The volatility of aggregate economic activity in the United States decreased markedly in the mid eighties. The decrease involved several components of GDP and has been linked to a more stable economic environment, identified by smaller shocks and more effective policy, and a diverse set of innovations related to inventory management as well as financial markets. We document a negative relation between the volatility of GDP and some of its components and one such financial development: the emergence of mortgage-backed securities. We also document that this relationship changed sign, from negative to positive, in the early 2000's.
The volatility of aggregate economic activity in the United States decreased in the mid eighties. The consensus date for a significant decrease, termed The Great Moderation by Stock and Watson (2003), is the last quarter of 1984. Three broad reasons have been suggested to explain this phenomenon: a structural change in the economy, an improvement in the implementation of economic policy, especially monetary policy, and a lucky draw in the sequence of random shocks that affect the economy. These explanations are not mutually exclusive, and can well interact with one another. A challenge has been to identify more precisely which channels of transmission from shocks to economic activity have been affected and how. Among the channels that have received much attention are monetary policy, technological change and especially inventory management, financial markets development, and international integration. Again, focusing on one aspect is dictated by convenience at some level; the idea that the decrease in volatility is diffuse across several components and therefore is not likely to be completely explained by one event is clearly expressed by Kim, Nelson and Piger (2004) and Stock and Watson (2003), among others.
We establish a link between a particular form of financial market development, the process of securitization of mortgage debt, and real economic activity. There are several reasons to focus on such an aspect of the evolution of financial markets over the last thirty to forty years. First, mortgage backed securities (MBS) markets were small as a fraction of GDP in the late seventies, but have become enormous in present days, and the timing of the market development is consistent with the timing of the Great Moderation. By the early 2000's, about sixty percent of household mortgages had been securitized. Because household mortgage debt is almost the size of GDP, the mortgage-backed securities market grew from a relatively small fraction to over half of GDP in about twenty years. It is therefore an interesting question to document whether real effects are detectable in aggregate real variables. Second, mortgage backed securities have a direct link to an important household decision, the purchase of a house, and lenders' decisions to finance the purchase. Thus, the evidence that we document points (indirectly) to the possibility that the availability of risk diversification through mortgage pools generated a smoother allocation of credit and thereby acted as a coordination mechanism for the supply side as well. This channel of transmission does not rely on or require that financial innovation be related to the quantity of credit available or to the relaxation of credit constraints. Third, mortgage backed securities allow for the diversification of different kinds of risks, in particular interest rate risk and credit risk. The credit risk or counterparty risk inherent in mortgage loans has been historically relatively low, in part because of the collateral and the fractional support of the house purchase, in part because the amount of counterparty risk is to a large extent under the control of the lender. Interest rate risk, on the other hand, is largely aggregate in nature, and not easily diversifiable by the lender. Diversification of prepayment risk is, initially, the main purpose of the creation of pools. The idea that both credit risk and interest rate risk are pooled in mortgage backed securities is important, because when one considers the potential effects of introducing a market for financial derivatives that create risk-diversification possibilities that were previously unavailable, there are at least two effects to consider. The diversification of prepayment risk could increase the resilience of intermediaries to shocks, but also increase the amount of counterparty risk that they are willing to undertake. Indeed, one of the hypothesis that we consider is that in the aggregate mortgage backed securities were associated with a decrease in aggregate volatility until about 2000, but that in the last part of the sample the relation changed sign and higher volatility is related to the growth of mortgage securities markets. A corollary of this hypothesis is that even if financial market developments contributed to the Great Moderation, their contribution could have been temporary, to the point of not only fading away over time but change direction. In light of the recent history, focusing on a transmission mechanism that highlights the potential temporary nature of changes in volatility seems particularly relevant. Finally, the structure of the mortgage pools market, which was completely dominated by agency and government sponsored enterprises until the early to mid nineties, allows us to test whether pools issued by government sponsored enterprises and private intermediaries were linked in different ways to aggregate economic activity.
We study the empirical relation between the volatility of economic activity and MBS markets between 1976 and 2011 using quarterly observations on GDP and some of its components and quarterly observations on MBS issued by government sponsored enterprises (GSE's) and private intermediaries. In particular, we construct various measures of volatility for the growth rates of real GDP, consumption, housing consumption, residential investment, and investment in single housing, and then examine the empirical relation between real and financial variables with two statistical models: a linear autoregressive model first and non-linear, Markov switching model next. Empirical evidence is supportive of a negative relationship between issuance of mortgage-backed securities and the volatility of real activity in the first part of the sample, between the mid seventies and roughly 2000; in the second part of the sample the relationship is to some extent reversed, and volatility in real economy growth is positively related to volumes in MBS markets.
The Great Moderation was identified by a set of papers by Kim and Nelson (1999), McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000), and Blanchard and Simon (2001); Stock and Watson (2003) provide a comprehensive review of this large literature and analysis of the phenomenon.1 These papers document a break in volatility in the mid eighties, and attribute it to smaller shocks, better implementation of monetary policy, and structural changes in the economy, especially related to technology and financial-market innovation. A particular aspect, for example stressed by Blanchard and Simon (2001), and Bernanke (2004), is the role played by a decrease in the variability of inflation during the Great Moderation, thus establishing a strong link between aggregate volatility monetary policy implementation. Financial-market development is discussed by Dynan, Elmendorf, and Sichel (2005); although they do not consider a specific form of financial innovation, they conclude that financial market developments played an important role in the Great Moderation. A type of analysis closer in spirit to ours, in the sense that it attempts to link the Moderation mainly to a single economic factor, is Kahn, McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2002). They analyze the role of inventories, and point to the technological innovations that allowed for a structural change in inventory management. Blanchard and Simon (2001) already note a reversion in the correlation between inventories and sales in the nineties; Kahn et al. (2002) go on to notice that much of the Great Moderation can be explained by a reduction in the variability in the production of durable goods, and that this reduction is not accompanied by a reduction in the volatility of sales of durable goods. A follow-up paper, Ramey and Vine (2003), however, points out that for the case of the auto industry, the explanation of the decrease in industry-output volatility is due to a structural change of the sale process rather than technical changes in inventory or production management. These ideas are in a way similar to and consistent with our approach: there is a structural change in the way a market works that leads to decreased volatility, and this change can be traced to more than one factor; we just use financial markets instead of durable goods markets.
