The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2013-47 Screen Reader version

Credit-crunch dynamics with uninsured investment risk

Jonathan Goldberg*

Abstract:

I study the effects of credit tightening in an economy with uninsured idiosyncratic investment risk. In the model, entrepreneurs require an equity premium because collateral constraints limit insurance. After collateral constraints tighten, the equity premium and the riskiness of consumption rise and the risk-free interest rate falls. I show that, both immediately after the shock and in the long run, the equity premium and the riskiness of consumption increase more than they would if the risk-free rate were constant. Indeed, the long-run increase in the riskiness of consumption growth is purely a general-equilibrium effect: if the risk-free rate were constant (as in a small open economy), an endogenous decrease in risk-taking by entrepreneurs would, in the long run, completely offset the decrease in their ability to diversify. I also show that the credit shock leads to a decrease in aggregate capital if the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is sufficiently high. Finally, I show that, due to a general-equilibrium effect, there is no "overshooting" in the equity premium: in response to a permanent decrease in firms' ability to pledge their future income, the equity premium immediately jumps to its new steady-state level and remains constant thereafter, even as aggregate capital adjusts over time. However, if idiosyncratic uncertainty is sufficiently low, credit tightening has no short- or long-run effects on aggregate capital, the equity premium, or the riskiness of consumption. Thus my paper highlights how investment risk affects the economy's response to a credit crunch.


Keywords: Incomplete markets, idiosyncratic risk, business cycles, risk-free rates

JEL codes: D52, E44, G11, O16



1 Introduction

This paper studies the short- and long-run effects of a shift from loose credit for firms to tight credit in an economy with uninsured investment risk. I focus on a general-equilibrium link between firms: financial claims issued by one firm can (directly or indirectly) be the asset of another firm. The debtor firm seeks to finance an investment. The creditor firm (which owns the debt perhaps in the form of a bank deposit) holds the other firm's debt in order to finance future investments or as a buffer against a bad shock to its own profitability.

When a firm faces tighter credit conditions, it seeks to decrease its borrowing: in part because it can no longer borrow as much against a given investment and in part because, with tighter credit, some investments are not worth pursuing and hence do not generate collateral. If many firms face tighter credit conditions, they will all seek to decrease their borrowing at the same time. Hence there will be fewer stores of value for other firms to hold.

To explore this linkage between firms and how it affects the economy's response to a credit crunch, I develop a tractable dynamic, general-equilibrium model in which collateral constraints limit the ability of entrepreneurs to hedge idiosyncratic risk. The model illustrates the interaction between idiosyncratic investment risk and limited commitment. In contrast, many papers on uninsured investment risk, including Angeletos (2007), Angeletos and Panousi (2009), Angeletos and Panousi (2011), and Panousi (2012), abstract from borrowing constraints, while many papers on shocks to collateral constraints, including Buera and Moll (2012) and Midrigan and Xu (2012), abstract from uninsured investment risk.

Thus, the paper's main contribution is to characterize the short- and long-run effects of credit tightening in a general-equilibrium model with uninsured investment risk. I emphasize the role of an endogenous decrease in the risk-free rate in determining the effects of credit tightening on capital accumulation, consumption riskiness, and the equity premium.

Preview of the model and results. In the model, firms are run by entrepreneurs and the output of each firm is subject to an idiosyncratic shock. Entrepreneurs can issue state-contingent assets of any maturity, but the set of financial contracts available to an entrepreneur is constrained because, in the event of default, creditors' recovery is limited. This limited-enforcement problem gives rise to collateral constraints. Due to these collateral constraints, taking advantage of investment opportunities requires forgoing insurance. Thus, entrepreneurs require a (private) equity premium.

The shock that I study takes the form of a decrease in creditors' recovery in the event of default. I begin by studying the economy's long-run response. When collateral constraints tighten, entrepreneurs are forced to retain a greater share of their profits. As each entrepreneur shifts to self-financing, he reduces the quantity of financial assets that can be owned by other entrepreneurs to insure against their bad idiosyncratic shocks. This has important general-equilibrium effects: the risk-free rate falls and consumption growth becomes riskier. The equity premium rises, for two reasons: first, credit tightening reduces the share of (risky) profits that entrepreneurs can sell to diversified investors; and, second, because the risk-free rate falls, hedging is more expensive. Correspondingly, the risk-adjusted return to saving falls. This gives rise to an income effect and a substitution effect, and thus aggregate capital decreases if and only if the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is sufficiently large.

