term premium effects of Federal Reserve's Large Scale Assset Purchase programs. Our estimates show that the first and the second large-scale asset purchase programs and the Maturity Extension program have a combined effect of about 100 basis points on the 10-year Treasury yield.

JEL Classification: G1, E4, C5

1 Introduction

Do changes in the supply of Treasury securities and other fixed-income assets affect nominal Treasury yields? This question has received renewed attention as the FOMC adopted large-scale asset purchases (LSAPs) as an alternative monetary policy tool to stimulate the economy, after the federal funds rate reached the zero lower bound during the most recent financial crisis. The answer to this question, however, is still subject to considerable uncertainty. On the one hand, the now-standard no-arbitrage term structure literature leaves little scope for the relative supply of deeply liquid financial assets, such as nominal Treasuries, to influence their prices because they can easily replicated or substituted by other similar assets. On the other hand, there is empirical evidence suggesting supply effects might exist in the Treasury market. For example, event studies typically show that the Federal Reserve's LSAP announcements had nontrivial effects on Treasury yields. More generally, Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2008) and Laubach (2009) show that the total supply of Treasury debt have explanatory power for Treasury yield variations beyond that of standard yield curve factors, while Hamilton and Wu (Forthcoming) and Greenwood and Vayanos (2010b,a) provide similar evidence for the maturity structure of Treasury debt outstanding. One possible explanation for the existence of supply effect in Treasury market is offered by the preferred-habitat model of interest rates, which assumes imperfect substitutability between securities with similar maturities.

The preferred-habit literature, which features early contributions by Modigliani and Sutch (1966,1967), resorts to the assumption that there exist "preferred-habitat" investors, who demonstrate preferences for specific maturities, and that interest rate for a given maturity is only influenced by demand and supply shocks specific to that maturity. Real-world examples of such preferred-habitat investors include long-term investors, such as pension funds and insurance companies, that prefer to hold long-term bonds to match their long-duration liabilities, and short-term investors, such as money market mutual funds and foreign reserve managers, that prefer to hold Treasury bills and short-dated notes to maintain a high degree of liquidity in their portfolio. The preferred-habitat approach provides a rationale for supply effects in the government bond markets, as a shock to the stock of privately-held bonds of a particular maturity creates a shortage of those assets that cannot be wholly relieved, at existing asset prices, by substitution into other securities.

This approach of modeling interest rates has been largely abandoned in today's term structure literature, as it implies that yields at different maturities are disconnected from each other, which is at odds with the continuous yield curve one typically observes. In contrast, in the now-standard arbitrage-free term structure models of Vasicek (1977) and Cox, Jonathan E. Ingersoll, and Ross (1985), long-term interest rates differ from the expected average future short rate because investors in long-term bonds demand excess returns for bearing interest rate risks. The existence of arbitrageurs in the economy ensures that the same stochastic discount factor prices interest risks consistently across the yield curve. It also implies that any changes in the supply of Treasury securities, if unrelated to the economic fundamentals, should not have significant effect on yields.

More recently, the preferred-habit literature was revitalized in the seminar work of Vayanos and Vila (2009), who recast Treasury supply and demand shocks in an arbitrage-free framework. In their model, the existence of preferred-habitat investors provides a channel for demand and supply factors to influence Treasury yields, while the existence of risk-averse arbitrageurs, who have no maturity preference but actively trade to take advantage of arbitrage opportunities, ensures that supply shocks are transmitted smoothly across the yield curve. Vayanos and Vila (2009) show that, under certain parameterizations, the yield impact of variations in relative supplies depends on the dollar duration of the supply shocks absorbed by the arbitrageurs, which implies a direct relationship between the term premium and the total duration risks faced by private investors.

Despite the theoretical advances, empirical studies of preferred-habitat term structure models are nearly non-existent, hampered by the lack of detailed data on Treasury holdings across investors and by the complexity of the Vayanos and Vila (2009) model. In this paper, we try to fill this gap by estimating and testing a no-arbitrage term structure model with supply factors. We adopt several simplifying assumptions: first, we assume observable supply factors and measure them using data on private holdings of Treasury debt and agency mortgage backed securities (MBS). Second, we assume that supply factors influence Treasury yields predominantly through the term premium channel. Supply affects future short rates only indirectly through current and future term premiums. Finally, we adopt a two-step estimation approach where factor dynamics are estimated in the first step while bond risk premium parameters are estimated in the second step.

We also use this model to evaluate the three LSAP programs announced by the Federal Reserve. Most empirical analysis of the LSAPs are based on either event studies (e.g. Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011), Swanson (2011); Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011)) or time series regressions of Treasury yields and/or Treasury term premiums on supply variables (e.g. Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011); Greenwood and Vayanos (2010a); Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011); Hamilton and Wu (Forthcoming)). To our knowledge, this paper is the first to use an arbitrage-free term structure model to evaluate the effects of LSAPs. Results based on event studies are known to be sensitive to the selection of event windows. Time series regressions used in these studies, on the other hand, are likely susceptible to small-sample bias, given the highly persistence of supply variables, and endogeneity problems, as changes in Treasury supply are likely correlated with other factors driving the yield curve. Neither approach can be used to answer the question of how supply changes affect yields that are not directly used in the study. By contrast, the no-arbitrage term structure approach in this paper offers a way to consistently summarize information from the entire yield curve and allows inference across maturities.

Our estimates show that the first and the second large-scale asset purchase programs and the Maturity Extension program have a combined effect of about 100 basis points on the ten-year Treasury yield.

While the current paper emphasizes the interest risk premium channel through which LSAP works to reduce longer term Treasury yields, other channels have been suggested in the literature. For example, Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011) offer evidence that significant clientele demand exists for long-term "safe" (i.e., nearly default-free) assets, such as Treasury and agency MBS. These investors are willing to pay a premium--the "safety premium"--for holding those safe assets. A reduction in the supply of "safe" assets would raise the safety premium and lower the yields on those assets. Another example is D'Amico and King (2010), who emphasize the scarcity channel, i.e. a localized effect of supply shocks on yields of nearby maturities. They use CUSIP-level data to show the Federal Reserve's purchases have significant yield effects on both purchased securities and those at nearby maturities.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and documents the relationship between Treasury term premiums and Treasury and agency MBS supply. Section 3 reviews existing literature on the supply effects in the Treasury market, while Section 4 summarizes recent studies evaluating the effects of LSAPs on long-term Treasury yields. Section 5 describes the term structure model with supply factors. Section 6 discusses the estimation methodology and presents the empirical results. Section 7 concludes.


2 Data and Motivation

This section presents some preliminary evidence suggesting there exists a link between the supply of government securities and Treasury term premiums.3 In particular, we run monthly regressions of the form

\displaystyle TP_{t}^{10}=\alpha+\beta^{\prime}SV_{t}+\gamma^{\prime}CV_{t}+\varepsilon_{t} (1)

over the sample period of March 1994 to July 2007, where  TP_{t}^{10} represents estimates of ten-year Treasury term premium,  SV_{t} denotes a vector of supply variables, and  CV_{t} denotes a vector of control variables.

We obtain nominal Treasury yields with maturities of 3, 6, 12, 24, 60, 84, and 120 months from the Svensson (1995) zero-coupon yield curve maintained by staff at the Federal Reserve Board .4 In this explorative exercise, we use ten-year term premium estimates from a three-latent-factor Gaussian term structure model developed by Kim and Orphanides (2012), which was estimated using Treasury yields described above and Blue Chip survey forecasts of 3-month Treasury bill yields over the next two years and the next five to ten years.5 As discussed in Kim and Orphanides (2012) and Kim and Wright (2005), incorporating survey forecasts of future short rates helps alleviate the small sample problem commonly encountered when fitting term structure models to highly persistent yields.

For reasons that will be discussed later, we include in  SV_{t} both Treasury and MBS supply variables as follows.