There are two recent papers that are directly linked to our analysis. The first is Den Haan and Sterk (2010) which looks at a specific consequence of financial innovation, the reduction in credit constraints. Although they conclude that the alleviation of credit constraints does not seem to be correlated with reduction in volatility of real economic activity, Den Haan and Sterk (2010) find that the shift in who holds the economy's mortgage debt, from banks to other institutions, does seem to play an important role. Of course, the shift was a consequence of the securitization process of mortgages. The second paper is Bezemer and Grydaki (2012) who show with a multivariate GARCH approach that mortgage lending played an important role in the Great Moderation. Finally, two papers analyze the role of investment. Justiniano and Primiceri (2008) point to investment as the main variable whose change can explain the moderation in the volatility of aggregate output. Peek and Wilcox (2006), with a different methodology, consider residential investment and mortgage pools and find that securitization played an important role in the reduction of the volatility of residential investment. The important message that emerges from these papers is that to see reduction in the volatility of output it is also essential to see reduction in the volatility of investment, not surprisingly, and that this reduction can be brought about indirectly, and not necessarily through direct shocks. The change in volatility, in other words, is diffuse and systemic.
We use five series from the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) to measure the change in volatility of economic activity. These are quarterly observations on the seasonal adjusted annual growth rates of real gross domestic product, real personal consumption, real consumption of housing services, real residential investment, and real single family residential investment. The full sample under consideration goes from the first quarter of 1974 to the second quarter of 2011.2 We employ personal housing consumption and investment in single-family homes in addition to aggregate variables because these variables correspond more closely to the financial derivatives that we consider. Specifically, we consider mortgage-backed securities issued by government-sponsored enterprises and over the full sample period, and mortgage-backed securities issued by private conduits from the fourth quarter of 1984 to the end of our sample. Observations about mortgage pools come from the Flow of Funds of the United States.
We consider only mortgage pools composed of single-family mortgages. This is by far the biggest component in the mortgage pools, much larger than multifamily and commercial pools (which are of course not held by government-sponsored enterprises) and is the aggregate for which most consistent observations are available throughout the sample.
Mortgage debt, as a fraction of GDP, was about 28 percent in 1974, and it has increased to about 68 percent in 2011 after a peak of about 78 percent in 2009. The total increase in the weight of mortgage debt over GDP is mirrored by the emergence of mortgage pools. The fraction of mortgages pooled in mortgage-backed derivatives by government-sponsored enterprises (GSE's) out the total amount of (single-family) mortgage debt outstanding was slightly below 10 percent in 1974, to reach 56 percent in 2011. Mortgage pools issued by other financial institutions (i.e. not GSE's) constituted about 1 percent of all single-family mortgages in 1988, and the size of the market was negligible before then. By the end of the sample period this share had increased to 11 percent. Thus, the size of all mortgage-backed securities market went from practically negligible in the early seventies to well over two thirds of single-family mortgages in about thirty years. Figures 1 and 2 give a graphic overview of the evolution of these markets.
The main differences between mortgages in GSE's pools versus other pools concern size of the underlying loans and quality of the borrowers. GSE's are limited by regulation to create pools only with smaller mortgages (the current upper limit is $417,000 per mortgage loan) and to borrowers with high credit scores. Other institutions do not face these limits. Their pools, which we will refer to as asset backed securities (ABS) pool, are composed by mortgage loans that are characterized as jumbo, sub-prime, or alt-A. The first label refer to the size of the loan,
the second to the quality of the borrower and the third to loans that could in principle qualify for purchase by a GSE but because of some limitations not directly imputable to size and credit score, were not held by GSE's. Thus, at the level of the aggregate economy, the main difference between GSE's and non-GSE's mortgage pools is that the latter are designed to pool a potentially larger amount of credit risk. Both financial instruments pool interest rate risk.Because of the explosive growth of MBS markets, we normalize its size and perform several stationarity tests on the resulting series. In particular, we normalize mortgage-backed securities pools, which are denominated in nominal terms in the Flow of Funds observations, in two ways: first, we express each series as a fraction of the total single-family mortgage debt outstanding (Figure 1); second, we use the average house price as a normalizing variables. We obtain average single-family house prices from the Census Bureau. Essentially, the normalization of outstanding mortgage-backed securities with average house prices supplies a (rough) measure of the average number of houses for which the "insurance coverage" is provided by mortgage pooling.
For both GSE and ABS pools we use both normalizations, by mortgage pools and house prices, throughout the analysis.
For each of the five NIPA variables (real growth of GDP, personal consumption, consumption of housing services, residential investment, single-family residential investment) we construct four measures of volatility. One is commonly used in the literature and consists of the rolling standard
deviation of a series using a twenty-quarter window (). This is the measure used, for example, by Blanchard and Simon (2001) and Stock and Watson (2003). We then compute two realized
volatility measures. Denote the growth rate of variable , we first run the
following regression
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
Figures 3 to 7 give a visual representation of the different volatility measures for each of the variables in the NIPA accounts used in the paper: the deseasonalized real growth rates GDP, consumption, consumption of housing services, residential investment, and investment in single housing. The graphs are similar to others in this literature (see for example Blanchard and Simon, 2001), and it is clearly visible a drop in volatility of GDP growth starting in 1984. It is also noticeable that volatility picks up, though at a reduced rate from a historic point of view, after 2000. Note that the pattern of GDP is repeated by the two residential investment measures employed, whereas consumption measure are historically much more stable, and show correspondingly a lower change in volatility both in 1984 and 2000 relative to GDP. It is also interesting to note the different magnitudes and variabilities of the volatility estimates. GDP volatility ranges between 1.4 and 7.2 percent across the different
measures5; consumption volatility, for both consumption and consumption of housing services, is lower and ranges between 1.1 and 5.4 percent. Real residential investment and real investment in single housing exhibit a much higher variability (between 3 and 114 percent) indicating that the volatility of these variables is itself very volatile.The next step that we perform is to formally investigate the empirical relationships between the volatility of real variables and mortgage-backed securities.
We analyze the relationship between the volatility of real variables and mortgage-backed securities with two empirical approaches. First, we estimate a linear model where we regress the different volatility measures of real variables described above, on mortgage-backed security variables (MBS and ABS). Here we assume that the sample period is divided in two sub-periods. For GSE securities, the first sub-sample runs from 1974-Q1 to 2003-Q4 and the second from 1999-Q1 to 2011-Q2. For ABS, the first sub-sample starts in 1984-Q4, and before that the size of the market is negligible. The two sub-samples correspond to a decline
and to an increase in the volatility of the macro variables considered.6 In the first sub-period we expect to find a negative relationship between real variables and mortgage-backed securities - i.e. MBS should reduce the volatility of real variables; in the second sub-period we expect mortgage-backed securities to increase volatility levels of real variables.For the linear approach, we need to make sure that our variables are stationary.7 We, therefore, perform four stationarity tests, the generalized least squares Dickey-Fuller (DF) test proposed by Elliott, Rothenberg, and Stock (1996), the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, the Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin (KPSS) test, and the Phillips-Perron (PP) test, for each variable and each sub-sample. The results are displayed in Table 11 in the Appendix. Stationarity is often a philosophical issue more than a substantive one and it strongly depends on the selected sample. We consider a variable to be stationary - i.e. I(0) - if at least two out of the four tests indicate that the variable is stationary (either by rejecting the null of non-stationarity, as for the DF, ADF and PP tests, or by failing to reject the null of stationarity, as in the KPSS test). Our data run over a relatively short time period (GSE emerged in the second half of the '80s). Therefore, we are generous with our critical values which we set at twenty percent level.