I show that if the risk-free rate were constant, as in a small open economy, the economy's response would be qualitatively different. In particular, because the risk-free rate would not fall as entrepreneurs shift to self-financing, the decrease in firms' ability to borrow would lead entrepreneurs to scale back risk-taking. This endogenous decrease in risk-taking would be so large that, in the long run, the riskiness of consumption growth would be unchanged - even though credit tightening mechanically reduces the share of profits that entrepreneurs can sell to diversified investors. The equity premium would still rise, because, for a given investment, an entrepreneur has to bear more risk. However, because entrepreneurs would accumulate safe financial assets, they would be better hedged. Hence, the equity premium would not rise as much as it does when the risk-free rate is endogenous.

This highlights the general-equilibrium effects of the endogenous decrease in the risk-free rate after a shock to collateral constraints. In the long run, the increase in the equity premium is higher than it would be if the interest rate were constant. Moreover, the increase in the riskiness of consumption growth can be accounted for by the decrease in the risk-free rate.

This analysis of the long-run response to credit tightening begs the question of how the economy responds in the short run. I show that there is no "overshooting" in the equity premium: in response to a permanent decrease in firms' ability to pledge their future income, the equity premium immediately jumps to its new steady-state level and remains constant thereafter, even as aggregate capital adjusts over time. One corollary of this result is that if idiosyncratic uncertainty is sufficiently low, credit tightening has no short- or long-run effects on aggregate capital, the equity premium, or the riskiness of consumption. I also show that the absence of overshooting is a general-equilibrium effect. Finally, in the case where the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is equal to one, I show that, in the short run, the increase in the equity premium and the riskiness of consumption caused by credit tightening are larger than they would be if the risk-free rate were unaffected by credit tightening.

3 Model

Time is discrete, indexed by  t\in\{0,...,\infty\}. There is a continuum of infinitely-lived entrepreneurs, indexed by  i. Each entrepreneur runs a firm. There is only one good, used for both capital and consumption.

Technology. In period  t, firm  i has a history of idiosyncratic productivity shocks  s^{i,t}=\{s_{0}^{i},s_{1}^{i},...,s_{t}^{i}\} and invests  k_{t}^{i} in the production technology. In period  t+1, the firm learns productivity  s_{t+1}^{i}. The firm then hires labor  l_{t+1}^{i}. The total output produced in period  t+1 is:

\displaystyle y_{t+1}^{i}=F(k_{t}^{i},l_{t+1}^{i},s_{t+1}^{i}).
 F is a neoclassical production technology. Period  t+1 output net of labor costs is given by:
\displaystyle \pi_{t+1}^{i}=y_{t+1}^{i}-\omega_{t+1}l_{t+1}^{i}.
Firms take the wage  \omega_{t+1} as given. I suppress the dependence of individual variables on the history of idiosyncratic shocks.

Productivity  s_{t}^{i} is independently and identically distributed over  i and  t.

Denote the cumulative distribution function over productivities  s by  P(s). I normalize the expected productivity to be equal to one.

Financial markets. The firm can access financial markets by trading state-contingent promises that pay out conditional on the realization of productivity. At history  s^{i,t}, the firm sells a portfolio of Arrow-Debreu securities that represent a promise to pay  d_{t+1}^{i} next period. Note that the promised payment  d_{t+1}^{i} may depend on the realization of  s_{t+1}^{i}. Because the shocks are idiosyncratic, the proceeds from this sale, in equilibrium, are  \frac{1}{R_{t}}E_{t}\left[d_{t+1}^{i}\right], where  R_{t} is the risk-free interest rate between periods  t and  t+1 and the expectation is taken with respect to productivity  s_{t+1}^{i}.

