Keywords: Large Scale Asset Purchases (LSAP), survey forecasts, balance sheet projections, term structure of interest rates, supply effects, treasury yields.
Abstract:
Through the financial crisis and subsequent recession, the Federal Reserve introduced unconventional monetary policy actions in order to "promote a stronger pace of economic recovery" and to help ensure that "inflation, over time, is at levels consistent with its mandate."3 To this end, the Federal Reserve embarked on a number of asset programs to purchase, sell, or reinvest securities that dramatically changed the Federal Reserve's securities holdings across all dimensions - size, composition, and maturity structure. Each asset program was implemented in part to put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates, aimed to support a stronger recovery.
But how much did these asset programs affect longer-term interest rates? There is a growing body of work on this subject, which can be divided into three broad categories. The first strand of research depends on event study methodology to determine the effect of the asset programs on interest rates at the onset of the programs.4 The second uses reduced-form regression analysis (either in a time series or using panel methods) to evaluate the effect of Federal Reserve purchases on interest rates over time.5 Finally, the third strand incorporates changes in the net private supply of different assets into a structural model of the economy or the yield curve to evaluate the effect of these programs on interest rates at any point in time.6 The dynamic nature of this third type of model requires one to incorporate information not only about the current level of System Open Market Account (SOMA) holdings, but also their expected future path for an accurate estimate on interest rates. In this paper, we take the third approach.
Most studies model the Federal Reserve's asset purchases and sales as either occurring instantly or spread out evenly over a short period of time. In reality, the purchases and sales were announced ahead of time, followed a pre-determined time table, and were commonly expected to be unwound at a future point of time, resulting in expected changes not only to the contemporaneous level of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet and private holdings of Treasury securities and agency MBS but also to their future dynamics. The dynamic pattern of the asset programs matter for the estimated impact on interest rates. To capture the projected time series patterns of these holdings at any point in time we use interest rate and macroeconomic projections consistent with the Blue Chip Economic Forecasters release at that time, Treasury issuance projections by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), as well as a possible path for the unwinding of monetary policy accommodation consistent with the exit strategy principles outlined in the minutes of the June 2011 Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meeting. We project private holdings of securities by recognizing that privately-held securities are simply the total stock of the securities outstanding minus the Federal Reserve's holdings.7 This strategy ensures that our estimates are consistent with market participants' views of the evolution of the economy and removal of unconventional monetary policy.
To construct our market expectations-consistent projections of Federal Reserve holdings, and hence private holdings, we lean on the methodology outlined in Carpenter, Ihrig, Klee, Quinn and Boote (2012). Their study considers how the Federal Reserve's balance sheet evolves with respect to both the Federal Reserve's projected unwinding of unconventional monetary policy accommodation, as well as the "natural" evolution of the balance sheet that accounts for increases in currency and Federal Reserve bank capital growth. The dollar amount of each asset purchase program and the maturity structure of the purchases and sales of securities also affect the expected evolution of the balance sheet, which is critical for determining the term premium effect (TPE). These characteristics are embedded in the estimates presented below and provide a view of how market participants perceived each asset program when it was implemented as well as what is expected as of today.
When assessing the interest rate effects of the Federal Reserve's asset programs, we focus on the "duration" channel through which Federal Reserve purchases reduce the quantity and the average maturity of long-term safe assets held by private investors and lower the term premiums on these assets. In particular, we adopt the model of Li and Wei (2012), which was motivated by empirical evidence that bond returns appear to be predictable by the amount and the average maturity of Treasury outstanding, as well as the theoretical work of Vayanos and Vila (2009), which shows that differences in maturity preferences of Treasury investors can generate supply effects in the government bond market. In the Li and Wei (2012) model, Treasury yields are driven by both yield factors and Treasury and agency MBS supply factors. They use the model to evaluate the magnitude of supply effects on term premiums, and find that a one-percentage-point decline in the private holdings of Treasury ten-year equivalents-to-GDP ratio or the MBS par-to-GDP ratio would reduce the ten-year Treasury yield by about 10 basis points, while a one-year shortening of the average effective duration of private MBS holdings would lower the ten-year Treasury yield by about 7 basis points. By combining estimates of market expectations constructed above with this term structure model, we are able to take a cohesive view of both the term structure of interest rates and the size and composition of the Federal Reserve balance sheet. As a result, the estimated interest rate effects of the Federal Reserve's asset programs are consistent with market expectations about how private holdings will evolve at the onset of an asset purchase program. This approach also allows us to track the expected "decay" of the program, and also allows us to evaluate the current TPE of the program using updated market expectations.
The main contributions of this paper are twofold. First, we provide a more systematic estimate of the TPE than other structural models by explicitly modeling the effects of an asset program on the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, contemporaneously and over time, that are consistent with market expectations. Most studies focus on the TPE at the onset of the asset programs, but we can re-evaluate the TPE of each asset program today. Second, we can estimate the expected decay of the TPE. The evolution of the TPE illustrates how past unconventional monetary policy will fade over the next several years.
Relative to other studies, this approach is more comprehensive and, therefore, could provide a more complete estimate of the TPE. For example, Chung et al (2011) uses the par value of the Federal Reserve's Treasury and agency MBS holdings to estimate their TPE. Because some of the asset programs hold the level of securities constant, but change the composition of holdings, the Chung methodology is not equipped to provide a TPE for this type of asset program. Li and Wei (2012) use a rule-of-thumb proxy for the evolution of private holdings of securities and, therefore, focus only on the contemporaneous impact of the asset programs. Here, we align our projections of private holdings with market participants' views about the expected path of Treasury issuance and future Federal Reserve holdings of securities and, as a result, have a contemporaneous estimate of the TPE of each asset program at implementation that is consistent with market expectations, have a projection of the expected path of decay of the TPE based on those expectations, and have the ability to evaluate the TPE with updated expectations at any point in time.
We evaluate the term premium effect of each of the six asset programs announced by the Federal Reserve as of June 2012 - the outright purchase programs announced on November 2008 and expanded in March 2009 (LSAP1); the reinvestment program announced in August 2010; the outright purchase program announced in November 2010 (LSAP2); the maturity extension program (MEP) announced in September 2011; the change to the reinvestment program announced in September 2011; and the continuation of the MEP announced in June 2012. We look at how the ten year Treasury yield was pushed down at the time of the program's inception based on rate expectations that were in place at the time, and we also examine how each program affects interest rates today, using current expectations. All told, our estimates suggest that the first LSAP program resulted in an apparent reduction in the 10-year Treasury yield term premium of about 40 basis points in the second quarter of 2009. At that time, based on market expectations, the TPE was estimated to drop at a moderate pace to about 10 basis points at the end of the second quarter of 2012, and then toward zero thereafter. The second LSAP program potentially reduced the term premium in the fourth quarter of 2010 by 10 to 15 basis points. The maturity extension program, announced in September 2011, brought down the term premium in the fourth quarter of 2011 by about an estimated 20 basis points; the estimated effect of the continuation of the maturity extension program, announced in June 2012, lowered the term premium in mid-2012 by about 11 basis points. The two reinvestment programs are estimated to have held down rates by 8 and 3 basis points in the third quarter of 2010 and the third quarter of 2011, respectively. These estimates of the term premium effect are based on market participants' views of the evolution of the economy at the time that each asset program was implemented. However, what was expected in 2009 did not always subsequently occur - for example, the June 2009 Blue Chip Forecast reported the federal funds rate was expected to rise above 25 basis points by June 2010. So, our model allows us to update the TPEs of each program for current market expectations. The current effect of all programs combined is estimated to be about 65 basis points. We attribute about one third of this apparent effect to the first large-scale asset purchase program, between 5 to 10 basis points to the second; a little over 10 basis points each to both the maturity extension program and its continuation, and the remainder to the reinvestment programs.