In a second approach, we postulate a non-linear relationship and estimate a Markov-switching model in which we assume that there are two possible regimes: one in which real variables are characterized by high volatility and one in which real variables are characterized by low volatility. We first estimate transition probabilities assuming that they are constant. Then, we estimate the model allowing the transition probabilities to be time varying as function of mortgage-backed securities. Stabilizing effects consist of increasing the probability of transitioning in the low-volatility state and/or decreasing the probability of leaving it. A change in transition probabilities with different sign would denote a destabilizing effect. In what follows we describe the linear and non-linear model and discuss the estimation results.
We estimate the following equation for each variable that survives the stationarity tests:
(4) |
Tables 1 - 5 display the results (missing estimated parameters indicate that at least one of the variable is not stationary).11 Table 1 shows that, in the first sub-period (1974-2003), GSE is reducing the volatility of GDP. ABS, in the second sub-period (1984 - 2003) also reduces GDP volatility levels. In the third sub-period, both GSE and ABS increase GDP volatility.These results are confirmed by Table 2, which refers to the volatility of real consumption. In Tables 1 and 2, the estimated parameters are strongly significant and have negative signs in the first two sub-periods and positive signs in the last sub-period. We interpret the difference in lag-length as a statistical artifact. In fact, we report results for the optimal lag. Our main findings, however, hold for a range of lag-lengths. Table 3 reports the results for the volatility of Real Consumption of Housing Services. In sub-periods one and two, GSE and ABS reduce volatility levels. In the third sub-period, however, ABS is increasing volatility, as expected, while GSE is decreasing volatility. Although this result may seem counter intuitive, it can be explained by the behavior of housing consumption. In fact, how we shall see in the next sub-section, low activity in the housing market is concentrated during recessions and, consequently, the volatility of housing consumption behaves inversely with respect to the volatility of the other real variables we consider. Table 4 shows estimation results for the volatility of Real Residential Investment. GSE always reduces volatility, while ABS is only marginally significant. Finally, Table 5 shows estimation results for the volatility of Single-Housing Investment. GSE and ABS reduce volatility in the first two sub-periods and increase volatility in the last sub-period. Overall, our linear estimates confirm that MBS reduce volatility of real variables in the first two sub-periods and increased the same volatility in the latest period when the recent sub-prime crisis hit the economy.12
Volatility | Indep. Var. | Coeff. | St.Err. | Lag | |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974 - 2003 | GSEH | -0.242** | 0.130 | -2 | 0.825 |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974 - 2003 | GSEM | -2.816* | 2.137 | -2 | 0.822 |
SD:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | 0.305*** | 0.153 | -1 | 0.970 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.140* | 0.092 | -6 | 0.841 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.340*** | 0.149 | -2 | 0.735 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.450** | 0.243 | -1 | 0.718 |
SD:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | 5.671 | 4.631 | -1 | 0.970 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -4.704*** | 1.993 | -5 | 0.847 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -5.543* | 3.453 | -1 | 0.724 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -10.46*** | 5.165 | -3 | 0.718 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 0.056* | 0.036 | -3 | 0.817 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 0.162** | 0.085 | -1 | 0.809 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | 0.858 | 1.554 | -1 | 0.806 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | 4.016* | 2.917 | -1 | 0.784 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.103*** | 0.044 | -6 | 0.827 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.245** | 0.140 | -10 | 0.802 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 5.219*** | 1.787 | -10 | 0.846 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 7.653 | 4.104 | -10 | 0.799 |
Volatility | Indep. Var. | Coeff. | St.Err. | Lag | |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974 - 2003 | GSEH | -0.221*** | 0.094 | -10 | 0.653 |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974 - 2003 | GSEM | 0.727 | 1.386 | -5 | 0.676 |
SD: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.124 | 0.101 | -8 | 0.925 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.417*** | 0.135 | -8 | 0.838 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.454*** | 0.206 | -8 | 0.596 |
SD: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -2.392 | 2.590 | -8 | 0.925 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -7.307*** | 2.937 | -8 | 0.831 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -9.095** | 5.072 | -6 | 0.595 |
SD:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 0.077*** | 0.018 | -2 | 0.953 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 0.096*** | 0.015 | -2 | 0.870 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 0.128*** | 0.044 | -1 | 0.826 |
SD: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | 3.029*** | 0.799 | -1 | 0.946 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | 2.260*** | 0.915 | -1 | 0.812 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | 3.454** | 1.849 | -1 | 0.785 |
SD: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.095*** | 0.039 | -9 | 0.934 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.120*** | 0.034 | -10 | 0.840 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.173*** | 0.079 | -10 | 0.804 |
SD: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 3.127*** | 1.399 | -10 | 0.932 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 4.122*** | 1.050 | -10 | 0.844 |
: Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 5.158*** | 2.376 | -10 | 0.797 |
Volatility | Indep. Var. | Coeff. | St.Err. | Lag | |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974 - 2003 | GSEH | 0.027 | -9 | 0.838 | |
GSEH | -0.092*** | 0.035 | -7 | 0.772 | |
GSEH | -0.048*** | 0.022 | -4 | 0.387 | |
GSEM | -1.527*** | 0.616 | -5 | 0.835 | |