Although the promises are state-contingent, markets are incomplete because entrepreneurs can renege on payment. In particular, if an entrepreneur reneges, the most that creditors can seize is a fraction  \theta_{t} of the firm's output net of labor costs. This setup nests no ability to borrow (  \theta_{t}=0) and complete financial markets (  \theta_{t}=1). When a firm reneges, the unmet portion of the firm's debt is erased. (When the firm is allowed to issue promises due in more than one period, all future promises by the firm are also erased). Given this, the firms repay in period  t+1 if and only if:

\displaystyle d_{t+1}^{i}\leq\theta_{t}\pi_{t+1}^{i}
By allowing state-contingent promises, I am able to focus exclusively on a single financial friction, the possibility of reneging.2 Note that  \theta_{t} controls both the entrepreneur's ability to finance the firm's investments and his ability to hedge against idiosyncratic risk.

The path of  \theta_{t} is deterministic but potentially time varying. Moreover, there exists a  \tau<\infty such that  \theta_{t}=\theta if  t\geq\tau.

Preferences. I assume that entrepreneurs have Epstein-Zin preferences with constant elasticity of intertemporal substitution and constant relative risk aversion. That is, associated with a stochastic consumption stream  \{c_{t}^{i}\}_{t=0}^{\infty} is a stochastic utility stream that satisfies the following recursion:

\displaystyle u_{t}^{i}=U(c_{t}^{i})+\beta U\left(\mathbb{CE}_{t}\left[U^{-1}(u_{t+1}^{i})\right]\right)
where  \beta<1 and  \mathbb{CE}_{t}(u_{t+1}^{i})=\Upsilon^{-1}\left(E_{t}\left[\Upsilon(u_{t+1}^{i})\right]\right) is the certainty-equivalent of  u_{t+1}^{i} conditional on period-t information.  \Upsilon and  U are given by:
\displaystyle \Upsilon(c)=\frac{c^{1-\gamma}}{1-\gamma} and \displaystyle U(c)=\frac{c^{1-\frac{1}{\epsilon}}}{1-\frac{1}{\epsilon}}.
Note that  \gamma>0 denotes the coefficient of relative risk aversion and  \epsilon>0 denotes the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. As in Angeletos (2007), allowing  \epsilon\gamma\in(0,\infty) permits the forces that operate in this economy to be more clearly elucidated while also nesting the frequently made assumption that  \epsilon\gamma=1.

The supply of labor is inelastic and, in aggregate, equals  L. I normalize  L=1.

Budgets. An entrepreneur's budget constraint at state  s^{t}is:

\displaystyle c_{t}^{i}+k_{t}^{i}-\frac{1}{R_{t}}E_{t}\left[d_{t+1}^{i}\right]\leq\pi_{t}^{i}-d_{t}^{i}
Consumption and capital must not be negative:  c_{t}^{i}>0 and  k_{t}^{i}>0. The right-hand-side of the equation is defined as the entrepreneur's period- t liquid wealth:  w_{t}^{i}\equiv\pi_{t}^{i}-d_{t}^{i}. Note that liquid wealth,  w_{t}^{i}, is equal to "cash on hand" (or "goods on hand," since this is a real economy with a single good), rather than actual wealth, which would reflect the value of firm.

I assume that workers are hand-to-mouth consumers, who live in financial autarky and each period consume their wage.

Equilibrium. The initial condition of the economy is given by the distribution of  \{k_{-1}^{i},d_{0}^{i}\} across firms. An equilibrium is a deterministic interest-rate and wage sequence  \{R_{t},\omega_{t}\}_{t=0}^{\infty}, collections of state-contingent plans for entrepreneurs  \{c_{t}^{i},k_{t}^{i},d_{t}^{i},l_{t}^{i}\}_{t=0}^{\infty} and paths for aggregate levels of debt  D_{t}, consumption  C_{t}, capital  K_{t}, output  Y_{t} and labor  L_{t} such that:

  1. the plans  \{c_{t}^{i},k_{t}^{i},d_{t}^{i},l_{t}^{i}\}_{t=0}^{\infty} maximize the utility of each entrepreneur;
  2. the bond-market clears:  D_{t}=0 for all  t;
  3. the labor-market clears:  L_{t}=L for all  t;
  4. aggregate quantities are determined by individual policies:  C_{t}=\int_{i}c_{t}^{i},  K_{t}=\int_{i}k_{t}^{i},  D_{t}=\int_{i}d_{t}^{i}, and  L_{t}=\int_{i}l_{t}^{i}.
Note that the path for prices and aggregate quantities is deterministic because idiosyncratic uncertainty washes out in the aggregate.