For each Treasury cusip, the total par amount outstanding as well as the maturity and coupon rate information are obtained from the Treasury's Monthly Statement of the Public Debt (MSPD), while the amount held in the Federal Reserve's System of Open Market Account (SOMA) is obtained from the weekly releases by the FRBNY.7The difference between total debt outstanding and SOMA holdings gives us the par amount held by private investors for each security. For each Treasury cusip, we also calculate the average duration and the ten-year equivalents using the same quotes used in constructing the Svensson yield curve as described above. We then sum over all cusips to calculate the total par amount and the total ten-year equivalents of private Treasury holdings and average across cusips to calculate the par amount-weighted average maturity and duration. We exclude Treasury bills and any previous-issued notes and bonds with remaining maturities below one year, as commonly done in the literature. For agency MBS, the par amount and average duration of privately-held agency MBS are taken from Barclays as reported for their MBS index, which includes mortgage-backed passthrough securities of Ginnie Mae (GNMA), Fannie Mae (FNMA), and Freddie Mac (FHLMC).

We control for other economic and market factors,  CV_{t}, that can be expected to affect term premiums, including:

Table 1 reports results from three variations of Regression (1), where the supply variables are the Treasury ten-year equivalents-to-GDP ratio (Reg. A), the Treasury par-to-GDP ratio and the average maturity (Reg. B), and the Treasury par-to-GDP ratio, the average Treasury maturity, the MBS par-to-GDP ratio, and the average MBS duration (Reg. C), respectively. Overall, these results suggest that term premiums are significantly and positively related to the supply variables after controlling for other economic factors. In the next section, we try to incorporate these supply variables into a standard no-arbitrage term structure model.


Table 1: Term premium regressions
  2-year Reg A 2-year Reg B 2-year Reg C 5-year Reg A 5-year Reg B 5-year Reg C 10-year Reg A 10-year Reg B 10-year Reg C
Constant -3.357*** -6.119*** -4.172** -2.264 -5.235*** -5.354** 1.198 -0.860 -4.844**
Constant (Standard Error) (1.197) (1.195) (1.820) (1.521) (1.547) (2.250) (1.536) (1.599) (2.260)
Ten-year Treasury implied volatility 0.056*** 0.062*** 0.005 0.101*** 0.103*** 0.015 0.144*** 0.138*** 0.029
Ten-year Treasury implied volatility (Standard Error) (0.021) (0.019) (0.016) (0.027) (0.025) (0.020) (0.027) (0.026) (0.020)
S&P 100 implied volatility -0.007** -0.016*** 0.001 -0.009** -0.019*** 0.003 -0.009** -0.016*** 0.004
S&P 100 implied volatility (Standard Error) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003)
Foreign Treasury holdings ratio -0.062*** 0.038** 0.010 -0.073*** 0.044 * 0.007 -0.058 *** 0.039 0.000
Foreign Treasury holdings ratio (Standard Error) (0.015) (0.018) (0.013) (0.019) (0.024) (0.016) (0.020) (0.025) (0.016)
Capacity Utilization 0.063*** 0.015 -0.025* 0.047** -0.014 -0.056*** -0.007 -0.065*** -0.093***
Capacity Utilization (Standard Error) (0.016) (0.016) (0.013) (0.021) (0.021) (0.016) (0.021) (0.022) (0.017)
Blue Chip CPI forecast 0.147 0.352*** 0.127* 0.258** 0.470*** 0.182** 0.348*** 0.474*** 0.194**
Blue Chip CPI forecast (Standard Error) (0.100) (0.091) (0.065) (0.127) (0.118) (0.080) (0.129) (0.122) (0.081)
Treasury TYE-to-GDP ratio (%) -0.047**     -0.039     -0.001    
Treasury TYE-to-GDP ratio (%) (Standard Error) (0.023)     (0.029)     (0.030)    
Treasury par-to-GDP ratio (%)   0.029 ** 0.063 ***   0.045*** 0.105***   0.058*** 0.140 ***
Treasury par-to-GDP ratio (%) (Standard Error)   (0.012) (0.012)   (0.016) (0.015)   (0.016) (0.015)
Treasury average maturity   0.533*** 0.418***   0.639*** 0.589***   0.563*** 0.660***
Treasury average maturity (Standard Error)   (0.092) (0.089)   (0.119) (0.110)   (0.123) (0.110)
MBS par-to-GDP ratio (%)     0.060**     0.130***     0.204***
MBS par-to-GDP ratio (%) (Standard Error)     (0.030)     (0.037)     (0.037)
MBS average duration     0.252***     0.329***     0.328***
MBS average duration (Standard Error)     (0.020)     (0.024)     (0.024)
R-squared 0.67 0.74 0.88 0.68 0.73 0.89 0.69 0.73 0.89
R-squared (cont'd) 0.66 0.72 0.87 0.66 0.72 0.88 0.68 0.71 0.88
Note: This table reports 2-, 5- and 10-year Treasury term premiums, estimated from the Kim and Orphanides (2012) model, on Treasury and MBS supply variables as well as other control variables. "TYE" refers to ten-year equivalents.

3 No-Arbitrage Term Structure Model with Supply Factors

3.1 A Standard Gaussian Term Structure Model

We start from a standard Gaussian term structure model, where we assume yields are driven by a number of state variables,  X_{t}\,, which follows a first-order vector autoregressive process:

\displaystyle X_{t}=\mu+\Phi X_{t-1}+\Omega v_{t},  \displaystyle v_{t}\sim i.i.d.N(0,I). % (2)

We further assume that there exists a stochastic discount factor of the form:
\displaystyle M_{t+1}=\exp\left( -r_{t}-\frac{1}{2}\Lambda_{t}^{\prime}\Lambda_{t}% -\Lambda_{t}^{\prime}v_{t}\right) ,
where both the short rate,  r_{t}, and the market price of risk,  \Lambda _{t}, are assumed to be linear functions of  X_{t}:
\displaystyle r_{t} \displaystyle =\delta_{0}+\delta_{1}^{\prime}X_{t}. (3)
\displaystyle \Lambda_{t} \displaystyle =\lambda_{0}+\lambda_{1}X_{t}.\displaystyle % (4)

Following Duffie and Kan (1996) and Dai and Singleton (2000), the price of a  n-period zero-coupon bond,  P_{t,n}, can be derived by iterating on the no-arbitrage bond pricing equation

\displaystyle P_{t,n}=E_{t}\left[ M_{t+1}P_{t,n-1}\right]
with the terminal condition  P_{t,0}=1, which gives the bond pricing formula:
\displaystyle P_{t,n}=\exp(A_{n}+B_{n}^{\prime}X_{t}),\displaystyle % (5)

where
with initial conditions  A_{1}=-\delta_{0} and  B_{1}=-\delta_{1}. The bond pricing formula can be rewritten in yield terms by taking logarithms of both sides of Equation (5)
\displaystyle y_{t,n}=-\frac{1}{n}\log P_{t,t+n}=-\frac{1}{n}(A_{n}+B_{n}^{\prime}X_{t})

The model can therefore be conveniently represented in a state-space form as follows,

\displaystyle y_{t,n} \displaystyle =-\frac{1}{n}(A_{n}+B_{n}^{\prime}X_{t})+\varepsilon _{t,t+n}\hrulefill  \displaystyle \varepsilon_{t,t+n}\sim i.i.d.N(0,\sigma_{n}^{2}), (8)
\displaystyle X_{t} \displaystyle =\mu+\Phi X_{t-1}+\Omega v_{t}     \displaystyle % v_{t}\sim i.i.d.N(0,I),% (9)

with Equation (8) being the measurement equation and Equation (9) being the state equation.

We consider the risk-neutral measure, under which the state variables \ follow the process

\displaystyle X_{t}=\tilde{\mu}+\tilde{\Phi}X_{t-1}+\tilde{v}_{t},\displaystyle %
with the VAR parameters under the physical and the risk-neutral meaures linked to each other through the relationship
The pricing iterations (6) and (7) can therefore be restated in terms of the risk-neutral VAR parameters as
while the market price of risk,  \Lambda _{t}, can also be written as functions of the two sets of VAR parameters:
\displaystyle \Lambda_{t}=\lambda_{0}+\lambda_{1}X_{t}=\Omega^{-1}[(\mu-\tilde{\mu}% )+(\Phi-\tilde{\Phi})X_{t})].\displaystyle % (14)

When implementing the model, we directly estimate the physical and risk-neutral VAR parameters, which jointly decides the market prices of risk.