GSEM | -1.830** | 0.936 | -4 | 0.765 | |
GSEM | -0.461 | 0.450 | -3 | 0.375 | |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.167** | 0.100 | -10 | 0.831 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.189** | 0.112 | -6 | 0.783 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.127* | 0.083 | -7 | 0.431 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -3.855*** | 1.819 | -10 | 0.833 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -3.946** | 2.201 | -6 | 0.782 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -2.682* | 1.633 | -7 | 0.430 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | -0.034*** | 0.011 | -9 | 0.821 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | -0.014* | 0.009 | -5 | 0.811 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | -0.024** | 0.014 | -5 | 0.701 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | -0.013** | 0.007 | -6 | 0.154 |
SD: :Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | -1.670*** | 0.487 | -9 | 0.830 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | -0.711* | 0.458 | -9 | 0.815 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | -0.951* | 0.596 | -7 | 0.699 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEM | -0.538 | 0.554 | -9 | 0.138 |
SD:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.084*** | 0.021 | -9 | 0.835 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.024* | 0.016 | -6 | 0.813 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.037** | 0.019 | -2 | 0.703 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSH | 0.016 | 0.014 | -3 | 0.134 |
SD :Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 3.169*** | 0.673 | -10 | 0.846 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 0.849* | 0.536 | -4 | 0 .814 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 1.074* | 0.651 | -4 | 0.696 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | ABSM | 0.622 | 0.571 | -6 | 0.134 |
Volatility | Indep. Var. | Coeff. | St.Err. | Lag | |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974 - 2003 | GSEH | -1.779*** | 0.797 | -7 | 0.859 |
:Sub-Period 1: 1974 - 2003 | GSEM | -28.64*** | 12.61 | -6 | 0.857 |
SD: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | 2.714* | 1.373 | -5 | 0.979 |
Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | 0.011 | 0.126 | -1 | 0.847 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.658 | 1.206 | -1 | 0.781 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003
|
ABSM | 78.50*** | 36.03 | -5 | 0.980 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | 5.658* | 3.506 | -4 | 0.852 |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | 13.79 | 29.23 | -2 | 1.388 |
We now take a different approach, and instead of postulating the presence of different sub-periods we estimate a regime-switching model over the entire sample. The assumption in this case is that the process described by the dependent variable can shift between two regimes, one of high and one
of low volatility, and that the process followed by the two regimes evolves according to a two-state first-order Markov process. The advantage of this approach is that, unlike the previous case, we need not be concerned with stationarity issues and do not have to partition exogenously the whole
sample period in sub-samples. The disadvantage is that we have to estimate a much larger number of parameters. The specific equation that we estimate is given by
As in the case of the linear model, estimates are broadly consistent across models. (Time lags are also in line between the linear and non-linear specifications.) Moreover, again like in the linear model, estimates pertaining to ABS markets tend to be statistically weaker due to the smaller sample.
Volatility | Indep. Var. | Coeff. | St.Err. | Lag | |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974- 2003 | GSEH | -0.060*** | 0.030 | -9 | 0.956 |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974- 2003 | GSEH | -0.087*** | 0.042 | -7 | 0.930 |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974- 2003 | GSEH | -5.436*** | 2.604 | -8 | 0.472 |
: Sub-Period 1: 1974- 2003 | GSEM | -1.700*** | 0.989 | -10 | 0.956 |
:Sub-Period 1: 1974- 2003 | GSEM | -1.700** | 0.989 | -10 | 0.956 |
:Sub-Period 1: 1974- 2003 | GSEM | 0.461 | 0.450 | -3 | |
: Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | 4.503** | 2.727 | -5 | 0.975 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | -0.187** | 0.095 | -4 | 0.918 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSH | 0.119* | 0.119 | -10 | 0.855 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -4.697* | 3.587 | -4 | 0.444 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | 133.6* | 70.58 | -5 | 0.976 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | ABSM | -7.324*** | 2.787 | -4 | 0.923 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | GSEH | -4.277* | 3.152 | -1 | 0.856 |
:Sub-Period 2: 1984 - 2003 | GSEH | -114.1* | 87.71 | -4 | 0.445 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 5.796** | 3.355 | -3 | 0.435 |
:Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 160.3*** | 74.00 | -1 | 0.361 | :Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | 3.803* | 2.276 | -7 | 0.308 | :Sub-Period 3: 1999 - 2011 | GSEH | -177.3* | 105.8 | -1 | 0.337 |
GSEH (2) | GSEM (4) | ABSH (4) | ABSM (5) | ||
1.910*** | 2.066*** | 2.142*** | 2.240*** | 2.361*** | |
: Standard Deviation | (0.689) | (0.679) | (0.759) | (0.734) | (0.696) |
3.217*** | 3.209*** | 3.197*** | 3.179*** | 3.217*** | |
: Standard Deviation | (0.209) | (0.213) | (0.228) | (0.212) | (0.204) |
5.022*** | 5.000*** | 5.134*** | 5.117*** | 4.962*** | |
: Standard Deviation | (0.556) | (0.544) | (0.566) | (0.624) | (0.555) |
1.683*** | 1.693*** | 1.889*** | 1.721*** | 1.666*** | |
: Standard Deviation | (0.185) | (0.233) | (0.197) | (0.219) | (0.168) |
TVP0 constant | 1.269*** | 1.490*** | 2.143*** | 1.550*** | 1.633*** |
TVP0 constant: Standard Deviation | (0.305) | (0.324) | (0.769) | (0.507) | (0.440) |
TVP0 expl. var. | -0.307* | -1.042** | 0.823 | 0.803* | |
TVP0 expl. var.: Standard Deviations | (0.210) | (0.611) | (0.787) | (0.576) | |
TVP1 constant | 1.669*** | 1.876*** | 2.137*** | 1.787*** | 1.766*** |
TVP1 constant: Standard Deviation | (0.292) | (0.402) | (0.439) | (0.388) | (0.352) |
TVP1 expl. var. | -0.378 | 0.175 | -0.143 | -0.15 | |
TVP1 expl. var.: Standard Deviation | (0.339) | (0.322) | (0.245) | (0.247) | |
Log-likelihood | -2.469 | -2.453 | -2.444 | -2.447 | -2.434 |
GSEH (8) | GSEM (8) | ABSH (8) | ABSM (8) | ||
-0.522 | 0.472 | 0.405 | 0.261 | 0.167 | |