4 Equilibrium characterization

4.1 Partial equilibrium

In the model, profits and labor demand for each entrepreneur are linear in the physical capital owned by the entrepreneur, due to constant returns to scale in technology and the ability to adjust labor demand according to the realization of idiosyncratic productivity:

\displaystyle \pi_{t+1}^{i}=\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})k_{t}^{i} and \displaystyle l_{t+1}^{i}=l(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})k_{t}^{i}
where  \tilde{f}(s,\omega)=\max_{z}[F(1,z,s)-\omega z] and  l(s,\omega)=\arg\max_{z}[F(1,z,s)-\omega z].

Thus, the firm's problem can be written recursively as:

\displaystyle V(w_{t}^{i};t)=\max_{k_{t}^{i},x_{t}^{i},\{w_{t+1}^{i}\}}U(w_{t}^{i}-x_{t}^{i})+\beta U\Upsilon^{-1}E_{t}[\Upsilon U^{-1}V(w_{t+1}^{i};t+1)] (4.1)

subject to
\displaystyle \frac{1}{R_{t}}E_{t}[w_{t+1}^{i}]=\left(\frac{1}{R_{t}}E_{t}[\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})]-1\right)k_{t}^{i}+x_{t}^{i} (4.2)

and, for each  s_{t+1}^{i},
\displaystyle w_{t+1}^{i}\geq(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})k_{t}^{i} (4.3)

In period  t, the entrepreneur chooses how much to consume,  w_{t}^{i}-x_{t}^{i}, and its capital  k_{t}^{i}. These choices determine, through the budget constraint (4.2), the expected value of next-period wealth. The firm also chooses a mapping from next-period productivity to next-period wealth,  w_{t+1}^{i}, that must satisfy the budget constraint (4.2) and the limited-enforcement constraints (4.3).

The (private) equity premium is  \frac{1}{R_{t}}E_{t}[\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})]-1. When this equity premium is positive, the firm faces a three-way tradeoff between insurance, the timing of consumption, and taking advantage of its investment opportunity. On the one hand, increasing capital  k_{t}^{i} increases expected next-period wealth, as shown in (4.2). On the other hand, for any state of the world  s^{i,t+1} for which (4.3) is binding, an increase in capital requires an increase in the amount of next-period period wealth that must be allocated to that state at the expense of either current consumption or the next-period wealth allocated to other states.

If  U^{-1}V is weakly concave, which I will verify below, then the period- t+1 wealth level  \{w_{t+1}^{i}\} will feature some constant level of wealth for every state  s_{t+1}^{i} below a threshold  s_{t+1}^{i*}, and for every state  s_{t+1}^{i} greater than this threshold, wealth will be determined by (4.3). That is,  w_{t+1}^{i} will be equal to the greater of a fixed salary or the minimum wealth level consistent with repayment. I denote the fixed salary by  n_{t}^{i}, so that

\displaystyle w_{t+1}^{i}=\max\left\{ n_{t}^{i},(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})k_{t}^{i}\right\} . (4.4)

Using this intuition, firms' optimal decisions for given prices can be characterized in closed form.
Lemma 1   Given prices, optimal consumption  c_{t}^{i}, capital  k_{t}^{i}, and minimum payoff  n_{t}^{i} are linear in wealth  w_{t}^{i}:
\displaystyle \frac{c_{t}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{c}_{t}  
\displaystyle \frac{k_{t}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{k}_{t}=(1-\tilde{c}_{t})\kappa_{t} (4.5)
\displaystyle \frac{n_{t}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{n}_{t}=(1-\tilde{c}_{t})\eta_{t}  

where
\displaystyle \tilde{c}_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(1+\sum_{\tau=t}^{\infty}\prod_{j=t}^{\tau}\beta^{\epsilon}\rho_{j}^{\epsilon-1}\right)^{-1} (4.6)
\displaystyle \rho_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \mathbb{CE}_{t}\left[\max\left\{ \eta_{t},(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1},\omega_{t+1})\kappa_{t}\right\} \right] (4.7)

and
\displaystyle \{\eta_{t},\kappa_{t}\} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \arg\max_{\eta,\kappa}\mathbb{CE}_{t}\left[\max\left\{ \eta,(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1},\omega_{t+1})\kappa\right\} \right]  
    subject to (4.8)
\displaystyle \frac{1}{R_{t}}E[\max\left\{ \eta,(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1},\omega_{t+1})\kappa\right\} ] \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left(\frac{1}{R_{t}}E[\tilde{f}(s_{t+1},\omega_{t+1})]-1\right)\kappa+1.  