It is well known at least since Litterman and Scheinkman (1991) that an overwhelming portion of Treasury yield variations can be summarized by three principal components, frequently termed the level, the slope and the curvature. In our sample, more than 99% of the yield variations can be explained by the first two factors, which is the number of yield factors we use in our empirical analysis. To avoid the difficulty frequently encountered when estimating latent-factor term structure models, in all our models we assume that these two yield factors are observable and measure them using the ten-year yield and the spread between the ten-year and the three-month Treasury yields, respectively.

3.2 Term Structure Model with a Treasury Supply Factor

We assume that the state variables,  X_{t}, consist of both yield and supply factors, denoted  f_{t} and  s_{t}, respectively. The yield factors include the level and slope factors described above. In the first model we consider, we assume there is only one supply factor, the Treasury ten-year equivalents-to-GDP ratio.

As in Vayanos and Vila (2009), we motivate our model by assuming the existence of two types of private participants in the Treasury market: preferred-habitat investors, who hold only a particular maturity segment of the Treasury yield curve, and risk averse arbitrageurs, who trade to take advantage of arbitrage opportunities. There are also government agencies, like the Treasury and the Federal Reserve, which are modeled as risk-neutral participants in the Treasury market. Vayanos and Vila (2009) show that in how government bond holdings of the arbitragers affect the equilibrium bond risk premiums. For simplicity, we do not impose specific functional forms on the demand functions of preferred-habitat investors or the utility function of the arbitrageurs, which Vayanos and Vila (2009) use to derive analytical solutions linking bond risk premiums to the arbitragers' bond holdings. Instead, we simply take their conclusion and assume supply factors affect bond risk premiums, which is in the same spirit as how macro yield factors are motivated in the macro-finance term structure models (e.g. Ang and Piazzesi (2003)).

We assume that yield and supply factors only load on their own lags:

\displaystyle \Phi=\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccc}% \Phi_{11} & \Phi_{12} & 0\\ \Phi_{21} & \Phi_{22} & 0\\ 0 & 0 & \Phi_{33}% \end{array} \right] . (15)

The assumption that yield factors do not load on past supply factors may appear inconsistent with regression results reported earlier or our stated objective of assessing how supply changes affect term premium and yields. This assumption is nonetheless imposed to ensure that any evidence we shall find in support of the supply effects is driven by the data rather than by assumptions. To ensure that this condition holds empirically, we measure yield factors as residuals from a regression of the level and the slope of the yield curve on supply factors plus a constant, and order them first in the VAR. The restriction that supply factors do not load on past yield factors reflects the Treasury's stated policy that it "does not `time the market'--or seek to take advantage of low interest rates--when it issues securities. Instead, Treasury strives to lower its borrowing costs over time by relying on a regular preannounced schedule of auctions."9

We identify supply shocks by imposing a lower-diagonal structure on the volatility matrix:

\begin{displaymath} \Omega=\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccc}% \Omega_{11} & 0 & 0\ \Omega_{21} & \Omega_{22} & 0\ \Omega_{31} & \Omega_{32} & \Omega_{33}% \end{array}\right] , \end{displaymath}
The non-zero terms  \Omega_{31} and  \Omega_{32} capture the correlation between systematic responses of monetary and fiscal policies to economic variations over the business cycle. For example, in a recession, the FOMC lowers the short rate to stimulate the economy and the yield curve steepens; at the same time, the Treasury will issue more debt to finance the rising federal budget deficit resulting from the automatic stabilizers. On the other hand, a pure supply shock,  v_{3t}, that is orthogonal to yield factor shocks has no effect on current or future (orthogonalized) yield factors.

We impose the restriction that the short-term rate loads only on the two yield factors, so that shocks to supply factors do not affect interest rate expectations but can affect bond yields through the term premium channel only.

\displaystyle \delta_{1}=\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccc}% \delta_{11} & \delta_{12} & 0 \end{array} \right] , (16)

We also impose the restriction that the supply factors do not carry their own risk premiums but can affect term premiums by changing the risk premiums on the yield factors.
\displaystyle \lambda_{0} \displaystyle =\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccc}% \lambda_{0,1} & \lambda_{0,2} & 0 \end{array} \right] ^{\prime}, (17)
\displaystyle \lambda_{1} \displaystyle =\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccc}% \lambda_{1,11} & \lambda_{1,12} & \lambda_{1,13}\\ \lambda_{1,21} & \lambda_{1,22} & \lambda_{1,23}\\ 0 & 0 & 0 \end{array} \right] . (18)

The first assumption captures the fact that the supply of Treasury securities is not an important consideration when the Fed determines the short-term interest rate, while the second assumption reflects our prior that Treasury supply is unlikely to be a source of undiversifiable risk that should be priced on its own. Imposing these restrictions help reduce the number of parameters that needs to estimated and avoid the overfitting problem. Under these two assumptions, the supply factors follow the same dynamics under the physical and the risk-neutral measures:
\displaystyle \tilde{\mu}_{3} \displaystyle =\mu_{3}, (19)
\displaystyle \tilde{\Phi}_{3\ast} \displaystyle =\Phi_{3\ast}, (20)

where  \tilde{\Phi}_{3\ast} and  \Phi_{3\ast} denote the third rows of the matrices  \Phi and  \tilde{\Phi}, respectively.

3.3 Extending the Model to Include MBS Supply Factors

Treasury yields might also be affected by the supply of agency MBS, which are viewed by many market participants as "safe" assets and close substitutes for Treasury debt due to their implicit or explicit government guarantee. Agency MBS and Treasury securities also share two features that set them apart from other privately-issued debt. First, the net issuance of both Treasury securities and of agency MBS does not react strongly to interest rates in the short run.10Their issuance is largely determined by the federal budget deficit and housing demand, respectively, which co-vary with interest rates mainly at the business-cycle frequency. In contrast, corporate bond issuance responds more opportunistically to the level of interest rates and this response can be significant even at the weekly frequency. The fact that the net supply of Treasury securities and agency MBS is relatively inelastic in the short run is one reason why investors need to take them into consideration when pricing those assets. Second, Treasury securities, agency MBS, and corporate debt can be viewed as ultimately transferring interest risks from tax payers, mortgage borrowers, and bond-issuing corporations, respectively, to bond investors. Both tax payers and mortgage borrowers are arguably sufficiently removed from investment decisions driving high-frequency asset price variations, so that their interest rate exposure may not be fully reflected in Treasury or agency MBS prices. As a result, investor holdings of these assets may still affect their prices, even though the net supply of such assets is zero when all players in the economy are taken into account. The same argument cannot be made for bond-issuing companies, especially financial corporations.

We therefore extend the model to include two additional supply factors, the par amount (normalized by nominal GDP) and the average duration of private MBS holdings, which are appended to the list of state variables. Specifying the model dynamics is however complicated by the fact that, unlike the duration of Treasury securities or the par supply of Treasury or agency MBS, the duration of agency MBS responds strongly to the level of interest rates; a lower interest rate will prompt more mortgage borrowers to prepay and the duration of agency MBS to shorten, and vice versa. As a result, we can no longer assume that all supply variables evolve independently of the yield factors; instead we need to allow MBS duration and the level of yields to be jointly determined within the model. MBS prepayment behavior is notoriously hard to model and depends on house prices, demographics, and many other non-interest rate factors. A fully-specified MBS prepayment model is beyond the scope of this paper; such a model is also not necessary for our purposes as we only need to capture the partial effect of MBS prepayments on MBS duration arising from interest rate changes. In the empirical analysis, we therefore model the average duration of privately-held agency MBS as a linear function of its own lag and the lagged yield curve level factor, while the Treasury supply factor and the par MBS-to-GDP ratio both follow AR(1) processes.