: Standard Deviation | (1.079) | (0.698) | (0.763) | (0.742) | (0.790) |
3.727*** | 3.781*** | 3.735*** | 3.754*** | 3.737*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.210) | (0.199) | (0.203) | (0.205) | (0.206) |
3.085*** | 3.039*** | 3.172*** | 3.032*** | 3.069*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.475) | (0.435) | (0.514) | (0.459) | (0.490) |
1.955*** | 1.929*** | 1.924*** | 1.940*** | 1.937*** | |
:standard deviation | (0.134) | (0.136) | (0.136) | (0.136) | (0.135) |
TVP0 constant | 0.804** | 1.333*** | 1.197*** | 1.781* | 1.457** |
TVP0 constant: standard deviation | (0.418) | (0.439) | (0.647) | (1.176) | (0.829) |
TVP0 expl. var. | -0.539 | -1.945 | 1.541 | 1.023 | |
TVP0 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.477) | (2.097) | (2.192) | (1.324) | |
TVP1 constant | 1.799*** | 2.159*** | 1.914*** | 1.822*** | 1.843*** |
TVP1 constant: standard deviation | (0.252) | (0.443) | (0.352) | (0.284) | (0.291) |
TVP1 expl. var. | 0.937* | 0.445* | -0.411* | -0.358 | |
TVP1 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.600) | (0.322) | (0.292) | (0.293) | |
Log-likelihood | -2.273 | -2.241 | -2.238 | -2.244 | -2.244 |
GSEH (4) | GSEM (4) | ABSH (1) | ABSM (1) | ||
2.926*** | 2.950*** | 2.887*** | 2.947*** | 2.948*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.240) | (0.252) | (0.231) | (0.235) | (0.235) |
0.754*** | 0.756*** | 0.727*** | 0.786*** | 0.829*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.255) | (0.252) | (0.238) | (0.255) | (0.245) |
2.445*** | 2.425*** | 2.425*** | 2.460*** | 2.470*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.161) | (0.169) | (0.162) | (0.163) | (0.164) |
1.278*** | 1.301*** | 1.270*** | 1.294*** | 1.294*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.178) | (0.174) | (0.165) | (0.170) | (0.166) |
TVP0 constant | 1.970*** | 2.407*** | 2.697*** | 2.300*** | 2.262*** |
TVP0 constant: standard deviation | (0.290) | (0.593) | (0.611) | (0.413) | (0.389) |
TVP0 expl. var. | 1.142** | 1.053*** | -0.694*** | -0.624*** | |
TVP0 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.612) | (0.402) | (0.287) | (0.286) | |
TVP1 constant | 1.878*** | 1.370*** | 2.264*** | 2.124*** | 2.523** |
TVP1 constant: standard deviation | (0.584) | (0.565) | (0.838) | (0.749) | (1.407) |
TVP1 expl. var. | 0.910* | 0.689* | -0.539* | -0.898 | |
TVP1 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.690) | (0.455) | (0.397) | (0.755) | |
Log-likelihood | -2.246 | -2.218 | -2.208 | -2.232 | -2.234 |
GSEH (6) | GSEM (5) | ABSH (3) | ABSM (4) | ||
-2.819 | -1.107 | -0.554 | -2.057 | -1.301 | |
: standard deviation | (3.634) | (4.081) | (3.015) | (3.759) | (3.703) |
4.744*** | 4.647*** | 4.754*** | 4.769*** | 4.816*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.961) | (0.924) | (0.909) | (0.963) | (0.983) |
27.97*** | 28.85*** | 27.45*** | 28.44*** | 27.92*** | |
: standard deviation | (2.810) | (3.066) | (2.619) | (3.008) | (2.995) |
7.81*** | 7.819*** | 7.637*** | 7.774*** | 7.752*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.641) | (0.628) | (0.626) | (0.644) | (0.649) |
TVP0 constant | 1.505*** | 1.458*** | 2.103*** | 1.650*** | 1.567*** |
TVP0 constant: standard deviation | (0.292) | (0.301) | (0.607) | (0.383) | (0.344) |
TVP0 expl. var. | -0.139 | -0.935** | 0.358 | 0.169 | |
TVP0 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.185) | (0.524) | (0.290) | (0.251) | |
TVP1 constant | 1.872*** | 2.363*** | 2.424*** | 2.038*** | 2.067*** |
TVP1 constant: standard deviation | (0.290) | (0.485) | (0.548) | (0.376) | (0.406) |
TVP1 expl. var. | 1.164*** | 0.691** | -0.434* | -0.444* | |
TVP1 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.573) | (0.381) | (0.313) | (0.336) | |
Log-likelihood | -4.098 | -4.043 | -4.047 | -4.076 | -4.072 |
GSEH (7) | GSEM (7) | ABSH (4) | ABSM (5) | ||
0.043 | 0.702 | 0.706 | 1.387 | 2.008 | |
: standard deviation | (0.774) | (4.209) | (4.241) | (6.062) | (6.716) |
4.987*** | 4.746*** | 4.584*** | 4.846*** | 4.788*** | |
: standard deviation | (1.289) | (1.254) | (1.280) | (1.274) | (1.295) |
43.24*** | 47.03*** | 46.86*** | 44.86*** | 45.44*** | |
: standard deviation | (4.193) | (5.006) | (5.149) | (4.559) | (4.865) |
10.75*** | 11.40*** | 11.45*** | 10.86*** | 11.03*** | |
: standard deviation | (0.954) | (0.879) | (0.884) | (0.967) | (1.035) |
TVP0 constant | 1.479*** | 1.317*** | 1.748*** | 1.515*** | 1.461*** |
TVP0 constant: standard deviation | (0.275) | (0.298) | (0.539) | (0.315) | (0.293) |
TVP0 expl. var. | -0.538* | -2.144** | 0.328 | 0.223 | |
TVP0 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.346) | (1.197) | (0.298) | (0.288) | |
TVP1 constant | 1.821*** | 2.494*** | 2.180*** | 1.918*** | 1.926*** |
TVP1 constant: standard deviation | (0.276) | (0.589) | (0.484) | (0.302) | (0.313) |
TVP1 expl. var. | 1.605*** | 0.853** | -0.423* | -0.406 | |
TVP1 expl. var.: standard deviation | (0.817) | (0.503) | (0.322) | (0.325) | |
Log-likelihood | -4.475 | -4.416 | -4.410 | -4.451 | -4.450 |
We have shown evidence of a strong and persistent statistical link between the volatility of certain real economic aggregates and financial products that ought to be directly linked to the decision process that leads to the determination of those same variables. The intent of the approach was to "let the data speak" as much as possible. The next step is to attempt to establish a closer link between mortgage backed securities and real variables. This can be done in several ways, but two seem particularly important. One is to look at empirical evidence in a different way, and use loan-level observations in mortgage pools to understand more precisely what risks mortgage pools insured and the extent to which different risks had different emphasis over time. The other is theoretical and would attempt to measure the phenomena discussed in this paper in a general equilibrium model. With regards to the housing market, our results indicate pretty explicitly that it is important to model the housing market and housing finance together to understand the aggregate behavior of the economy. In particular, it is important to model explicitly the behavior of financial institutions with some precision in terms of the risks that financial derivatives are meant to capture and the incentives that financial institutions face. With respect to the more general question of the joint behavior of real and financial variables, our analysis points to a direction of analysis that explores financial products and the risk transfer that they operate jointly with the real variables on which they are written.