Finally, we perform some sensitivity analysis on our results. Since we assume the unwind of unconventional monetary policy is linked to when the federal funds rate moves above its lower bound, our results are sensitive to market participants' views on the most likely lift-off date. However, different sources have different views; as such, we compare how our current TPE estimate would change if we shifted from the Blue Chip forecast, which has lift off in late 2013, to the Primary Dealer survey, which has lift off in late 2014. We find the total current estimated TPE would move from 65 basis points to about 70 basis points. That is, if market participants shifted their views of timing of the lift off of the federal funds rate toward the guidance provided in the January 2012 statement that "economic conditions ...are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through late 20148, the TPE is estimated to be only modestly larger.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents background, including a brief explanation of the theory used in this paper and a short literature review, as well as a basic summary of the Federal Reserve's actions during the financial crisis. Section 3 discusses the theoretical term structure model with supply factors used to produce the term premium estimates of the balance sheet programs, and also reviews the methodology for constructing the balance sheet projections. Section 4 reviews the results of these efforts, and reports the interest rate effects of each program individually at the time of the program's implementation, as well as the interest rate effect of all programs together, taken at the present. Section 5 concludes.
This section reviews both the theory behind our model and the events during the financial crisis that shaped the Federal Reserve's balance sheet. We discuss each in turn.
Vayanos and Vila (2009) formulated a modern arbitrage-free preferred-habitat term structure model that shows a direct relationship between the term premium and the total duration risk faced by investors, in particular by the arbitrageurs. To the extent that LSAP programs remove duration risk from the market by withdrawing a portion of long-term securities, the risk premium built into the price of such assets should decline, and as a result, their yield should decline. The removal of duration risk should generate reactions of yields across much of the maturity spectrum - not just on the yields of purchased securities, but those of adjacent maturities as well.
Following on this theory, Li and Wei (2012) propose and estimate such an arbitrage-free term structure model with supply factors including the private holdings of Treasury and agency MBS securities. They show supply factors have important explanatory power on the term premium beyond that embedded in traditional yield curve factors. They also derive a formula that links the term premium to current and expected future shocks to these supply factors. As a result, their model can be used to evaluate an asset purchase program's term premium effect based on the program's projected impacts over time on these supply factors.
Of course, there are other plausible modeling approaches that differ from the one we have chosen here. While the Li-Wei paper emphasizes the duration risk channel that the Federal Reserve's asset programs work on reducing longer term rates as shown in the Vayanos and Vila (2009) preferred-habitat term structure model, other papers have emphasized different channels. For example, Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) offer evidence that there is another important channel that Treasury supplies could also affect interest rates, which they call "the safety premium channel." Another example is D'Amico and King (2010); their work emphasizes the "scarcity channel," or the available supply of nearby maturities. D'Amico, English, Lopez-Salido, and Nelson (2012) also focus on the scarcity channel in their analysis; they couple this channel with the duration channel to arrive at their final estimates of the term premium effects of the programs.
There are also alternative choices for modeling private holdings of securities. One example is in Chung et al (2011), which uses the differences in the SOMA-to-GDP ratio from a long-run average as a proxy for changes in private holdings of securities. While this methodology likely gives similar results to those presented here for the LSAP1 and LSAP2 purchase programs, it cannot evaluate the effect of the MEP or the change in the reinvestment policy in the same way as the modeling approach does here.
In order to have a cohesive estimate of how the Federal Reserve's asset programs affected private sector holdings of securities, one must consider how the SOMA evolves over time both with and without these programs. To do this properly, one has to ensure that the size of SOMA is consistent with the Federal Reserve's full balance sheet, as SOMA holdings are naturally affected by other factors, such as Federal Reserve actions associated with credit and liquidity facilities, demand for U.S. currency, and changes in Reserve Bank capital. To understand this point, we begin this section with a review of the historical composition of the balance sheet as well as how it changed as a result of the financial crisis.9
For most of the post-war period, the largest asset on the Federal Reserve's balance sheet was the SOMA, and the largest liability was Federal Reserve notes (FR Notes), or paper currency, in circulation outside of reserve banks. Growth of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet reflected growth in currency outstanding, as well as increases in Reserve Bank capital. As currency and capital grew, the Federal Reserve purchased Treasury securities in the open market to keep assets on the Federal Reserve's balance sheet equal to liabilities plus capital. The SOMA portfolio grew at a moderate pace in line with currency and capital for many years. And overall, changes in the SOMA portfolio were fairly small and growth was pretty steady.
In addition to steady growth, the composition of the SOMA portfolio was fairly steady as well. Over time, the Federal Reserve held a few types of securities in the SOMA portfolio; and from 2004 through the financial crisis, the portfolio held only Treasury securities.10 In particular, the SOMA usually had a substantial fraction of bills, in order to provide the Desk flexibility in managing its liquidity position. The weighted average maturity of the portfolio ranged from three to four years, rising a little around the year 2000 date change ("Y2K") and dropping some during the middle part of the last decade. Still, these changes were small, and implied a relatively steady weighted average maturity of the portfolio. In addition, as expressed in ten year equivalents, or duration equivalents of the on-the-run ten year note, the SOMA portfolio grew at a pace similar to the par growth rate of the portfolio, although fluctuated some as the duration of the ten year note changed.11
The remainder of the assets on the balance sheet, for example, borrowings from the discount window, other assets, and foreign exchange assets, were relatively small when compared with the SOMA portfolio. Even around Y2K and September 11, 2001, the asset side of the balance sheet was fairly steady. The liabilities side of the balance sheet saw a pickup in currency growth around Y2K, but again, changes were relatively small and not much in terms of a percentage of the balance sheet.
The Federal Reserve's balance sheet changed markedly with the start of the financial crisis. The first actions the Federal Reserve took in August 2007 were to engage in reserve-adding repurchase agreements and to lower the rate on discount window loans.12 This had the effect of increasing reserve balances available to depository institutions - on August 10, reserve balances were double what they had been the day before. Although reserve balances quickly returned to usual levels, on August 20, the Desk announced that it would redeem $5 billion in Treasury bill holdings in order to provide the Desk with greater flexibility in managing reserve balance levels "to offset factors that may add reserves to the banking system, such as additional discount window borrowings."
Strains continued in financial markets for most of the fall, and as year-end approached, the Federal Reserve introduced long-term repurchase agreements and the Term Auction Facility (TAF), both of which granted banks term loans of central bank funds. As these loans expanded the asset side of the balance sheet, reserve balances would necessarily increase if there was no offsetting change to other assets. Consequently, the Desk redeemed maturing securities throughout December in order to counteract the reserve-adding loan operations.13
With the near-failure of Bear Stearns and its subsequent takeover by JPMorgan Chase in March 2008, the Federal Reserve introduced the Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF) to provide loans of central banks funds to primary dealers.14 In addition, the spread of the primary credit rate over the target rate was narrowed again to 25 basis points. Furthermore, TAF auctions continued, with the total amount offered by the Federal Reserve climbing from $20 billion in December 2007 to $150 billion in October 2008.15 Again, all of these actions expanded the asset side of the balance sheet. Although reserve balances remained elevated relative to their previous levels as a result, the Desk allowed some Treasury bills to mature and sold other securities in order to sterilize these reserve-adding actions. As a result of the sterilization, Treasury bill holdings in the SOMA dropped to a little less than $20 billion in June 2008. Importantly, these actions on the asset side of the balance sheet implied that SOMA was, in fact, now only about half the size of Federal Reserve notes and capital. This point is quite important, as the sterilization dropped SOMA below what would be the level consistent with its fundamental driving factors and, all else equal, implied that as credit and lending decreased, ceteris paribus, SOMA would need to be replenished.16
After the collapse of Lehman Brothers in the fall of 2008, the Federal Reserve continued to lend funds through its various facilities. In addition, the Federal Reserve also started its first foray into actively changing the size and composition of the SOMA portfolio through purchase, sales, and reinvestment programs. From that time to the present, the Federal Reserve announced six different asset programs, summarized in table 1. In very broad terms, two changed the size of the balance sheet, and four focused mainly on composition, although all had some elements of both. The first LSAP program, announced on November 25, 2008, focused on purchases of agency MBS and agency debt. This action "[was] taken to reduce the cost and increase the availability of credit for the purchase of houses, which in turn should support housing markets and foster improved conditions in financial markets more generally." In the expansion of this program, announced March 18, 2009, the target purchase amounts for agency MBS and agency debt were increased, and Treasury securities purchases were added to the program. Once LSAP1 was complete, the size of the SOMA portfolio began to shrink, reflecting maturing and prepaying securities. Since the economic recovery was not as robust as the FOMC wanted, it directed the SOMA manager to reinvest the proceeds of maturing and prepaying agency securities into Treasury securities in an effort to keep the size of the SOMA portfolio roughly constant. The second LSAP program, announced in November 2010, entailed only purchases of Treasury securities. In the maturity extension program (MEP), which began in September 2011 and was extended in June 2012, the Federal Reserve sold shorter-dated securities and bought longer-dated ones. And finally, the Committee agreed to switch reinvestment of agency securities from Treasuries into agency MBS on the same date that it announced the initial MEP.