\displaystyle \Phi=\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccccc}% \Phi_{11} & \Phi_{12} & 0 & 0 & 0\\ \Phi_{21} & \Phi_{22} & 0 & 0 & 0\\ 0 & 0 & \Phi_{33} & 0 & 0\\ 0 & 0 & 0 & \Phi_{44} & 0\\ \Phi_{51} & 0 & 0 & 0 & \Phi_{55}% \end{array} \right] . (21)

We maintain earlier restrictions that the short-term rate loads only on the two yield factors,

\displaystyle \delta_{1}=\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccccc}% \delta_{11} & \delta_{12} & 0 & 0 & 0 \end{array} \right] (22)

and that all supply factors carry zero risk premiums11:
\displaystyle \lambda_{0} \displaystyle =\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccccc}% \lambda_{0,1} & \lambda_{0,2} & 0 & 0 & 0 \end{array} \right] ^{\prime}, (23)
\displaystyle \lambda_{1} \displaystyle =\left[ \begin{array}[c]{ccccc}% \lambda_{1,11} & \lambda_{1,12} & \lambda_{1,13} & \lambda_{1,14} & \lambda_{1,15}\\ \lambda_{1,21} & \lambda_{1,22} & \lambda_{1,23} & \lambda_{1,24} & \lambda_{1,25}\\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0\\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 \end{array} \right] . (24)

Under these two assumptions on the short rate and the risk premiums, the supply factors follow the same dynamics under the physical and the risk-neutral measures:

\displaystyle \tilde{\mu}_{i} \displaystyle =\mu_{i}, (25)
\displaystyle \tilde{\Phi}_{i\ast} \displaystyle =\Phi_{i\ast}, (26)

for  i=3,4,5, where  \tilde{\Phi}_{i\ast} and  \Phi_{i\ast} denote the  i^{th} rows of the matrices  \Phi and  \tilde{\Phi}, respectively.

4 Model Estimation and Empirical Results

We estimate the model using monthly data on Treasury yields and private holdings of Treasury and Agency MBS from March 1994 to July 2007. We assume the short rate is represented by the one-month yield, the level factor is represented by the five-year yield, and the slope factor is represented by the spread between the five-year yield and the one-month yield. Because our primary purpose is to identify the possible effect of supply factors on Treasury yield term premium, we take a two-step approach to estimate the model parameters as in Ang and Piazzesi (2003). In the first step, we estimate the factor dynamics equation (9) and the short rate equation (3) by ordinary least squares. In the second step, we estimate the remaining risk premium parameters by minimizing the average difference between observed yields and the term premium estimates described in Section 2, on the one hand, and model-implied yields and term premiums, on the other, over maturities of six months and one, two, seven, and ten years, while at the same time holding fixed all pre-estimated parameters. This two-step approach avoids the difficulties of estimating a model with many factors using the one-step maximum likelihood when yields and factors are highly persistent.

4.1 Estimation Results

Table 2 presents the model parameter estimates and Figures (1) and 2 show the fit of the model. The risk premiums on yield level risk carry the same sign of loadings on the three supply factors as on the level factor itself, which suggests that the three supply factors carry positive interest rate level risk premium as one would expect. Similarly the risk premiums on the yield slope risk carry the same sign of loadings on two supply factors (Treasury supply factor and MBS duration factor) as on the slope factor itself, which implies these two supply factors carry positive interest rates slope risk premium. The fit of the model is also reasonably good as evidenced in the two figures.


Table 2a : Model Parameter Estimates ( \mathbf{\Phi})
   \mathbf{\Phi}  \mathbf{\Phi}  \mathbf{\Phi}  \mathbf{\Phi}  \mathbf{\Phi}  \mathbf{\mu}
 L_{t} 0.970 -0.010       0.148
 S_{t} -0.052 0.938       0.298
 Tsy_{t}     0.990     0.082
 MBSpar_{t}       0.997   34.540
 MBSdur_{t} 0.238       0.860 2.074
Table 2b : Model Parameter Estimates ( \mathbf{\tilde{\Phi}})
   \mathbf{\tilde{\Phi}}  \mathbf{\tilde{\Phi}}  \mathbf{\tilde{\Phi}}  \mathbf{\tilde{\Phi}}  \mathbf{\tilde{\Phi}}  \mathbf{\tilde{\mu}}
 L_{t} 0.992 0.019 0.002 0.002 0.005 0.969
 S_{t} -0.098 0.961 0.003 -0.000 0.040 1.160
Table 2c : Model Parameter Estimates ( \mathbf{\Omega})
   \mathbf{\Omega}  \mathbf{\Omega}  \mathbf{\Omega}  \mathbf{\Omega}  \mathbf{\Omega}
 L_{t} 0.284        
 S_{t}   0.296      
 Tsy_{t}     0.274    
 MBSpar_{t}       0.142  
 MBSdur_{t} 0.312       0.258
Table 2d : Model Parameter Estimates ( \mathbf{\lambda_{1}})
   \mathbf{\lambda_{1}}  \mathbf{\lambda_{1}}  \mathbf{\lambda_{1}}  \mathbf{\lambda_{1}}  \mathbf{\lambda_{1}}  \mathbf{\lambda_{0}}
 L_{t} -0.077 -0.102 -0.008 -0.006 -0.016 -2.887
 S_{t} 0.152 -0.080 -0.010 0.002 -0.136 -2.908
Note: This table reports parameter estimates.

Figure 1: Yield fit
Figure 1: Yield fit. The four panels in this figure plot the actual yields (blue solid lines) and the model-predicted yields (red dashed lines) for maturities of 4, 8, 28 and 40 quarters, respectively.
Figure 2: Term premium fit
Figure 2: Term premium fit. The four panels in this figure plot term premium estimates from the Kim-Wright model (blue solid lines) and our model (red dashed lines) for maturities of 4, 8, 28 and 40 quarters, respectively.


Table 3: Estimated Factor Loadings of Term Premiums
Maturity (Years)  L_{t}  S_{t}  Tsy_{t} (\%)  MBSpar_{t} (\%)  MBSdur_{t} (Years)
0.5 1.18 -0.86 -0.08 0.59 -6.65
1 1.29 -0.70 0.13 1.36 -9.50
2 1.34 -0.44 1.13 2.89 -8.14
5 1.17 -0.02 5.29 6.49 1.70
7 1.04 0.09 7.70 8.11 5.01
10 0.86 0.15 10.16 9.73 6.79
Note: This table reports model-implied loadings of term premiums on the factors.

As summarized in Table 3, this model suggests that a one-percentage-point decline in the Treasury ten-year equivalent to-GDP ratio or the MBS par-to-GDP ratio would reduce the ten-year Treasury yield by about 10 basis points, while a one-year shortening of the average effective duration of private MBS holdings would lower the ten-year Treasury yield by about 7 basis points.

4.2 Impulse Response and Variance Decomposition

Next we examine the impulse responses of term premiums to supply shocks. We define the bond risk premium or term premium as the difference between the actual yield  y_{t,n} and the average future short rate,  y_{t,n}^{eh}:

\displaystyle RP_{t,n} \displaystyle =y_{t,n}-y_{t,n}^{eh}    
  \displaystyle =-\frac{1}{n}\left[ \left( A_{n}-A_{n}^{eh}\right) +\left( B_{n}% -B_{n}^{eh}\right) ^{\prime}X_{t}\right]% (27)

where the price loadings also follow a recursive relation:
with the initial conditions  A_{1}^{eh}=A_{1}=-\delta_{0} and  B_{1}% ^{eh}=B_{1}=-\delta_{1}. Note that in our setup, the average future short rate only loads on yield factors. We can therefore focus exclusively on the term premium components of yields in our analysis of the effects of supply variables on the term structure.

Recall there are only two risk factors in this model, i.e., only the first two elements in the price of risk vector,  \Lambda_{t}=\lambda_{0}+\lambda _{1}X_{t}, are non-zeros. The top panel of Figure 3 plots the impulse responses of these two elements, which represent the market price of yield curve level and slope risks, respectively, to one unit of shock to each supply factor. The market price of yield slope risk seems to react more strongly to MBS duration shocks than the price of level risk, while the responses to Treasury and MBS par supply factors are comparable across the two prices of risk.

Turning to term premiums, the bottom panel of Figure 3 plots impulse responses of 5-year and 10-year term premiums to one unit of shock to each supply factor as implied by Equations (2) and (27). MBS duration shocks seem to have smaller and more transitory effects on yields than the other two shocks, while the effects of Treasury and MBS par supply factors are both long-lasting and rising with bond maturities.