This appendix presents tables with summary statistics, the results of the stationarity tests, and the graphs of the (exogenous) transition probabilities estimates from the Markov switching model.
Mean | Median | Max | Min | Std. Dev. | Skew | Kurt. | |
GDP | 3.063 | 3.150 | 16.700 | -7.900 | 3.451 | -0.081 | 5.143 |
SD (GDP) | 3.330 | 2.578 | 5.697 | 1.424 | 1.408 | 0.229 | 1.374 |
(GDP) | 3.301 | 3.210 | 4.064 | 2.574 | 0.427 | 0.195 | 1.656 |
(GDP) | 2.862 | 2.781 | 3.860 | 2.130 | 0.466 | 0.288 | 1.761 |
(GDP) | 3.257 | 2.650 | 7.250 | 1.896 | 1.254 | 1.085 | 3.317 |
CONSUMPTION | 3.322 | 3.550 | 8.800 | -8.800 | 2.735 | -1.067 | 6.113 |
SD (CONS) | 2.706 | 2.464 | 4.092 | 1.142 | 0.871 | 0.156 | 1.667 |
(CONS) | 3.172 | 3.252 | 3.745 | 2.395 | 0.345 | -0.391 | 2.378 |
(CONS) | 2.745 | 2.817 | 3.446 | 1.908 | 0.382 | -0.259 | 2.226 |
(CONS) | 2.673 | 2.575 | 5.373 | 1.849 | 0.653 | 1.530 | 6.220 |
HOUS CONS | 2.708 | 2.750 | 8.000 | -4.500 | 2.435 | -0.255 | 2.930 |
SD(HOUS CONS) | 2.400 | 2.424 | 3.411 | 1.631 | 0.409 | 0.071 | 2.166 |
(HOUS CONS) | 3.168 | 3.167 | 3.600 | 2.432 | 0.213 | -0.607 | 3.703 |
(HOUS CONS) | 2.744 | 2.741 | 3.242 | 2.021 | 0.267 | -0.353 | 2.869 |
(HOUS CONS) | 2.433 | 2.392 | 3.095 | 2.276 | 0.143 | 1.840 | 6.915 |
RESID INV | 4.142 | 3.200 | 87.700 | -55.900 | 19.316 | 0.869 | 6.768 |
SD (RESID INV) | 17.863 | 14.089 | 34.211 | 4.888 | 9.380 | 0.157 | 1.531 |
(RESID INV) | 4.681 | 4.699 | 5.750 | 3.464 | 0.621 | -0.074 | 1.957 |
(RESID INV) | 4.233 | 4.193 | 5.465 | 3.009 | 0.665 | 0.095 | 2.016 |
(RESID INV) | 15.095 | 11.880 | 43.761 | 4.668 | 9.623 | 1.281 | 3.804 |
SING HOUS INV | 6.546 | 4.950 | 153.600 | -65.200 | 28.218 | 1.495 | 9.119 |
SD (SING HOUS INV) | 25.822 | 22.082 | 55.336 | 8.301 | 13.723 | 0.570 | 2.392 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 5.022 | 5.079 | 6.177 | 4.165 | 0.542 | 0.147 | 1.893 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 4.581 | 4.467 | 5.749 | 3.745 | 0.582 | 0.357 | 1.863 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 20.626 | 15.109 | 114.006 | 8.930 | 15.391 | 3.032 | 15.287 |
GSEH | 0.456 | 0.371 | 1.487 | -0.212 | 0.376 | 0.735 | 2.866 |
GSEM | 0.014 | 0.012 | 0.057 | -0.018 | 0.016 | 0.800 | 3.702 |
ABSH | 0.083 | 0.034 | 0.351 | -0.088 | 0.115 | 0.945 | 2.631 |
ABSM | 0.003 | 0.001 | 0.015 | -0.006 | 0.005 | 0.964 | 3.278 |
Mean | Median | Max | Min | Std. Dev. | Skew | Kurt. | |
GDP | 3.177 | 3.300 | 8.000 | -3.500 | 2.157 | -0.290 | 3.629 |
SD (GDP) | 2.452 | 2.336 | 5.255 | 1.424 | 0.918 | 1.714 | 5.363 |
(GDP) | 3.023 | 2.981 | 3.602 | 2.574 | 0.237 | 0.408 | 2.454 |
(GDP) | 2.574 | 2.503 | 3.278 | 2.130 | 0.278 | 0.782 | 2.832 |
(GDP) | 2.489 | 2.346 | 4.012 | 1.896 | 0.466 | 1.394 | 4.458 |
CONSUMPTION | 3.490 | 3.600 | 7.800 | -3.100 | 2.113 | -0.237 | 3.229 |
SD (CONS) | 2.167 | 2.262 | 3.996 | 1.142 | 0.557 | 0.978 | 4.968 |
(CONS) | 3.004 | 3.005 | 3.487 | 2.395 | 0.297 | -0.309 | 2.128 |
(CONS) | 2.575 | 2.589 | 3.161 | 1.908 | 0.334 | -0.143 | 1.950 |
(CONS) | 2.384 | 2.378 | 3.277 | 1.849 | 0.372 | 0.516 | 2.379 |
HOUS CONS | 2.545 | 2.500 | 7.000 | -4.500 | 2.228 | -0.322 | 3.145 |
SD(CONS) | 2.344 | 2.380 | 3.411 | 1.738 | 0.416 | 0.520 | 2.518 |
(HOUS CONS) | 3.106 | 3.094 | 3.600 | 2.432 | 0.225 | -0.242 | 3.593 |
(HOUS CONS) | 2.677 | 2.666 | 3.242 | 2.021 | 0.276 | -0.079 | 2.910 |
(HOUS CONS) | 2.409 | 2.366 | 3.095 | 2.276 | 0.138 | 2.655 | 11.433 |
RESID INV | 3.691 | 3.400 | 24.100 | -21.800 | 9.601 | -0.345 | 3.418 |
SD (RESID INV) | 12.879 | 10.154 | 34.005 | 4.888 | 7.809 | 1.357 | 3.760 |
(RESID INV) | 4.310 | 4.276 | 5.018 | 3.464 | 0.421 | -0.173 | 2.045 |