The next section lays out how we estimate the TPE of each of these six asset programs when they were announced, and also estimates the current effect of these programs.
This section reviews the two aspects of our modeling efforts: the term structure model with supply factors, and the construction of private sector holdings of securities. We discuss each in turn.
As discussed above, the term premium effect relies on the projected path of shocks to private-sector holdings of securities. We construct this path by projecting the evolution of total Treasury issuance and Federal Reserve holdings of securities.18 Our approach is a more complete version of Chung et al (2011) who also use balance sheet projections to evaluate LSAPs. They approximate the balance sheet contours by looking at the current par value of SOMA holdings and assume that SOMA holdings in excess of one year remaining maturity trend towards a long-run level of 5 percent of nominal GDP. This approximation is reasonable for a "rough estimate" of the TPE associated with the LSAP programs, but the results depend critically on the assumption for the steady-state SOMA to GDP ratio, which changes over time. More importantly, however, is that this methodology was created prior to the MEP and the model is not able to estimate the term premium effect of this type of program, which reflects a change the duration of SOMA, as short-term Treasury securities were swapped for longer-term Treasury securities, but not the nominal value of the portfolio.
This remainder of this section reviews the construction of the Federal Reserve's holdings of securities; many of the specifics of the methodology are reviewed in Carpenter et al (2012) and in the appendix.
To estimate the TPE for a given asset program upon implementation, we project how the SOMA portfolio evolved in two scenarios: (1) a projection of SOMA holdings immediately after at the onset of the program (using expectations by market participants at that point in time); and (2) a projection of SOMA holdings immediately prior to the implementation of the asset program under consideration (the counterfactual). For each scenario, we project the evolution of the balance sheet, and in particular, an exit strategy from policy accommodation. We base our projections on the general principles for the exit strategy that the FOMC outlined in the minutes of the June 2011 FOMC meeting.19 The Committee stated that it intended to take steps in the following order:
To complete the exit strategy we make a few additional assumptions. We tie changes in the SOMA portfolio to the date the federal funds rises from its effective lower bound.20 We assume that the reinvestment of securities ends six months before this date. We do not explicitly model the use of reserve-draining tools. We assume that sales of agency securities begin six months after the federal funds rate begins to rise and that the balance sheet has returned to normal size over about four years. In interpreting "normal size" we rely on an assumption that $25 billion in reserve balances, the average level before the crisis, is about "normal." The exit strategies and timing for each scenario are summarized in table 2.
In addition to these exit strategy assumptions, we need assumptions on interest rates and debt outstanding in order to construct the Federal Reserve's and then the private-sector holdings of ten-year equivalents, with the latter being the supply input for the term structure model. For interest rates, we rely on the Blue Chip Survey of Professional Forecasters for their views on the paths of the federal funds and 10 year Treasury rates immediately before the implementation of the policy action we consider. The five-year long-run annual projections from this data source are released twice a year, in June and December. In addition, these projections include a five year average for the selected variables for the years after the individual annual projections, resulting in a ten-year projection. As a result, for policy interventions announced in intervening months, we inspect the short-run projections that cover six quarters into the future that are produced monthly and interpolate these projections on a case-by-case basis, as described in table 3. Furthermore, for each of the balance sheet scenarios, we project total Treasury debt outstanding as well as the composition of Treasury debt so we can project ten year equivalents of both SOMA holdings and private-sector holdings. We use the Congressional Budget Office's deficit forecast close to the time of the inception of the program to project Treasury debt outstanding. For the construction of the maturity structure of Treasury debt, we rely on forecasts by Wrightson Research for Treasury issuance, as well as policy statements by the Treasury on the expected evolution of the maturity of Treasury debt over time.
Given the models and assumptions outlined in section 3, we now construct the estimated term premium effect of each of the six programs upon inception, as well as an estimate of the current TPE of all the asset programs combined and their individual contributions. A little balance sheet history is included with each program in order to inform the construction of the counterfactual.
The first large-scale asset purchase program, announced in November 2008, included purchases of agency mortgage-backed securities (MBS) and agency debt. Initially, the intended amounts for purchase were $500 billion in agency MBS and $100 billion in agency debt. After the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) lowered the federal funds rate to the current 0-25 basis point range in December 2008, and as the financial crisis wore on through the winter of 2009, the Federal Open Market Committee announced an expansion of the program in order to foster additional declines in longer-term interest rates. In March 2009, the FOMC revised its plan for the first LSAP program, and all together, the first round of purchases included $1.25 trillion of agency MBS, about $175 billion of agency debt, and $300 billion in longer-dated Treasury securities.21
Markets reacted to these actions. Upon the first announcement of the program, as documented in Gagnon et al (2011), the 10 year Treasury rate declined 7 basis points. However, the second announcement generated a 40 basis point decline in the 10 year Treasury rate. These reductions in the 10-year rate may have reflected changes in investor's beliefs about the size and composition of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, expectations for privately-available securities in the future, and general improvement in market functioning. To estimate the TPE associated with LSAP1, we need two projections - the counterfactual scenario where no LSAP1 was implemented, and the scenario with LSAP1.
We now turn to estimating the TPE for LSAP1. To do this, first, we construct a projection of how the Federal Reserve's balance sheet was expected to have evolved at the time the LSAP1 program was implemented. Next, we construct a projection of how the Federal Reserve's balance sheet would have evolved without a LSAP1 program.22 The difference between the paths of SOMA holdings in these two scenarios represents supposed supply shocks to private investors that were generated by the LSAP1 program; i.e, the path in our term premium model. Finally we plug the path into our model for the estimated TPE.
The projection for the Federal Reserve's balance sheet at the time when the first LSAP occurred is constructed using expectations for interest rates and other key variables at the time of the implementation of the program. It is helpful to remember that at the inception of LSAP1, the Committee stated that all purchases would be completed by December 2009. As the program wore on, the Committee revised its estimate to the first quarter of 2010 "in order to promote a smooth transition in markets."23 As a result, the projections here reflect the earlier completion date of the LSAP1 program. Another assumption at the time of LSAP1 was that as the agency securities prepaid or matured, that these securities would roll off the portfolio, i.e., there was no expectation of reinvestment at this time.
As shown by the solid line in the top left panel of figure 1, the Federal Reserve's portfolio, the System Open Market Account (SOMA), rose dramatically between late 2008 and end-2009. Treasury holdings, shown in the top right panel, moved up by $300 billion, while MBS holdings, shown in the bottom left panel, jumped from zero to nearly $1.25 trillion.
Our projection for how the Federal Reserve's balance sheet would have evolved after the purchases were completed depends critically on market expectations. There was no intention of further asset purchases, no expectation of reinvestment, and the assumed lift off date of the funds rate was not that much later than when the purchases were completed. As shown in the top panel of figure 2, the liftoff of the federal funds rate--the date at which the federal funds rate was projected to rise above the 0-to-25 basis point range--was projected to occur in June 2010, about six months after the Committee had stated that the LSAP1 purchase programs would be finished. The ten year rate, the bottom panel, was expected to fall a bit further from its April 2009 level, but then slowly approach the same long-run average a few quarters later than investors projected in October.