Figure 3: Impulse Response
This figure plots the impulse responses of the price of yield level risk (upper left panel), the price of yield slope risk (upper right panel), the 5-year term premium (lower left panel), and the 10-year term premium (lower right panel), respectively, to one unit of shock to the three supply factors, including the ten-year equivalents of public Treasury holdings (blue solid lines), the par amount of public MBS outstanding (green dot-dashed lines), and the average duration of public MBS outstanding (red dashed lines).

We can also use Equations (2) and (27) to decompose the conditional variance  Var_{t}(RP_{t+h,n}) at horizon  h and maturity  n as explained by each factor. The results for maturities of 1, 5, 10 years and horizons of 12 and 60 months are reported in Figure 4 and Table 4. As expected, the Treasury and MBS par supply factors explain very little of term premium variations at short maturities and short horizons, because short-term yields are primarily driven by interest rate expectations, which by construction are not affected by supply factors; in addition, supply factors are highly persistent and show little variations over short horizons. As the maturity rises, however, changes in term premiums explain a larger portion of yield variations. As the forecasts horizon increases, supply factors also exhibit more notable variations. Taken together, these two observations suggest that the effect of supply factors on term premiums should become more important at longer maturities and horizons, which is what we observe in the data. More specifically, about  9\% and  20\% of the conditional variance of 5- and 10-year term premiums, respectively, are attributable to shocks to the supply factors. Moreover, the Treasury supply factor accounts for most of the contributions of supply factors to term premium variations.

Figure 4: Variance decomposition of term premiums
The two panels of this figure plot the contributions of supply variables to the conditional variances of term premiums with maturities up to ten years at horizons of one and five years, respectively.  The supply variables include the ten-year equivalents of public Treasury holdings (blue solid lines), the par amount of public MBS outstanding (green dot-dashed lines), and the average duration of public MBS outstanding (red dashed lines), with the total contributions by all three supply variables marked in black dashed lines.


Table 4: Variance decompositions of term premiums
Maturity (years) Horizon (months) Yield factors Level Supply factors Slope Supply factors Treasury Supply factors MBS Par Supply factors MBS Dur Supply factors All
1 1 52 19 0 0 29 29
1 12 38 61 1 0 0 2
1 60 35 59 4 1 1 6
5 1 44 26 0 1 29 30
5 12 34 63 2 1 0 3
5 60 33 58 6 2 1 9
10 1 46 27 0 2 25 27
10 12 29 62 5 3 0 9
10 60 28 52 15 5 1 20
Note: This table reports variance decompositions of yield risk premiums.

5 Evaluating the Federal Reserve's Asset Purchase Programs

This section uses our term structure model with supply factors to evaluate the Federal Reserve's previous asset purchase programs--LSAP1, LSAP2, and MEP, which provide natural experiments for assessing the effects of exogenous shocks to the supply of Treasury securities and their close substitutes on Treasury yields. For reference, the details of these programs are described briefly below.12

5.1 Previous empirical studies

A growing empirical literature tries to assess the effects of these asset purchase programs, which are summarized in Table 5 and described in more details below.


Table 5: Previous empirical studies of LSAPs
  Event studies Time series regressions Panel regressions Estimated decline in ten-year Treasury yield (basis points)
LSAP1 Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011)  \checkmark  \checkmark   91 (Event studies); 36 to 82 (Regressions)
LSAP1 Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011)  \checkmark     100
LSAP1 D'Amico and King (2010)      \checkmark 20-30 (Treasury purchases only)
LSAP1 D'Amico, English, López-Salido, and Nelson (2011)    \checkmark   35 (Treasury purchases only)
LSAP2 Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011)  \checkmark     25
LSAP2 D'Amico, English, López-Salido, and Nelson (2011)    \checkmark   55
LSAP2 Meaning and Zhu (2011)      \checkmark 21
LSAP2 Swanson (2011)  \checkmark     15
MEP Hamilton and Wu (Forthcoming)    \checkmark   22
MEP Meaning and Zhu (2011)      \checkmark 17
Note: This table summarizes previous studies of the Federal Reserve's three asset purchase programs.

LSAP1

  1. Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011) using one-day window around 8 baseline events from November 25, 2008 to November 4, 2009, find that the 2-year Treasury yield declined 34bps , the ten-year Treasury yield declined 91bps, the ten-year agency debt yield declined 156bps, the current-coupon 30-year MBS yield declined 113bps, the ten-year SWAP rate 101bps, and the Baa corporate bond index yield declined 67 bps. Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011) also use several regression models on a sample from January 1985 to June 2008, to estimate the effect of changes in the stock of privately-held longer-term debt (normalized by nominal GDP) on the term premium, after controlling for other factors related to business cycles, and uncertainties about economic fundamentals. From those regression models they estimate the term premium effects of the first LSAP are 36 to 82bps.
  2. D'Amico and King (2010), which focuses only on Treasury LSAPs, using a panel of CUSIP-level data (where they regress the cumulative change in each security price on the total amount purchased of that security and its close substitutes) find that at the end of the first LSAP, Treasury yields with remaining maturity between 5 to 15 years were 20 to 30 basis points lower than what they would otherwise have been. The largest effects are at horizons of about 6 to 8 years and 11 to 14 years, consistent with the relatively high proportion of securities purchased in these sectors.
  3. D'Amico, English, López-Salido, and Nelson (2011) provide empirical estimates of the effect on longer-term U.S. Treasury yields of LSAP-style operations focusing on two channels: (i) scarcity (available local supply) and (ii) duration. According to these estimates the total impact from the first Treasury LSAP program is about 35 basis points: the scarcity effect accounts for 23 basis points and the duration effect for 12 basis points. The estimates indicate that: both proxies for scarcity and duration are positively and significantly related to longer-term Treasury yields and term premiums; a sizable portion of the impact on longer-term Treasury yields has been transmitted via the nominal term-premium component; within the overall term premium, it is the real term premium component that exhibits the greatest response to these two variables; and the inflation risk premium's response, in contrast, is quite small and is not uniformly statistically significant across different specifications.
  4. Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011) using one-day window around 6 baseline events from November 25, 2008 to March 18, 2009, find that the ten-year Treasury yield declined 100bps, the ten-year agency debt yield declined 164bps, the current-coupon 30-year MBS yield declined 116bps, and the Baa corporate bond index yield declined 68bps.

    Overall, the above mentioned studies imply that the first round of Treasury LSAPs had an impact that ranges between 15 and 35 basis points.

LSAP2

  1. Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011) using an event-study approach that analyzes the period from August 26, 2010 (day before the Chairman Bernanke's Jackson Hole speech) to November 2, 2010 (day before the LSAP2 announcement), find that the ten-year Treasury yield declined 25bps, the ten-year agency debt yield declined 27bps, and the Baa corporate bond index yield declined 17bps. In addition, their regression approach predicts that LSAP2 should result in a 26.5 basis-point decline in Treasury yields, which is quite aligned with the event-study results.
  2. D'Amico, English, López-Salido, and Nelson (2011) results suggest that the scarcity effect from the second LSAP program is about 45 basis points and the duration effect is about 10 basis points. Thus, the total effect of the second LSAP is estimated to be about 55 basis points.
  3. Meaning and Zhu (2011) applying the methodology developed by D'Amico and King (2010) estimate that LSAP2 on average lowered the yield curve by 21 basis points, with a maximum impact of 108 basis point for some securities with remaining maturity of about 20 years.
  4. Swanson (2011) also employs an event-study approach to measure the impact of Operation Twist (1961) that is extrapolated to quantify the effect of LSAP2, based on similarities between the two programs. The size of Operation Twist accounted for 4.5% of U.S. Treasury-guaranteed debt and it appeared to have reduced short- and long-term rates by 13bps. The size of LSAP2 was very similar to Operation Twist as percentage of Treasury debt, and it is estimated to have reduced long-term rates by 15bps.

MEP

  1. Meaning and Zhu (2011) simulations suggest that on average, yields may drop 22 basis points for securities with a remaining maturity over 8 years.
  2. Hamilton and Wu (Forthcoming), using regression on a sample from 1990 to 2007, estimate the effect of variations in the average maturity of privately-held Treasury debt on the term structure of interest rates, after controlling for level, slope and curvature of the yield curve. Using the estimated coefficients they evaluate a swap experiment where the Fed sells $400bn of short-term securities and buys $400bn of long-term securities. The results indicate that yields with maturity longer than 2 year fall about 17 basis points, while short-term yields increase of a similar amount.