(RESID INV) | 3.843 | 3.840 | 4.691 | 3.009 | 0.435 | -0.070 | 2.078 |
(RESID INV) | 9.346 | 9.078 | 17.216 | 4.668 | 2.965 | 0.480 | 2.552 |
SING HOUS INV | 4.857 | 5.400 | 55.700 | -34.900 | 14.496 | -0.010 | 4.491 |
SD (SING HOUS INV) | 20.407 | 16.500 | 54.622 | 8.301 | 13.072 | 1.331 | 3.559 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 4.733 | 4.636 | 5.628 | 4.165 | 0.416 | 0.652 | 2.278 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 4.257 | 4.131 | 5.284 | 3.745 | 0.400 | 1.051 | 3.313 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 14.803 | 13.345 | 47.642 | 8.930 | 6.396 | 2.489 | 11.488 |
GSEH | 0.576 | 0.573 | 1.487 | -0.212 | 0.399 | 0.258 | 2.461 |
GSEM | 0.013 | 0.012 | 0.057 | -0.018 | 0.016 | 0.597 | 3.139 |
ABSH | 0.129 | 0.103 | 0.351 | -0.088 | 0.121 | 0.242 | 1.959 |
ABSM | 0.005 | 0.003 | 0.015 | -0.006 | 0.005 | 0.239 | 2.446 |
Mean | Median | Max | Min | Std. Dev. | Skew | Kurt. | |
GDP | 1.924 | 2.350 | 8.000 | -8.900 | 2.963 | -1.278 | 6.444 |
SD (GDP) | 2.412 | 2.404 | 3.577 | 1.521 | 0.684 | 0.507 | 2.040 |
(GDP) | 3.047 | 3.048 | 3.569 | 2.378 | 0.371 | -0.288 | 1.654 |
(GDP) | 2.600 | 2.538 | 3.339 | 1.625 | 0.474 | -0.036 | 1.995 |
(GDP) | 2.782 | 2.512 | 5.418 | 1.815 | 0.866 | 1.324 | 4.332 |
CONSUMPTION | 2.384 | 2.400 | 6.400 | -5.100 | 2.324 | -0.907 | 4.596 |
SD (CONS) | 1.827 | 1.738 | 2.647 | 1.164 | 0.434 | 0.544 | 2.226 |
(CONS) | 2.877 | 2.819 | 3.383 | 2.502 | 0.269 | 0.421 | 2.038 |
(CONS) | 2.450 | 2.367 | 3.217 | 2.031 | 0.324 | 1.050 | 3.078 |
(CONS) | 2.296 | 2.109 | 4.029 | 1.820 | 0.488 | 1.932 | 6.231 |
HOUS CONS | 1.802 | 1.250 | 6.700 | -1.500 | 2.139 | 0.532 | 2.346 |
(HOUS CONS) | 2.108 | 2.121 | 2.443 | 1.729 | 0.177 | 0.030 | 2.634 |
(HOUS CONS) | 3.107 | 3.133 | 3.363 | 2.714 | 0.171 | -0.700 | 2.961 |
(HOUS CONS) | 2.697 | 2.747 | 3.016 | 1.925 | 0.225 | -1.274 | 4.713 |
(HOUS CONS) | 2.399 | 2.400 | 2.563 | 2.267 | 0.070 | 0.467 | 2.898 |
RESID INV | -3.164 | 2.300 | 22.800 | -35.400 | 14.450 | -0.543 | 2.490 |
(RESID INV) | 9.512 | 7.456 | 16.075 | 4.888 | 4.218 | 0.487 | 1.482 |
(RESID INV) | 4.300 | 4.174 | 5.376 | 3.464 | 0.564 | 0.483 | 2.149 |
(RESID INV) | 3.940 | 3.871 | 5.152 | 3.009 | 0.624 | 0.389 | 2.041 |
(RESID INV) | 10.987 | 8.649 | 32.299 | 4.668 | 6.553 | 1.513 | 4.730 |
SING HOUS INV | -4.700 | 1.600 | 72.800 | -64.700 | 24.218 | -0.050 | 4.160 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 15.620 | 11.279 | 32.384 | 8.177 | 8.431 | 0.954 | 2.405 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 4.736 | 4.576 | 5.768 | 4.165 | 0.497 | 0.934 | 2.565 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 4.382 | 4.235 | 5.527 | 3.745 | 0.559 | 0.878 | 2.451 |
(SING HOUS INV) | 19.394 | 14.209 | 93.045 | 9.055 | 14.372 | 3.056 | 15.118 |
GSEH | 0.796 | 0.571 | 3.992 | -1.435 | 1.231 | 0.814 | 3.435 |
GSEM | 0.004 | 0.005 | 0.050 | -0.061 | 0.031 | -0.283 | 2.331 |
ABSH | 0.241 | 0.213 | 1.865 | -1.664 | 0.851 | 0.101 | 2.482 |
ABSM | 0.004 | 0.003 | 0.046 | -0.031 | 0.023 | 0.263 | 2.077 |
For DF, ADF and PP we report the value of the test for the null that the variable is integrated of order one - I(1). DF refers to the Dickey-Fuller test proposed by Elliott, Rothenberg, and Stock (1996). ADF refers to the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test. PP refers to the Phillips-Perron test. KPSS refers to the Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin test. For the KPSS the null is that the variable is stationary - I(0). means rejection of the I(1) null for DF, ADF and PP at least at the 20% level, and failure to reject the null of I(0) for KPSS at least at the 1% level.