The projection of the path of the federal funds rate affects the contours of the balance sheet projection, as we anchor our assumed exit from monetary policy accommodation off this date as noted in table 2. Under the Blue Chip projection, liftoff occurs in June 2010, and using the June 2011 exit principles as a guide as noted in section 3.2, agency MBS sales begin in December 2010. This assumption leads to a normalization of the size of the portfolio - defined as the size for which the implied level of reserve balances is $25 billion - in October 2012, as listed in table 4. After that point, the portfolio grows in line with Federal Reserve notes and capital. Furthermore, when these purchases occur to increase the size of the portfolio, we propose that the purchases are at first only in Treasury bills until SOMA bills reach 1/3 of total Treasury securities held in the portfolio--roughly in line with the composition of the portfolio before the start of the financial crisis. Once this 1/3 bills, 2/3 notes and bonds ratio is reached, purchases continue so that this ratio stays constant. These assumptions are embedded in the projections shown in figure 1.
Putting the interest rate paths together with SOMA Treasury holdings gives us a path for SOMA Treasury ten year equivalents, shown in the bottom right panel of figure 2. This and SOMA MBS (par value) holdings are the two inputs into the term premium model for LSAP1.
To estimate the TPE associated with LSAP1, we need to look at how much larger projected SOMA holdings were with the asset purchases than in a scenario where no LSAP1 was implemented. In this scenario we assume the past actions of the FOMC would have been enough to move the economy (and the Federal Reserve's balance sheet) back toward its steady state growth path. This projection is consistent with what was assumed by Blue Chip forecasters immediately prior to LSAP1. We take the Federal Reserve's balance sheet as it appeared immediately prior to LSAP1, in October 2008, and make three assumptions regarding the evolution of the portfolio. First, because the SOMA portfolio comprised only Treasury securities, as had been the case for many years before the beginning of the crisis, we project a Treasury-only portfolio.24 Second, we assume the balance sheet expands at roughly the growth rate of currency and capital, its historical pattern for many years. Third, we assume that the path of unwinding of the credit and lending facilities followed its actual path.25 As shown by the dashed line in figure 1, because the level of securities in November 2008 was in fact lower than its long-run growth path as a result of the runoff of securities that occurred during the time when the credit and lending facilities were sterilized, we forecast that SOMA's holdings of Treasury securities begin to climb around October 2009.26 After the unwind of the credit and liquidity facilities, the SOMA portfolio grows at a constant rate, in line with growth of currency (which is in line with growth of nominal GDP as reported in the table appendix)) and capital.
To generate the projected supply shocks for this scenario we use the interest rate forecasts shown in figure 2, which are the October 2008 and June 2008 Blue Chip forecasts for the near term (six quarters) and longer term respectively. The target federal funds rate was expected to decline 25 basis points from its level at the time, and bottom out at 1 percent. The funds rate was then expected to climb steadily to about 4.5 percent, near its long-run average and somewhat lower than it had been immediately preceding the crisis. As shown in the bottom panel, the ten year rate was expected to climb as well, reaching a long-run value of about 5.25 percent by the end of 2012. Using these interest rates with the projected SOMA Treasury holdings path, the SOMA Treasury 10-year equivalents projection is shown in the bottom right panel of figure 2.
With the LSAP1 and LSAP1 counterfactual projections, we can construct our supply shocks for our TPE model as the LSAP1 value minus the counterfactual value for both SOMA MBS holdings and SOMA Treasury ten-year equivalents as displayed in the bottom panels of figure 1. Since the Federal Reserve never held MBS prior to the financial crisis, the projected value of is just the amount of Federal Reserve holdings normalized by nominal GDP. For Treasury ten-year equivalents, one can see that projected Treasury holdings are actually lower in the LSAP1 scenario than those in the counterfactual from mid-2010 through mid-2014, reflecting the fact that LSAP1's purchases of MBS holdings boost the SOMA value and Treasury holdings are not needed to offset growth in currency and capital. Looking at the long-run, actual currency growth was much faster than what would have been projected in October 2008 - likely a result of precautionary demand for dollar-denominated banknotes. Consequently, the balance sheet is permanently larger in the LSAP1 scenario than in the counterfactual.
As shown in figure 3 and reported in row 1, column 1 of table 5, the initial impact of the LSAP1 program on the ten-year Treasury yield was to push down the rate by about 40 basis points. This estimate is almost identical to the original announcement effect, as discussed above, and our estimate is certainly well within confidence bands around other studies' estimates. In particular, D'Amico and King report a 20 basis point decline attributable to the Treasury portion of the LSAP, while Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2011) estimate a 100 basis point fall for all types of securities purchased under this program. The similarity between the original announcement effect and our estimate suggests that our modeling approach captures the change in expectations for the balance sheet at that time, and gives us a reasonable estimate of the term premium effect of the program.
Figure 3 also shows the expected path of decay of the TPE. As the Federal Reserve's balance sheet is projected to slowly return to a more normal level over time, securities are returned to private investors and the TPE becomes less negative. As reported in column 3 of table 5, by early 2013 the estimated TPE associated with the first LSAP program is -6 basis points. This reduction primary reflects two factors: first, the Federal Reserve was not reinvesting the proceeds from prepayments of agency securities and so those securities were essentially returned to private investors; and second, markets expected the funds rate to rise above 25 basis points in June 2010, implying the unwind of unconventional monetary policy well before 2013.
After the first round of LSAPs were completed in March 2010, and final settlements of agency MBS were finished in June 2010, the balance sheet began to contract. Much of this contraction was due to prepayments on holdings of agency MBS: when a mortgage borrower refinances a mortgage or sells a home with a mortgage, the borrower pays off the outstanding mortgage balance, and consequently, the MBS associated with the mortgage "prepays" before the stated maturity of the security. With mortgage rates near historical lows, the incentive for borrowers to refinance was fairly strong, and as a result, there were substantial prepayments on the Federal Reserve's agency MBS holdings. Indeed, over July 2010, the Federal Reserve's holdings of agency securities fell by $6 billion.
This contraction in the balance sheet was implicitly offsetting LSAP1's TPE and pushing up interest rates at a time when the economic recovery was still not robust. In order to address the contraction of the balance sheet and the upward pressure on interest rates due to agency securities prepayments, the FOMC announced an agency securities reinvestment program in August 2010. The program worked as follows: After the monthly release of agency MBS prepayment factors, on or around the eighth business day of the month the Desk announced a target amount of Treasury securities purchases from equal to the amount of projected prepayments over the next month. The targeted maturities for this program were concentrated in sectors less than 10 years, with an average targeted maturity of a little over six years. Market participants reacted to this announcement, and the 10 year Treasury yield fell 5 basis points at the start of the program.
We now turn to estimating the TPE for the MBS reinvestment, following similar steps as outlined for the LSAP1 program.
The balance sheet projections associated with the reinvestment program are shown in figure 4. While agency securities holdings were projected to decline as they prepaid or matured, Treasury securities holdings climbed (both par amount and in terms of ten year equivalents) with the reinvestment of the agency securities into Treasury securities, and total SOMA holdings held relatively steady. Using the expectations that were likely in place at the time of the start of the program, a notable amount of agency securities were expected to be reinvested before rolloff begins in late 2010.27 From that point forward, the SOMA was expected to contract. Sales start in December 2011, six months after the funds rate lifts off, and as shown in table 4, all agency MBS are sold or prepay from the portfolio as of November 2015.
As reported in table 2, investors became increasingly pessimistic about the economy in the months leading up to the reinvestment program. By the time of the reinvestment decision, the federal funds liftoff date shifted out to mid-2011 and, as shown in figure 5, the ten year rate fell dramatically from June 2010 to September 2010.28 This not only changed the pace of the run off of LSAP1 securities, but also affected the expected timing of the FOMC's exit strategy.
For this counterfactual, we use interest rates and balance sheet projections starting in June 2010, the end of the first LSAP program. As shown in the top panel of figure 5, investors expected the federal funds rate to remain at its lower bound until October 2010. The ten year rate was expected to climb as well, and reach its steady-state level by mid-2014.