5.2 LSAPs as One-Period Supply Shocks

Most studies mentioned above treated these asset purchase programs as causing instant shocks to the supply variables. Following the same approach, we consider the $300 billion of Treasury security purchase in LSAP1 as roughly corresponding to a $169 billion shock to private Treasury holdings in terms of ten-year equivalents (Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011), footnote 47), or a 1.2 percent shock to the Treasury supply factor when normalized by the 2009Q4 nominal GDP of $14.1 trillion. Similarly, the $1.25 trillion purchases of Agency MBS under the LSAP1 program roughly translates into a 8.9 percent shock to the MBS par supply factor. By comparison, both the $600 billion of Treasury Purchase under the LSAP2 program and the $400 billion simultaneous purchases of Treasury security with maturities longer than 6 years and sales of Treasury securities with maturity less than 3 years under the MEP are estimated to have removed about $400 billion 10-equivalents from the market, or about 2.6 percent and 2.5 percent shocks to the Treasury supply factor when normalized by the 2010Q4 and the 2011Q4 nominal GDP of $14.7 trillion and $15.3 trillion, respectively.

We use the estimated factor loadings in Table 3 to estimate the term premium effects of such supply shocks and summarize the results in Table 6. We estimate that the LSAP1 program lowered the ten-year Treasury yield by about 100 basis points, the five-year yield by about 65 basis points, and the two-year yield by about 25 basis points in the near term. By comparison, the other two programs (the LSAP2 program and the MEP) are both estimated to have lowered the ten-year Treasury yield by about 25 basis points and the five-year yield by 10 to 15 basis points, but have almost no effect on the two-year Treasury yield.


Table 6: Estimated Supply Factor Shocks and Term Premium Effects of LSAP1, LSAP2 and MEP
Program Shocks  Tsy_{t} (\%) Shocks  MBSpar_{t} (\%) Shocks  MBSdur_{t} (Years) Term Premium Effect (bps) 2-year Term Premium Effect (bps) 5-year Term Premium Effect (bps) 10-year
LSAP1 -1.2 -8.9   -27 -64 -99
LSAP2 -2.7     -3 -14 -26
MEP -2.6     -3 -13 -25
Note: This table reports model estimates of various asset purchase programs assuming one-period shocks.

5.3 LSAPs as a Sequence of Supply Shocks

The above analysis implicitly assumes that these asset purchase programs can be considered as one-time supply shocks that would dissipate over time following the historical dynamics of the supply variables. In reality, these programs are implemented according to pre-determined time tables and are widely expected by market participants to be gradually unwound in the future to return the SOMA portfolio to its historical level and composition, causing changes to not only the level but also the dynamics of the supply factors during and after the purchases. As a result, the term premium effect estimates in Table 3 may overstate or understate the true effect by ignoring the fact the the persistence of LSAP-induced supply shocks could deviate from its historical norm. To capture this divergence, we model those programs as generating a sequence of shocks to the Treasury and agency MBS supply factors,  u_{t}^{s}, which become known to the investors once the programs are announced:

\displaystyle X_{t} \displaystyle =[X_{t}^{y},X_{t}^{s}]^{\prime} (30)
\displaystyle \hat{X}_{t}^{s} \displaystyle =X_{t}^{s}+u_{t}^{s}, (31)

As shown in the appendix, the time- t effect of such a pre-announced Fed asset purchase program on the  n-period yield is given by
\displaystyle \hat{y}_{t,n}-y_{t,n}=b_{n}^{s}u_{t}^{s}+{\sum\limits_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }}\frac{n-i}{n}b_{n-i}^{s}\left( u_{t+i}^{s}-\rho ^{ss}u_{t+i-1}^{s}\right) ,% (32)

where  \hat{y}_{t}^{n} and  y_{t}^{n} represents bond pricing with and without Fed operations respectively.13

To understand the intuition in this formula, assume  \rho_{ss} to be equal to an identity matrix because the supply factors are typically highly persistence as evidenced by the estimates in Table 2. Equation 32 then simplifies to

\displaystyle \hat{y}_{t,n}-y_{t,n}=b_{n}^{s}u_{t}^{s}+{\sum\limits_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }}\frac{n-i}{n}b_{n-i}^{s}\left( u_{t+i}^{s}-u_{t+i-1}% ^{s}\right) ,% (33)

The above formula states that the Term Premium Effect (TPE) at time  t of any program is equal to the sum of discounted expected yield impacts from the future incremental supply shocks generated by such a program (i.e. the total stock TPE is equal to the sum of flow TPE).14 More specifically, recall that the supply shocks generated by each program  u_{t}^{s} represent changes to private holdings from the baseline scenario with no purchase program in each period.15 Therefore, the holdings difference between the current and the previous period,  (u_{t+i}% ^{s}-u_{t+i-1}^{s}), represents the net changes (positive for asset sales and negative for asset purchase) to the private holdings in that period from the program,16 and the entire term following the summation sign represents discounted future yield responses, with  b^{s} representing yield responses per unit of supply shocks and  \frac{n-i}{n} representing the discounting factor. The formula can be used to evaluate effects from both past programs and new program. For past purchase programs, the first supply shock would be the programs' cumulative purchases by that period. For a new program that yet to be started, the first term is the new program's projected net purchase in that period.

There are several important implications from the formula:

  1. A program's TPE depends on both purchase amount and investors' expectation of timing and pace of future exit sales.
  2. Similarly, a program's TPE is not fixed number. It can change over time depending on investors' changing expectation of timing and pace of future exit sales. For example, extending federal funds liftoff date also has important implication for program TPEs if asset sales dates are expected to be tied to federal funds liftoff dates as outlined by the FOMC in its June 2011 meeting minutes .
  3. The further away and the slower future exit sales, the bigger the TPE (there is less offsetting effect from those future sales due to more discounting).
  4. TPE of asset purchases and sales are not symmetric; yields would increase faster during asset sales than their declines during purchases (there are no offsetting terms in the TPE formula during asset sales).

To use the above TPE formula to evaluate the Fed's LSAP1, LSAP2 and MEP, we start by forming projections for SOMA Treasury and MBS holdings both under a baseline scenario with no such program and under each purchase program. We assume that the purchase proceeds at a constant speed such that the supply shocks reported in Table 6 are spread out evenly over the life span of each program. Compared with the baseline scenario, the Federal Reserve's purchases will create initial large negative shocks to the supply variables, which starts to shrink as SOMA holdings under the purchase program and under the baseline scenario start to converge when the Federal Reserve begins unwinding these programs. For illustrative purposes, we assume that investors expect the Fed to begin selling securities 2 years after the end of each program and to finish the sales 5 years after the end of the program. The results based on these assumptions are reported in Table 7, which is based on applying equation (32) to the series of supply shocks under each program (For the LSAP1 program, the duration of the Treasury purchase part is only 8 months and we ignore MBS runoff due to principal prepayment). These new estimates suggest that the LSAP1 program lowered the ten-year Treasury yield by about 60 basis points, the five-year yield by about 50 basis points, and the two-year yield by about 15 basis points in the near term. By comparison, the other two programs (the LSAP2 program and the MEP) are estimated to have lowered the ten-year Treasury yield by about 20 basis points and the five-year yield by 10 to 15 basis points, and to have almost no effect on the two-year Treasury yield. These results on LSAP1 and LSAP2 are similar to those reported in Chung, Laforte, Reifschneider, and Williams (Forthcoming).


Table 7: Estimated Term Premium Effects of LSAP1, LSAP2 and MEP at Announcment
Program Durations (months) Shocks per month  Tsy_{t} (\%) Shocks per month  MBSpar_{t} (\%) Shocks per month  MBSdur_{t} (Years) Term Premium Effect (bps) 2-year Term Premium Effect (bps) 5-year Term Premium Effect (bps) 10-year
LSAP1 15 -0.120 -0.593   -16 -52 -60
LSAP2 8 -0.338     -2 -13 -19
MEP 9 -0.289     -2 -13 -19
Note: This table reports model estimates of various asset purchase programs using assumptions on the time paths of the purchase programs.