Full Sample: DF | Full Sample:ADF | Full Sample:PP | Full Sample:KPSS | 1974-2003: DF | 1974-2003:ADF | 1974-2003:PP | 1974-2003:KPSS | 1984-2003:DF | 1984-2003:ADF | 1984-2003:PP | 1984-2003:KPSS | 1999-2011:DF | 1999-2011:ADF | 1999-2011:PP | 1999-2011:KPSS | |
GDP | -2.87† | -8.09† | -8.09† | 0.17 † | -2.62† | -7.99† | -7.99† | 0.06† | -2.16† | -3.87† | -7.12† | 0.08† | -2.42† | -4.25† | -4.17† | 0.29† |
SD(GDP) | -0.92 | -1.35 | -1.47 | 0.90 | -0.41 | -0.89 | -1.10 | 0.98 | -0.54 | -3.16† | -3.14† | 0.47† | -1.10 | 1.45 | -1.21 | 0.31† |
(GDP) | -1.02 | -1.65 | -2.00 | 0.73† | -0.68 | -1.36 | -1.58 | 0.78 | -0.95 | -3.51† | -3.36† | 0.15† | -0.94 | -0.97 | -1.38 | 0.16 † |
(GDP) | -0.94 | -2.00 | -2.45† | 0.75 | -0.96 | -1.85 | -2.10 | 0.75 | -1.43† | -2.84† | -3.07† | 0.11† | -2.06† | -2.09 | -1.77 | 0.12 † |
(GDP) | -2.15 † | -2.73 † | -2.76 † | 0.71† | -2.02 † | -2.43 † | -2.36 † | 0.76 † | -1.53 † | -3.04 † | -3.24 † | 0.19 † | -2.27 † | -2.60 † | -2.24 † | 0.14 † | CONSUMPTION | -1.45† | -4.06† | -9.28† | 0.17† | -1.27 | -8.90 † | -9.13 † | 0.10 † | -2.90 † | -2.88 † | -7.89 † | 0.13 † | -1.77 † | -2.37 † | -3.37† | 0.48 † | SD (CONS) | -0.94 | -1.49 | -1.50 | 1.14 | -0.72 | -1.18 | -1.18 | 1.15 | -0.31 | -3.05 † | -3.12 † | 0.92 | -1.61 † | -1.70 | -1.34 | 0.30 † |
(CONS) | -1.50 † | -2.07 | -2.09 | 0.92 | -0.96 | -1.49 | -1.74 | 0.99 | -1.07 | -1.56 | -1.64 | 0.74 | -1.04 | -0.97 | -1.30 | 0.28 † |
(CONS) | -1.06 | -2.26 † | -2.65 † | 0.93 † | -1.16 | -2.19 | -2.27 † | 0.91 | -1.55 † | -2.00 | -2.01 | 0.59† | -1.39† | -1.57 | -2.04 | 0.19† |
(CONS) | -2.94† | -3.76† | -3.77† | 0.84 | -2.97† | -3.57† | -3.52† | 0.94 | -2.98† | -3.12† | -3.04† | 0.57† | -1.75† | -2.25† | -2.19 | 0.24† | HOUS CONS | -5.29† | -5.44† | -12.18† | 0.69† | -12.15† | -12.13† | -12.13† | 0.28† | -10.67† | -10.79† | -10.79† | 0.24† | -4.36† | -4.91† | -4.99† | 0.40† |
(HOUS CONS) | -1.07 | -1.96 | -2.13 | 0.62† | -0.98 | -2.05 | -2.12 | 0.47† | -0.79 | -1.38 | -1.38 | 0.89 | -2.46† | -3.10† | -1.90 | 0.17† |
(HOUS CONS) | -2.95† | -3.14† | -3.08† | 0.39† | -2.71† | -2.85† | -2.61† | 0.51† | -1.51† | -1.91 | -2.35† | 0.23† | -1.48† | -1.48 | -1.52 | 0.27† |
(HOUS CONS) | -2.73† | -3.09† | -3.62† | 0.26† | -2.34† | -2.60† | -3.11† | 0.35† | -1.80† | -2.12† | -2.42† | 0.11† | -2.04† | -2.08 | -2.05 | 0.19† |
(HOUS CONS) | -5.94† | -6.05† | -6.08† | 0.42† | -5.25† | -5.39† | -5.42† | 0.42† | -3.46† | -3.98† | -4.02† | 0.24† | -4.15† | -4.28† | -4.30† | 0.18† |
RESID INV | -4.15† | -6.57† | -6.55† | 0.21† | -3.74† | -6.04† | -5.71† | 0.04† | -4.14† | -4.59† | -4.64† | 0.15† | -1.49† | -2.50† | -3.87† | 0.40† |
SD(RESID INV) | -1.15 | -1.42 | -1.26 | 0.98 | -0.71 | -0.94 | -0.49 | 1.02 | -0.23 | -2.62† | -2.70† | 0.81 | -0.30 | -0.17 | -0.04 | 0.73† |
(RESID INV) | -1.22 | -1.19 | -1.40 | 0.61† | -0.85 | -1.05 | -1.16 | 0.89 | -0.78 | -2.07 | -2.03 | 0.48† | 0.13 | 0.21 | 0.61 | 0.86 |
(RESID INV) | -2.00† | -2.05 | -1.91 | 0.54† | -1.84† | -1.97 | -1.83 | 0.83 | -1.29 | -3.02† | -2.94† | 0.36† | 0.56 | 0.09 | 0.15 | 0.86 |
(RESID INV) | -2.62† | -2.61† | -2.58† | 0.69† | -2.39† | -2.38† | -2.36† | 0.89 | -1.00 | -3.41† | -3.43† | 0.48† | 2.07 | 2.31 | 0.02 | 0.77 |
SING HOUS INV | -4.18† | -5.73† | -5.42† | 0.25† | -3.58† | -5.76† | -4.40† | 0.04† | -0.86 | -4.68† | -4.78† | 0.07† | -3.46† | -3.71† | -3.72† | 0.31† |
(SING HOUS INV) | -1.63† | -1.71 | -1.53 | 0.68† | -1.30 | -1.38 | -1.11 | 0.76 | -0.33 | -2.52† | -2.48† | 0.76 | 0.26 | 0.45 | 0.78 | 0.71† |
(SING HOUS INV) | -1.68† | -1.66 | -1.61 | 0.48† | -1.54† | -1.60 | -1.44 | 0.73† | -1.02 | -2.59† | -2.34† | 0.40† | 0.67 | 0.41 | 0.68 | 0.81 |
(SING HOUS INV) | -2.15† | -2.14 | -2.04 | 0.41† | -1.99† | -2.03 | -1.93 | 0.69† | -1.14 | -3.44† | -3.33† | 0.30† | 0.27 | -0.31 | -0.07 | 0.80 |
(SING HOUS INV) | -5.48† | -5.82† | -5.82† | 0.32† | -4.49† | -4.81† | -4.69† | 0.68† | -3.50† | -3.81† | -3.73† | 0.25† | -3.67† | -3.73† | -3.61† | 0.60† |
GSEH | -3.07† | -4.13† | -3.26† | 0.26† | -1.27 | -2.23† | -3.87† | 0.40† | -2.54† | -2.52† | -3.62† | 0.10† | -2.71† | -2.69† | -2.13 | 0.24† |
GSEM | -2.46† | -2.48† | -2.75† | 0.24† | -2.22† | -2.35† | -2.11 | 0.45† | -0.70 | -2.02 | -2.36† | 0.69† | -2.20† | -2.29† | -1.36 | 0.30† |
ABSH | -2.88† | - 3.20† | -2.09 | 0.12† | -2.19† | -2.68† | -2.60† | 0.80 | -2.17† | -3.01† | -3.01† | 0.23† | -1.80† | -1.97 | -1.13 | 0.25† |
ABSM | -3.20† | -3.24† | -2.55† | 0.09† | -3.43† | -3.82† | -3.27† | 0.41† | -3.10† | -3.62† | -3.16† | 0.07† | -2.40† | -2.39† | -1.35 | 0.27† |