These interest rate paths inform the projected evolution of the balance sheet. The balance sheet projection starts with how it looked at the end of LSAP1: agency MBS were close to their peak holdings, agency debt was around $170 billion, and Treasury notes and bonds were $753 billion. The balance sheet is poised to decline in size from that point forward as a result of prepayments on agency MBS holdings as well as maturities of agency debt holdings. We project agency MBS prepayments using the SOMA holdings of agency MBS as of June 2010, and then apply the actual prepayment speeds on those securities reported by Barclays for the first few months of the projection. We then gradually allow the prepayment speed approach that which is implied by the agency MBS market standard prepayment assumption. By contrast to agency MBS, agency debt maturities are known with certainty and we use this schedule in our projections. Because liftoff occurs in October 2010, Treasury securities begin to decline immediately, both in par levels and ten year equivalents.29 Prepayments on agency MBS securities are expected to be rapid in the short run, but then prepays began to return to normal speeds by liftoff. Combining together all of these paths, the size of the balance sheet normalizes around mid-2013 and no agency securities remain in the SOMA portfolio after November 2015.
The term premium effect estimate of the reinvestment program is shown in figure 6 as the deviation between the TPE with and without reinvestment and row 2, column 1 of table 5. Using the expectations of the balance sheet in place at the time of the program, the estimates suggest that the reinvestment program was pushing down the 10-year Treasury yield by almost 10 basis points. The joint potential effect of both the LSAP1 and reinvestment program as of June 2011 was to depress the 10 year by 30 basis points, column 2. Importantly, this is not the sum of the LSAP1 and reinvestment TPEs at the onset of each program. Between June 2010 and June 2011, agency MBS prepaid, which likely reduced the TPE associated with LSAP1, and as noted above, was a factor in the FOMC's decision to begin the reinvestment program. Also discussed earlier, at the time of the announcement of the reinvestment program, the ten year Treasury yield declined about 5 basis points, again, roughly in line with our estimate of the term premium effect of the program.
Starting with the Chairman's speech at Jackson Hole at the end of August 2010, there was some expectation in financial markets that another round of LSAPs might occur. Over the next couple of months, the 10 year Treasury rate fell about 10 basis points perhaps reflecting, in part, an anticipation of an asset program. On November 3, 2010, the FOMC announced that it intended to purchase $600 billion of longer-term Treasury securities by the end of the second quarter of 2011, implying a pace of about $75 billion per month. In addition, the agency MBS reinvestment program was slated to continue. On net on the announcement, 10 year Treasury yields actually rose about 4 basis points. Part of this rise was attributable to the Desk's announcement of the targeted maturities for purchases in the program, which reportedly were somewhat shorter-dated than investors had expected. Over the course of the two programs, Treasury holdings increased $716 billion through June 2011.
The projected effect of the LSAP2 program on the balance sheet is depicted in figure 7. In par amounts and in ten-year equivalents, Treasury holdings likely reach a peak in mid-2011, at the end of the purchase program. The weighted average maturity of the portfolio was projected to decline a little bit after the completion of the program, as the $600 billion in purchases were concentrated between 2 and 10 years of maturity, with the weighted average maturity hovering around 6 ½ years. As a result of the lowering of longer-term interest rates, the prepayment speed on the portfolio picked up a little bit, which contributed to a lower amount of agency MBS holdings and a higher amount of reinvested securities. Because more securities prepaid and the prepay rate is faster, there are fewer to sell during the sales period.
Despite the announcement of additional policy accommodation through the LSAP program, investors pushed back the expected liftoff date, to December 2011. The path of the ten year rate followed suit, with the rate exceeding 5 percent in the second quarter of 2015.
For this counterfactual, we used the short-run Blue Chip forecast from September 2010 smoothed into the Blue Chip forecast from December 2010. Although this forecast may have contained some expectation of an upcoming LSAP program, we would like the forecast to contain the effect of the reinvestment program announced in August 2010. As shown in the top panel of figure 8, under this scenario, the federal funds rate lifts off in the second quarter of 2011. The ten year rate reaches its steady state level of about 5 percent in late 2014.
As with the other programs, the liftoff date dictates the contour of the balance sheet projection. Because liftoff occurs in June 2011, reinvestment continues through November 2010, after which the balance sheet begins to contract. The size of the portfolio is projected to normalize about two years after liftoff, in mid-2013, after which point Treasury holdings climb as MBS continue to be sold. MBS holdings reach zero in November 2015; subsequently, the projected growth in the portfolio reflects the expansion of currency and capital. The weighted average maturity of the Treasury portfolio is projected to hold relatively steady through most of the projection, until purchases of coupon securities resume.
Similar to the other programs, these two projections enable us to estimate the term premium effect of the second LSAP program. As shown in figure 9 and row 3, column 1 of table 5, the announcement effect of the LSAP2 program is estimated to be about 15 basis points. While this is quite a bit larger than the actual announcement effect at the time of the program, it may reflect the effect of the program on private investors' holdings of duration, as this program was highly anticipated. That is, in the days leading up to the FOMC announcement, market participants priced in an LSAP2 program of similar size to that which was implemented, and thus, little news was learned by investors on the announcement of the program. Indeed, the ten year rate had moved down 21 basis points in the roughly two months between the discussion of the program at Jackson Hole and its implementation in November 2010.
Our LSAP2 TPE estimate of 15 basis points is in line with Swanson (2011), while D'Amico, English, Lopez-Salido, and Nelson (2012) estimate a much larger decline of about 55 basis points.30 Other estimates fall somewhere between those two values.
As shown in figure 9 and reported in column 2 of the table, the total TPE at the inception of LSAP2 is estimated to have been 40 basis points. So, with the continuation of the reinvestment program and the introduction of LSAP2, the FOMC kept the same downward pressure on the ten year Treasury yield at this point in time as it did in June 2010 when it completed LSAP1. One can also see that the TPE was projected to decay quite quickly, with the TPE being only -14 basis points by 2013:Q1, reflecting market expectations that the funds rate would be lifting off from the zero bound in December 2011.
By the summer of 2011, the purchase programs had increased the size of the balance sheet well above what would have been expected by the growth rate of currency and capital, but the pace of economic recovery was not as fast as desired by the FOMC. The next two programs implemented by the Federal Reserve kept the size of the balance sheet the same, but changed its composition and duration to lower interest rates and help support a stronger recovery. On September 22, 2011, the Committee announced the MEP and the reinvestment of agency securities payments into MBS. In this section we focus on the impact of the MEP and the MBS reinvestment, together and individually, on the term premium.
For the MEP, the Desk sold $400 billion of shorter-dated Treasury securities and purchased an equal amount of long-dated Treasury securities. For the MBS reinvestment program, which had the stated objective of supporting conditions in mortgage markets, both maturing and prepaying agency securities (both debt and MBS) were rolled over into MBS. This latter policy replaced the reinvestment program where these securities were rolled over into Treasury securities. These two policies combined had the effect of keeping roughly constant the holdings of each security type in the SOMA portfolio, but at the same time, lengthening the maturity of the portfolio. On the announcement of the two programs, the 10 year yield dropped 7 basis points.31
Although the par value of SOMA is roughly the same under the MEP and agency MBS reinvestment programs as without the two programs, the composition of the balance sheet is projected to be notably different. To start, as shown in figure 10, in the MEP projection, the Treasury holdings remained constant but the weighted average maturity increases over the 9 months of the program; when measured in terms of ten year equivalents, the MEP Treasury portfolio is boosted by almost $300 billion. Second, agency MBS holdings incrementally increased as a result of the reinvestment of agency debt into agency MBS. Because of these factors, the balance sheet is "larger" for longer with the MEP and reinvestment policy than without, and the normalization of the balance sheet is pushed out to 2017.
Our assumptions on interest rates are similar with and without the MEP and reinvestment. According to the Blue Chip forecast, there was little change in expectations of the liftoff in the federal funds rate from the Blue Chip forecast between August 2011 and September 2011. By contrast, the ten year rate, as shown in the bottom panel of figure 11, was pushed down, and remained near the lower bound through 2013. For all series, we used the same longer-run forecast from June 2011, which was taken at the end of LSAP2, but before the change in the reinvestment policy or the MEP.