6 Conclusions

In this paper, we provide evidence that private holdings of Treasury securities and agency MBS have explanatory power for variations in Treasury yields above and beyond that of standard yield curve factors.

Based on this observation, we extend the standard Gaussian essentially affine no-arbitrage term structure model to allow Treasury and MBS supply variables to affect Treasury term premiums. The model is fitted to historical data on Treasury yields as well as the supply and the maturity characteristics of private Treasury and MBS holdings. The estimation results suggest that a one-percentage-point decline in the Treasury ten-year equivalent to GDP ratio or the MBS par-to-GDP ratio would reduce the ten-year Treasury yield by about 10 basis points, while a one-year shortening of the average effective duration of private MBS holdings would lower the ten-year Treasury yield by about 7 basis points.

We then apply this model to evaluating the Federal Reserve's various asset purchase programs. Our estimates show that the first and the second large-scale asset purchase programs and the Maturity Extension program have a combined effect of about 100 basis points on the ten-year Treasury yield.


Appendix: LSAPs as a Sequence of Supply Shocks

This appendix derives the model-implied effect of a pre-announced asset purchase program by the Federal Reserve on the  n-period yield. Partition the state variables into yield factors (level and slope) and supply factors (average maturity and par debt/GDP ratio) and denote by `y' and `s' respectively.

\displaystyle X_{t}=\left\{ X_{t}^{y},X_{t}^{s}\right\}
Absent Federal Reserve operations, the state variables evolve as
\displaystyle X_{t+1}=c+\rho X_{t}+\Sigma\varepsilon_{t+1},
where  \rho can be similarly partitioned into \begin{displaymath}\left[ \begin{array}[c]{cc}% \rho^{yy} & \rho^{ys}\ \rho^{sy} & \rho^{ss}% \end{array}\right] .\end{displaymath} We model Federal Reserve operations as inducing deterministic shocks to  X_{t}^{s} that become known once the program is announced:
\begin{displaymath} \hat{X}_{t}=X_{t}+\left[ \begin{array}[c]{c}% 0\ u_{t}^{s}% \end{array}\right] \end{displaymath}
and assume that the effect of the operations completely goes away by period  T
\displaystyle \hat{X}_{T}=X_{T}, \displaystyle u_{T}^{s}=0.
Without Federal Reserve operations, bond prices are determined as
\displaystyle P_{t}^{n}=\exp\left( A_{n}+B_{n}X_{t}\right)
where
We assume that once the program is announced, bond prices become affine functions of  \hat{X}_{t}
\displaystyle \hat{P}_{t}^{n}=\exp\left( \hat{A}_{t,n}+\hat{B}% _{t,n}\hat{X}_{t}\right)
where the subscript  t in  \hat{A}_{t,n} and  \hat{B}_{t,n} captures the idea that bond price loadings could potentially be time-varying and depend on current and future shocks  \left\{ u_{t}\right\} . Standard pricing equation implies
\displaystyle P_{t}^{n} \displaystyle =E_{t}\left[ M_{t+1}P_{t+1}^{n-1}\right]    
\displaystyle \exp\left( \hat{A}_{t,n}+\hat{B}_{t,n}\hat{X}_{t}\right) \displaystyle =E_{t}\left[ \exp\left( -r_{t}-\frac{1}{2}\lambda_{t}^{^{\prime}}% \lambda_{t}-\lambda_{t}^{\prime}\varepsilon_{t+1}+\hat{A}_{n-1,t}% +\hat{B}_{n-1,t}\hat{X}_{t+1}\right) \right]    
  \displaystyle =E_{t}\left[ \exp\left( -\left( \delta_{0}+\delta_{1}\hat{X}% _{t}\right) -\frac{1}{2}\left( \lambda+\Lambda\hat{X}_{t}\right) ^{\prime}\left( \lambda+\Lambda\hat{X}_{t}\right) -\left( \lambda+\Lambda\hat{X}_{t}\right) ^{\prime}\varepsilon_{t+1}\right. \right.    
  \displaystyle \left. \left. \text{ }+\hat{A}_{n-1,t+1}+\hat{B}% _{n-1,t+1}\left( c+\rho\left( \hat{X}_{t}-\left[ \begin{array}[c]{c}% 0\\ u_{t}^{s}% \end{array} \right] \right) +\Sigma\varepsilon_{t+1}+\left[ \begin{array}[c]{c}% 0\\ u_{t+1}^{s}% \end{array} \right] \right) \right) \right]    
  \displaystyle =\exp\left[ -\delta_{0}+\hat{A}_{n-1,t+1}+\hat{B}% _{n-1,t+1}\left( c-\Sigma\lambda\right) +\hat{B}_{n-1,t+1}^{s}\left( u_{t+1}^{s}-\rho^{ss}u_{t}^{s}\right) \right.    
  \displaystyle \left. \text{ \ \ \ \ \ \ }+\left( -\delta_{1}+\hat{B}% _{n-1,t+1}\left( \rho-\Sigma\Lambda\right) \right) \hat{X}% _{t}\right]    

Matching terms yields
Taking the difference between recursions (37) and (35) and iterating give
\displaystyle \hat{B}_{t,n}-B_{n} \displaystyle =\left( \hat{B}_{n-1,t+1}-B_{n-1}\right) \left( \rho-\Sigma\Lambda\right)    
  \displaystyle =\cdots    
  \displaystyle =\left\{ \begin{array}[c]{cc}% \left( \hat{B}_{n-\left( T-t\right) ,T}-B_{n-\left( T-t\right) }\right) \left( \rho-\Sigma\Lambda\right) ^{T-t} & if\text{ }t+n>T\\ \left( \hat{B}_{0,t+n}-B_{0}\right) \left( \rho-\Sigma\Lambda\right) ^{n} & if\text{ }t+n\leq T \end{array} \right.    
  \displaystyle =0,    

since  \hat{B}_{n-\left( T-t\right) ,T}=B_{n-\left( T-t\right) } by the assumption that the effect of operations completely disappears by time  T and  \hat{B}_{0,t+n}=B_{0}=0 by definition. Similarly, taking the difference between recursions (36) and (34), using the result  \hat{B}_{t,n}=B_{n}, and iterating give
\displaystyle \hat{A}_{t,n}-A_{n} \displaystyle =\hat{A}_{n-1,t+1}-A_{n-1}+B_{n-1}% ^{s}\left( u_{t+1}^{s}-\rho^{ss}u_{t}^{s}\right)    
  \displaystyle =% {\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} B_{n-i}^{s}u_{t+i}-% {\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} B_{n-i}^{s}\rho^{ss}u_{t+i-1}.    

In yield terms
\displaystyle \hat{y}_{t,n} \displaystyle =-\frac{1}{n}\log\hat{P}_{t}^{n}    
  \displaystyle =-\frac{1}{n}\left( A_{t,n}+B_{t,n}\hat{X}_{t}\right)    
  \displaystyle =-\frac{1}{n}\left[ A_{n}+% {\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} B_{n-i}u_{t+i}-% {\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} B_{n-i}\rho^{ss}u_{t+i-1}\right.    
  \displaystyle \left. \text{ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ }+B_{n}\left( X_{t}+\left[ \begin{array}[c]{c}% 0\\ u_{t}^{s}% \end{array} \right] \right) \right]    
  \displaystyle =y_{t,n}-\frac{1}{n}\left( {\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i=0}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} B_{n-i}^{s}u_{t+i}^{s}-% {\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} B_{n-i}^{s}\rho^{ss}u_{t+i-1}^{s}\right)    
  \displaystyle =y_{t,n}-\frac{1}{n}\left[ B_{n}^{s}u_{t}^{s}+% {\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} B_{n-i}^{s}\left( u_{t+i}^{s}-\rho^{ss}u_{t+i-1}^{s}\right) \right]    
  \displaystyle =y_{t,n}+\left[ b_{n}^{s}u_{t}^{s}+% {\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} \frac{n-i}{n}b_{n-i}^{s}\left( u_{t+i}^{s}-\rho^{ss}u_{t+i-1}^{s}\right) \right]    

where  y_{t,n}=-\frac{1}{n}\left( A_{n}+B_{n}f_{t}\right) represents bond pricing without Federal Reserve operations. In other words,
\displaystyle b_{n}^{s}u_{t}^{s}+% {\displaystyle\sum\limits_{i=1}^{\min\left\{ T-t,n-1\right\} }} \frac{n-i}{n}b_{n-i}^{s}\left( u_{t+i}^{s}-\rho^{ss}u_{t+i-1}^{s}\right)
represents the time- t effect of a pre-announced asset purchase program by the Federal Reserve on n-period yields.