The projection of total SOMA without the MEP and change in reinvestment policy looks quite similar to the projection with these additional programs in the near term. However, by comparing the dotted red line (no MEP and no MBS reinvestment) to the solid line (MEP and MBS reinvestment) in figure 10 one can see there is a difference in the composition of securities holdings. As noted in the top right panel, prior to the MEP and change in reinvestment strategy, Treasury holdings would have increased almost $300 billion from their level in August 2011 as a result of the reinvestments of agency securities into Treasury securities. As shown in the bottom left panel, agency MBS holdings are projected to run off more quickly as there was no reinvestment into MBS. Further out in the projection, returning to the top left panel, without these last two programs SOMA holdings would have declined quicker and normalization of the balance sheet would have occurred in the first half of 2016. This reflects the fact that MBS holdings would have been much smaller in the medium term without the MBS reinvestment program in place. As shown in the bottom right panel, ten year equivalents for Treasury securities follow the same general contour as that for par holdings.
Although disentangling an announcement effect from the agency MBS reinvestment program from that of the MEP is not possible in the actual data, we can use our framework for an approximate estimate of each program's effect on the 10-year Treasury yield. We do this by projecting the balance sheet with and without the MEP, as shown in figure 10. The MEP, by extending the maturity of the Treasury securities holdings, has a projected obvious effect on the evolution of the SOMA portfolio, both in par value and ten year equivalents that can be seen by comparing the black solid lines with the blue dashed lines. Since the projections are as would be expected, we do not discuss them further, but use the deviations between these two projections to estimate the TPE associated with the MEP.
The change in the composition of the balance sheet has a notable impact on the estimated term premium effect. As shown in figure 12 and column 1 of table 5, the estimated maximum effect of the MEP and MBS reinvestment programs combined was -20 basis points. The vast majority, 17 basis points, is potentially attributed to the MEP. Therefore, although the par amount of the MEP program was less than the second LSAP program, the impact on the term premium is estimated to be about 1 ½ times as large.
Estimates reported in other research for the interest rate effects of the MEP are fairly close together. Hamilton and Wu (forthcoming) report a 22 basis point reduction in the 10-year yield of a swap program in similar size as the MEP, and Meaning and Zhu (2011) estimate a -17 basis point effect. The convergence of these results likely rests on the lack of anticipation of the MEP in markets, as well as a more structured methodology in each of these studies.
Against a backdrop of projected moderate GDP growth as well as an anticipated slow decline in the unemployment rate, at the June 2012 FOMC meeting the Committee decided to continue the maturity extension program that was previously scheduled to be completed at the end of that month. The Committee stated its intention to sell or redeem an additional $267 billion of short-dated securities and buy an equal amount of longer-dated ones before the end of 2012. All reinvestment policies for agency securities remained unchanged. As with the programs announced in September 2011, these two policies combined had the effect of keeping roughly constant the holdings of each security type in the SOMA portfolio, but lengthening the maturity of the portfolio. At the time of the announcement of the program, the weighted average maturity of the Treasury portfolio was assumed to increase to about 120 months, or 10 years. On the announcement of the program, the nominal Treasury yield curve flattened notably, with 2- and 5-year Treasury yields edging up 2 basis points and 10- and 30-year yields declining 2 to 7 basis points.
Again, although the par value of SOMA is roughly the same under the first installment of the MEP and the continuation, the duration of the portfolio is notably different. To start, as shown in figure 13, in the continuation of the MEP, Treasury holdings are projected to remain constant until 2015 even though roll off of securities is assumed to begin in mid-2013. In terms of ten-year equivalents, the portfolio remains elevated beyond the projection period. As in the initial MEP, agency MBS holdings are projected to incrementally increase as a result of the reinvestment of agency debt into agency MBS. Normalization is estimated to be pushed out even further than under the initial MEP, to August 2017.
Our assumptions on interest rates are slightly different for the continuation of the MEP relative to those for the initial implementation of the MEP in September 2011. Perhaps, in part, being influenced by the extension of the forward guidance in January 2012 that rates would be low "until at least late 2014," market participants pushed out the liftoff date about six months, to the end of 2013. Again, the ten year rate was revised lower. For all series, we used the same longer-run forecast from December 2012, which was taken mid-way through the first MEP, but before the announcement of the continuation of the MEP.
The near-term projection of total SOMA in par value terms with the extension to the MEP looks quite similar to the projection without it. However, in figure 13, one can see that in terms of 10 year equivalents, the portfolio is estimated to be nearly 172 billion larger with the extension of the MEP. Also, the projected date of normalization is pushed out to August 2017, 7 months later than prior to the extension.
According to our calculations, the continuation of the MEP reduced the ten-year Treasury interest rate by 11 basis points. As shown in figure 15, this pushed the TPE back to the level it was at the start of the first MEP. Consequently, one might say that, coupled with the change in the forward guidance, the FOMC action provided the same additional monetary policy accommodation through the extension of the MEP as was instituted at the start of the MEP in September 2011.
Since the start of the asset programs, expectations of how monetary policy accommodation will unwind have changed. As a result, the calculation of term premium effects associated with each of the asset programs may no longer be consistent with current policy expectations. That is, the estimated term premium effects for, say, the first quarter of 2012 reported in the above figures were those associated with what market participants thought monetary policy accommodation would look like at the time of the implementation of the asset program. One can easily see that some assumptions made at the onset of these programs may not hold today. Consider what market participants thought at the time of when LSAP1 was implemented. As reported in table 2, in April 2009, the Blue Chip forecast expected the federal funds rate to rise above 25 basis points by June 2010. Of course, the federal funds rate remains in the 0-25 basis point range today, about two years later. Over time, therefore, the term premium effect associated with LSAP1 would have been adjusted for likely changes in market participants' views of the unwinding of monetary policy.
In order to control for this effect in our analysis, we construct program and counterfactual balance sheet projections for each program, shown in figure 16, using the Blue Chip forecast for interest rates as of June 2012, figure 17. This allows us to decompose the current term premium effect into the individual effect of each program, standardized by current expectations for policy. In addition, we also used "realized" paths for items on the balance sheet through June 2012. For example, rather than agency MBS prepayments relying on an assumed model through June 2012, we use actual outstanding agency MBS balances outstanding; for Treasury securities, we use actual holdings rather than projected; and for all other assets on the balance sheet, we again use actual figures. The difference resulting from this change is relatively small; our estimates suggest not more than 5 basis points.
Figure 18 displays the estimated term premium effect associated with each program. As indicated by the solid black line, we estimate that the Federal Reserve's asset programs are currently depressing the 10-year Treasury yield by 64 basis points.32 About one-third of this effect can be potentially associated with LSAP1 actions, another 8 basis points is a result of LSAP2 actions, 25 basis points possibly reflects both the initial MEP and its extension, and the remainder is likely associated with reinvestment. Although one of the main drivers in differences of the programs is the change in expectations regarding interest rates, there are also differences that result from using realized balance sheet quantities instead of projected ones. For example, the projection at the time of LSAP1 had much slower agency MBS prepayments than what actually occurred, as interest rates declined much more than what was expected at the time of the implementation of LSAP1. Consequently, the realized term premium effect was likely a bit smaller than the projected term premium effect at the inception of the program.
To summarize, the yield on the 10-year Treasury has fallen about 160 basis points since the start of the LSAP1 program. Although there have been many factors that have affected yields over the financial crisis, we would potentially attribute slightly more than a one-third of the drop to the asset programs by the Federal Reserve.
Our TPE estimate depends critically on the assumed path of how the Federal Reserve's unconventional monetary policy is expected to unwind and, hence, how the net supply of assets return back to private investors. Using the June 2011 FOMC Minutes as guidance, we link the exit strategy principles to when the federal funds rate will lift off from the lower bound. Here we test how much our TPE estimate would change if we shifted from the June 2012 Blue Chip forecast (which has lift off in late 2013) to the June 2012 Primary Dealer survey (which has lift off in late 2014). Overall, we find that if market participants shifted their views of the timing of the lift off of the federal funds rate toward the guidance provided in the January 2012 statement that "economic conditions ...are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through late 2014", the TPE would be only modestly larger.
For this analysis, we take the federal funds rate path for the MEP2 analysis and shift the curve out to the right for about one year, holding the rate steady at 12.5 basis points from today through the fourth quarter of 2014. When the funds rate moves above the lower bound, the contour of the path is identical to the Blue Chip contour. With only this adjustment to the MEP2 assumptions, as shown in figure 19, the balance sheet contours are very similar to the MEP2 projection; the main difference is that normalization of the balance sheet is projected to occur in January 2018, about 5 months later than in the December 2013 liftoff scenario. Because the balance sheet is large for a longer period of time, the total contemporaneous TPE, as shown in Figure 20, is estimated to be about 70 basis points. The rule-of-thumb suggested by this exercise is that a change in forward guidance of about half-a-year results in an increase in the term premium effect of about 3 basis points.
More generally, this analysis suggests that for each of the asset programs, there are two critical factors affecting the estimate of the TPE. The first is the effect of the asset program when it is announced, and the second is the effect of expectations for liftoff and, hence, the unwinding of the unconventional monetary policy. We take the view that both components are critical for evaluating the impact of an asset program, and without controlling for both of these properly, the effects of balance sheet actions may be over- or understated.
This paper provides a novel application of a term structure model that includes supply effects to evaluate the effect of the Federal Reserve's recent unconventional monetary policy on interest rates. Overall, our results suggest that a large portion of the decline in interest rates since April 2009 may be attributed to the Federal Reserve's asset programs. In doing so, we highlight the importance of expectations of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet and of interest rates on the impact of the asset programs, as well as the importance of careful application of an implied Federal Reserve portfolio strategy to calculating these effects. That said, we expect that our results are relatively robust to our assumptions, although any change that would expand (contract) the SOMA portfolio would lead to a higher (lower) interest rate effect.
Going forward, this framework can be easily applied to study the effects of purchase programs by other central banks, in addition to, with some tweaks, the effect of higher-or-lower than expected debt issuance by the Treasury. In general, however, the results in this paper apparently seem to suggest that the central bank can potentially use asset programs to influence market interest rates, even when the target federal funds rate is at the zero lower bound.
This section reviews a few of the key inputs into the balance sheet construction. Details on other factors are available in Carpenter et al (2012).
In order to form a complete balance sheet through time, we need a projection of each element of the balance sheet.
SOMA Treasury holdings are assumed to evolve through a combination of outright purchases and outright sales in the secondary market, reinvestment at auction, and maturities.
Nominal securities | Nominal securities | Nominal securities | Nominal securities | Nominal securities | Nominal securities | Nominal securities | TIPS |
1½ -2½ | 2½-4 | 4-5½ | 5½-7 | 7-10 | 10-17 | 17-30 | 1½-30 |
Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years |
21 | 17 | 19 | 21 | 9 | 8 | 5 |
Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | TIPS |
1½ -2½ | 2½-4 | 4-5½ | 5½-7 | 7-10 | 10-17 | 17-30 | 1½-30 |
Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years |
5 | 20 | 20 | 23 | 23 | 2 | 4 | 3 |
Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | Nominal Securities | TIPs |
1½ -2½ | 2½-4 | 4-5½ | 5½-7 | 7-10 | 10-17 | 17-30 | 1½-30 |
Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years | Years |
21 | 17 | 19 | 21 | 9 | 8 | 5 |
Nominal coupon securities | Nominal coupon securities | Nominal coupon securities | Nominal coupon securities | TIPS |
6-8 years | 8-10 years | 10-20 years | 20-30 years | |
32 | 32 | 4 | 29 | 3 |
Year | CBO debt held by the public ($ billions) |
2010 | 9,018.94 |
2011 | 10,164.11 |
2012 | 11,152.93 |
2013 | 11,773.39 |
2014 | 12,148.09 |
2015 | 12,462.72 |
2016 | 12,839.81 |
2017 | 13,169.09 |
2018 | 13,473.33 |
2019 | 13,820.23 |
2020 | 14,180.64 |
2021 | 14,541.09 |
Maturity | November 2011 Issuance by maturity ($ billions) | Initial shares of issuance |
1 month | 140 | 0.25 |
3 month | 116 | 0.21 |
6 month | 108 | 0.19 |
1 year | 25 | 0.04 |
2 year | 35 | 0.06 |
3 year | 32 | 0.06 |
5 year | 35 | 0.06 |
7 year | 29 | 0.05 |
10 year | 24 | 0.04 |
30 year | 16 | 0.03 |
Source: Wrightson, Auction Calendar
The agency securities portfolio is assumed to evolve due to a combination of purchases, sales, and prepayments.
A premium (discount) is the amount paid above (below) the par value of a security. We use straight-line amortization of these premiums and discounts over the expected life of current SOMA holdings. We derive new premiums and discounts from outright Treasury purchases by using the difference between the assumed coupon of the security being purchased and the corresponding market interest rate, as given by the yield curve estimates shown below.34
Tenor | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 10 | 15 | 20 | 30 |
Constant | -0.0143 | -0.0183 | -0.0178 | -0.0155 | -0.0124 | 0.0018 | 0.0084 | 0.0096 | 0.0050 |
Fed Funds | 0.7264 | 0.5363 | 0.3923 | 0.2822 | 0.1958 | -0.0394 | -0.1206 | -0.1487 | -0.1682 |
10 yr T coupon | 0.4907 | 0.7460 | 0.8773 | 0.9455 | 0.9803 | 1.0000 | 0.9953 | 1.0134 | 1.0830 |
Table 1: Asset Programs
Program name | Type of securities being purchased | Program effects on SOMA Size of program | Program effects on SOMA Composition over life of program | Program effects on SOMA Maturity | Date announced | Date operations began | Date operations ended |
LSAP I | Treasury securities, agency debt, agency MBS | "Up to" $200 billion in agency debt, $300 billion in Treasury securities, and $1.25 trillion in agency MBS | Share of agency securities increased from zero to 68 percent | Maturity of portfolio lengthened | Nov-08 | Nov-08 | Jun-10 |
Reinvestments into Treasuries | Treasury securities | Maintained size of SOMA | 30 percent increase in Treasury securities, share of agency MBS decreased 20 percent.* | Treasuries remained steady, MBS maturity lengthened | Aug-10 | Aug-10 | Sep-11 |
LSAP II | Treasury securities | Increased size of SOMA by about $600 billion | Share of Treasury securities increased from 50 percent to 62 percent. | Maturity slightly shortens | Nov-10 | Nov-10 | Jun-11 |
Reinvestments into Agency MBS | Agency MBS | Maintained size of SOMA | Share of agency MBS slightly increases | Maturity of portfolio lengthened | Sep-11 | Sep-11 | Ongoing |
MEP | Treasury securities | $400 billion of shorter-term Treasury securities sold, $400 billion of longerterm Treasury securities purchased | Weighted average maturity of Treasury portfolio increases from 70 months in mid-2011 to 100 months by mid-2012. | Maturity of portfolio lengthened | Sep-11 | Sep-11 | Jun-12 |
MEP II | Treasury securities | $267 billion of shorter-term Treasury securities sold or redeemed, $267 billion of longer-term Treasury securities purchased | Weighted average maturity of Treasury portfolio increases from 70 months in mid-2011 to 120 months by end of 2012. | Maturity of portfolio lengthened | Jun-12 | Sep-11 | Dec-12 |
* Share of Treasury securities also include reinvestments from agency debt.