Bibliography

ANG, A., M. PIAZZESI,
2003. A No-Arbitrage Vector Autoregression of Term Structure Dynamics with Macroeconomic and Latent Variables. Journal of Monetary Economics 50(4), 745-787.
CHUNG, H., J.-P. LAFORTE, D. REIFSCHNEIDER, J. C. WILLIAMS,
Forthcoming. Have We Underestimated the Likelihood and Severity of Zero Lower Bound Events?. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.
COX, J. C., J. JONATHAN E. INGERSOLL, S. A. ROSS, 1985.
A Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates. Econometrica 53(2), 385-407.
DAI, Q., K. SINGLETON, 2000.
Specification Analysis of Affine Term Structure Models. Journal of Finance 55(5), 1943-1978.
D'AMICO, S., W. B. ENGLISH, D. LÓPEZ-SALIDO, E. NELSON, 2011.
The Federal Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs: Rationale and Effects. Working Paper.
D'AMICO, S., T. B. KING, 2010.
Flow and Stock Effects of Large-Scale Treasury Purchases. Working Paper.
DUFFIE, D., R. KAN, 1996.
A Yield-Factor Model of Interest Rates. Mathematical Finance 6(4), 379-406.
GAGNON, J., M. RASKIN, J. REMACHE, B. SACK, 2011.
The Financial Market Effects of the Federal Reserve's Large-Scale Asset Purchases. International Journal of Central Banking 7(1), 3-43.
GREENWOOD, R., D. VAYANOS, 2010a.
Bond Supply and Excess Bond Returns. Working Paper.
-------- , 2010b.
Price Pressure in the Government Bond Market. American Economic Review 100(2), 585-590.
GÜRKAYNAK, R. S., B. SACK, J. H. WRIGHT, 2007.
The U.S. Treasury Yield Curve: 1961 to the Present. Journal of Monetary Economics 54(8), 2291-2304.
HAMILTON, J. D., J. WU, Forthcoming.
The Effectiveness of Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking.
KIM, D. H., A. ORPHANIDES, 2012.
Term Structure Estimation with Survey Data on Interest Rate Forecasts. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis Forthcoming.
KIM, D. H., J. H. WRIGHT, 2005.
An Arbitrage-Free Three-Factor Term Structure Model and the Recent Behavior of Long-Term Yields and Distant-Horizon Forward Rates. Federal Reserve Board FEDS Working Paper 2005-33.
KRISHNAMURTHY, A., A. VISSING-JORGENSEN, 2008.
The Aggregate Demand for Treasury Debt. Working Paper.
-------- , 2011.
The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates. Working Paper.
LAUBACH, T., 2009.
New Evidence on the Interest Rate Effects of Budget Deficits and Debt. Journal of the European Economic Association 7(4), 858-885.
LITTERMAN, R., J. SCHEINKMAN, 1991.
Common Factors Affecting Bond Returns. Journal of Fixed Income 1(1), 54-61.
MEANING, J., F. ZHU, 2011.
The Impact of Recent Central Bank Asset Purchase Programmes. BIS Quarterly Review December.
MODIGLIANI, F., R. SUTCH, 1966.
Innovations in Interest Rate Policy. American Economic Review 56(1/2), 178-197.
MODIGLIANI, F., R. C. SUTCH, 1967.
Debt Management and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: An Empirical Analysis of Recent Experience. Journal of Political Economy 75(4, Part 2: Issues in Monetary Research), 569-589.
SVENSSON, L. E. O., 1995.
Estimating Forward Interest Rates with the Extended Nelson & Siegel Method. Quarterly Review, Sveriges Riksbank 3, 13-26.
SWANSON, E. T., 2011.
Let’s Twist Again: A High-Frequency Event-Study Analysis of Operation Twist and Its Implications for QE2. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity forthcoming.
VASICEK, O., 1977.
An Equilibrium Characterization of the Term Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 5(2), 177-188.
VAYANOS, D., J.-L. VILA, 2009.
A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates. Working Paper.



Footnotes

* The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect views of the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal Reserve System. We thank Jim Clouse, Bill English, Thomas Laubach, Emanuel Moench, Fabio Natalucci, Matt Raskin, Tony Rodrigues, and Brian Sack, and participants at the 2012 FRBNY SOMA Portfolio Workshop for helpful comments. All errors are our own. Return to Text
1. Division of Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board of Governors, [email protected], +1-202-452-2227. Return to Text
2. Division of Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board of Governors, [email protected], +1-202-736-5619. Return to Text
3. Hamilton and Wu (Forthcoming) and Greenwood and Vayanos (2010a) also presents evidence on the relationship between bond supplies and bond risk premiums. Return to Text
4. Data downloaded from http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2006/200628/200628abs.html. See Gürkaynak, Sack, and Wright (2007) for details. Return to Text
5. Data downloaded from http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2005/200533/200533abs.html. Return to Text
6. The ten-year equivalents of a fixed-income portfolio are calculated as the par amount of on-the-run ten-year Treasury notes that would have the same par value times duration as the portfolio under consideration. In mathematical terms, ten-year equivalents = par value of portfolio * average portfolio duration / duration of the ten-year on-the-run Treasury note. Return to Text
7. For MSPD, see http://www.treasurydirect.gov/govt/reports/pd/mspd/mspd.htm. For SOMA holdings, see http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/soma/sysopen_accholdings.html. Return to Text
8. See http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h41/, memorandum item, "Marketable securities held in custody for foreign official and international accounts." Return to Text
9. See http://www.gao.gov/special.pubs/longterm/debt/, which updates information in "Federal Debt: Answers to Frequently Asked Questions: An Update," GAO-04-485SP (Washington, D.C.: Aug. 12, 2004). Return to Text
10. Note that the gross issuance of MBS can still respond strongly to the level of rates. For example, in a refinance boom sparked by declining interest rates, old mortgages and MBS are replaced with new ones, but the net supply of MBS stays about unchanged. Return to Text
11. We experimented with an alternative assumption that Treasury and MBS supply factors carry zero risk premiums but the MBS duration factor can have its own risk premium, which would allow MBS convexity hedging demand to potentially carry its own premiums. Results are similar. Return to Text
12. There were also two changes in how principal payments from SOMA holdings of agency debt and agency MBS are handled. Those principal payments were allowed to roll off the Federal Reserve's balance sheet from the start of the LSAP1 program till August 2010, when they were reinvested in longer-term Treasury securities instead. The current policy of reinvesting those principal payments in agency MBS was announced in September 2011, together with the MEP. The first reinvestment policy change was taken into account in our analysis of the LSAP2 program but not the LSAP1 program, while the second reinvestment policy change was taken into account in our analysis of the MEP but not the LSAP1 or the LSAP2 programs. Return to Text
13. Chung, Laforte, Reifschneider, and Williams (Forthcoming) uses a similar formula to quantify the term premium effect of the LSAP1 and LSAP2 programs based on the deviations of SOMA holdings under these programs from a baseline scenario with no Fed purchases. Return to Text
14. We assume SOMA holdings return to normal and the supply shocks disappear at time T. Return to Text
15. For simplicity, we assume there are no exogenous shocks to the MBS average-duration supply factor from the program. In other words, this supply factor only changes endogenously through the program's effect on the other two supply factors and their effects on the ten-year Treasury yields. Return to Text
16. Remember each  u is a holdings difference under the program versus under no such program.  (u_{t+i}^{s}-u_{t+i-1}^{s}) thus is a difference-in-difference that captures the true "treatment" effect over time of the asset purchase program. This difference-in-difference approach is commonly used to study effects of regulatory changes in corporate finances and treatment effects of new drugs in parametrical studies. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text