Table 2 - Assumptions
FOMC policy | Date of projection | Lift-Off | Roll-Off | MBS Sales |
LSAP I: Immediately prior to LSAP I | Oct-08 | N/A | N/A | N/A |
LSAP I: Announcement of extension of LSAP I | Apr-09 | Jun-10 | N/A | Dec-10 |
Treasury Security reinvestments: Immediately prior to reinvestments into Treasuries | Jun-10 | Oct-10 | N/A | Apr-11 |
Treasury Security reinvestments: Announcement of reinvestments into Treasuries | Sep-10 | Jun-11 | Dec-10 | Dec-11 |
LSAP II: Announcement of LSAP II | Nov-10 | Dec-11 | Jun-11 | Jun-12 |
MEP and MBS reinvestments: Immediately prior to reinvestments into MBS | Aug-11 | Oct-13 | Apr-13 | Apr-14 |
MEP and MBS reinvestments: Announcement of reinvestments into MBS | Sep-11 | Oct-13 | Apr-13 | Apr-14 |
MEP and MBS reinvestments: Announcement of MEP | Sep-11 | Oct-13 | Apr-13 | Apr-14 |
MEP II: Immediatley prior to extension of MEP | Jun-12 | Dec-13 | Jun-13 | Jun-14 |
MEP II: Announcement of MEP extension | Jun-12 | Dec-13 | Jun-13 | Jun-14 |
Table 3 - Publication Dates of Data Sources
FOMC policy | Blue Chip Interest Rates Short-term* | Blue Chip Interest Rates Long-term | Blue Chip real GDP growth Short-term | Blue Chip real GDP growth Long-term | CBO Forecast Fiscal Year |
LSAP I: Immediately prior to LSAP I | Nov-08 | Jun-08 | Nov-08 | Jun-08 | 2009 |
LSAP I: Announcement of extension of LSAP I | Apr-09 | Jun-09 | Apr-09 | Jun-09 | 2009 |
Treasury Security reinvestments: Immediately prior to reinvestments into Treasuries | Jun-10 | Jun-10 | Jun-10 | Jun-10 | 2009 |
Treasury Security reinvestments: Announcement of reinvestments into Treasuries | Sep-10 | Dec-10 | Sep-10 | Dec-10 | 2010 |
LSAP II: Announcement of LSAP II | Dec-10 | Dec-10 | Dec-10 | Dec-10 | 2011 |
MEP and MBS reinvestments: Immediately prior to reinvestments into MBS | Sep-11 | Dec-11 | Sep-11 | Dec-11 | 2011 |
MEP and MBS reinvestments: Announcement of reinvestments into MBS | Sep-11 | Dec-11 | Sep-11 | Dec-11 | 2011 |
MEP and MBS reinvestments: Announcement of MEP | Sep-11 | Oct-11 | Sep-11 | Oct-11 | 2011 |
MEP II: Immediatley prior to extension of MEP | Jun-12 | Jun-12 | Jun-12 | Jun-12 | 2012 |
MEP II: Announcement of MEP extension | Jun-12 | Jun-12 | Jun-12 | Jun-12 | 2012 |
* Short term is defined as 6 quarters.
Table 4 - Dates for Key Balance Sheet projections
FOMC policy | Date | Reserves = $25B | MBS = 0 | Treasury bills are 1/3 of portfolio |
LSAP I | Apr-09 | Oct-12 | Nov-14 | Apr-13 |
Reinvestment into Treasury securities | Sep-10 | Jun-13 | Nov-15 | Feb-14 |
LSAP II | Nov-10 | Jan-15 | May-16 | Dec-15 |
Reinvestment into Agency MBS securities | Sep-11 | Apr-16 | Mar-18 | Feb-17 |
MEP | Sep-11 | Jan-17 | Mar-18 | Jan-18 |
MEP II | Jun-12 | Aug-17 | May-18 | Aug-18 |
Table 5 - TPE estimates at inception of the asset program
FOMC policy | Marginal TPE from program | TPE at onset of program (basis points) | Expected TPE as of 2013:Q1 |
LSAP I | -38 | -38 | -6 |
Reinvestment into Treasury securities | -8 | -30 | -9 |
LSAP II | -13 | -40 | -14 |
Reinvestment into Agency MBS securities | -3 | -48 | -30 |
MEP | -17 | -64 | -44 |
MEP II | -11 | -65 | -54 |
Notes: *Evolution of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet assuming no asset programs.
Scenario | Immediately prior to LSAP I Annualized Percentage Rates | Annoucement of extension of LSAP I Annualized Percentage Rates | Immediately prior to reinvestments into Treasuries Annualized Percentage Rates | Annoucement of reinvestments into Treasuries Annualized Percentage Rates | Annoucement of LSAP II Annualized Percentage Rates | Immediately prior to reinvestments into MBS Annualized Percentage Rates | Annoucement of Reinvestments into MBS Annualized Percentage Rates | Annoucement of MEP Annualized Percentage Rates | Announcement of MEP II Annualized Percentage Rates |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Short-term Blue Chip Forecast | Nov-08 | Apr-09 | Jun-10 | Sep-10 | Dec-10 | Sep-11 | Sep-11 | Oct-11 | Jun-12 |
Long-term Blue Chip Forecast | Jun-08 | Jun-09 | Jun-10 | Dec-10 | Dec-10 | Dec-11 | Dec-11 | Dec-11 | Jun-12 |
Dec-08 | -0.44 | -8.71 | -8.71 | -8.71 | -8.71 | -8.71 | -8.71 | -8.71 | -8.71 |
Mar-09 | 0.69 | -5.34 | -5.34 | -5.34 | -5.34 | -5.34 | -5.34 | -5.34 | -5.34 |
Jun-09 | 2.14 | 1.69 | -1.14 | -1.14 | -1.14 | -1.14 | -1.14 | -1.14 | -1.14 |
Sep-09 | 3.35 | 3.07 | 1.92 | 1.92 | 1.92 | 1.92 | 1.92 | 1.92 | 1.92 |
Dec-09 | 3.90 | 3.76 | 4.80 | 4.80 | 4.80 | 4.80 | 4.80 | 4.80 | 4.80 |
Mar-10 | 4.50 | 4.16 | 5.41 | 5.41 | 5.41 | 5.41 | 5.41 | 5.41 | 5.41 |
Jun-10 | 5.00 | 4.10 | 4.25 | 5.32 | 5.32 | 5.32 | 5.32 | 5.32 | 5.32 |
Sep-10 | 5.00 | 4.40 | 4.42 | 3.11 | 3.81 | 3.81 | 3.81 | 3.81 | 3.81 |
Dec-10 | 5.00 | 4.60 | 4.48 | 3.56 | 3.60 | 4.10 | 4.10 | 4.10 | 4.10 |
Mar-11 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 4.67 | 4.08 | 4.00 | 3.06 | 3.06 | 3.06 | 3.06 |
Jun-11 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 4.73 | 4.20 | 4.08 | 3.90 | 3.90 | 3.90 | 3.90 |
Sep-11 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 4.93 | 4.54 | 4.52 | 3.75 | 3.75 | 3.75 | 3.75 |
Dec-11 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 4.90 | 4.74 | 4.70 | 3.91 | 3.91 | 3.76 | 3.76 |
Mar-12 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 4.07 | 4.07 | 3.96 | 3.96 |
Jun-12 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 4.35 | 4.35 | 4.21 | 3.99 |
Sep-12 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 4.68 | 4.68 | 4.53 | 4.43 |
Dec-12 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.68 | 4.40 |
Mar-13 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 4.92 | 4.35 |
Jun-13 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 4.62 |
Sep-13 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 4.98 |
Dec-13 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 | 5.20 |
Mar-14 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 |
Jun-14 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 |
Sep-14 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 |
Dec-14 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.10 | 5.00 |
Mar-15 | 5.10 | 5.30 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.20 |
Jun-15 | 5.10 | 5.30 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.20 |
Sep-15 | 5.10 | 5.30 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.20 |
Dec-15 | 5.10 | 5.30 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.00 | 5.20 |
Mar-16 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 5.10 |
Jun-16 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 5.10 |
Sep-16 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 5.10 |
Dec-16 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 4.90 | 5.10 |
Mar-17 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 5.00 |
Jun-17 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 5.00 |
Sep-17 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 5.00 |
Dec-17 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 5.00 |
Mar-18 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.90 |
Jun-18 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.90 |
Sep-18 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.90 |
Dec-18 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.90 |
Mar-19 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |
Jun-19 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |
Sep-19 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |
Dec-19 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |
Mar-20 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |
Jun-20 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |
Sep-20 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |
Dec-20 | 5.10 | 5.00 | 4.80 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.70 | 4.60 |