Lemma 1 shows that one can think about the entrepreneur's decision of how much to consume as equivalent to that of an investor choosing how to consume and how much to invest in a risky asset with a risk-adjusted return  \rho_{t}. This risk-adjusted return  \rho_{t} reflects the optimal tradeoff between the expected value and riskiness of next-period wealth. Due to the homotheticity of preferences, the linearity of profits in physical capital, and the linearity of the limited-enforcement problem, the entrepreneur's choices of how much to consume and how to divide savings among physical capital and insurance are linear in the entrepreneur's wealth. Thus, we can write (4.4) as:
\displaystyle \frac{w_{t+1}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}}=\tilde{w}_{t+1}=\max\left\{ \tilde{n}_{t},(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})\tilde{k}_{t}\right\} (4.9)

Equation (4.9) shows how the limited-enforcement problem interferes with insurance and the optimal timing of consumption. In period  t, the financial constraint (4.3) binds for all productivity realizations  s_{t+1}^{i} above a threshold  s_{t+1}^{i*}, which is uniquely determined by:
\displaystyle \tilde{n}_{t}=(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i*},\omega_{t+1})\tilde{k}_{t}.
For productivity realizations below the threshold  s_{t+1}^{i*}, there is full insurance: that is,  c_{t+1}^{i}=\tilde{c}_{t+1}\tilde{n}_{t}w_{t}^{i} for all  s_{t+1}^{i}\leq s_{t+1}^{i*}. Moreover, for these low productivity realizations, the consumption growth rate is undistorted in the following sense: an entrepreneur at history  s^{i,t} is indifferent between (i) an additional unit of consumption next period in states with  s_{t+1}^{i}\leq s_{t+1}^{i*}; or (ii)  \frac{1}{R_{t}}P(s_{t+1}^{i*}) units of consumption in period  t.3

In contrast, for productivity realizations for which the financial constraint does bind, insurance is limited: that is,  c_{t+1}^{i} is strictly increasing in  s_{t+1}^{i} for  s_{t+1}^{i}>s_{t+1}^{i*}. Moreover, for these high productivity realizations, the consumption growth rate is "too high": the entrepreneur would prefer  \frac{1}{R_{t}}\left(1-P\left(s_{t+1}^{i*}\right)\right) units of consumption in period  t rather than an additional unit of consumption next period in states with  s_{t+1}^{i}>s_{t+1}^{i*}.

Correspondingly, when financial constraints bind with positive probability, entrepreneurs require an expected return on physical capital greater than the risk-free rate. The first-order conditions of (4.8) imply that the equity premium is:

\displaystyle \frac{1}{R_{t}}E_{t}[\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})]-1=\frac{1}{R_{t}}E_{t}\left[(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})\left(1-\Upsilon'\left(\frac{\tilde{w}_{t+1}}{\tilde{n}_{t}}\right)\right)\right] (4.10)

Consider an entrepreneur in period  t with history  s^{i,t}. At the margin, increasing capital  k_{t}^{i} by one unit requires an entrepreneur to hold  (1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1}) units of additional wealth next period in any state with  s_{t+1}^{i}\geq s_{t+1}^{i*} in order to satisfy the financial constraint for that state. To do so, the entrepreneur must hold less wealth in states with  s_{t+1}^{i}<s_{t+1}^{i*}.4 However, period- t+1 consumption,  c_{t+1}^{i}, is already higher in states with  s_{t+1}^{i}\geq s_{t+1}^{i*}than in states with with  s_{t+1}^{i}<s_{t+1}^{i*}. Thus,  \Upsilon'\left(\frac{\tilde{w}_{t+1}}{\tilde{n}_{t}}\right)<1 for  s_{t+1}^{i}>s_{t+1}^{*}, and hence the equity premium is positive if financial constraints bind (i.e., if  P(s_{t+1}^{i*})<1).

4.2 General equilibrium

Because shocks are i.i.d. across firms, the period- t market-clearing wage  \omega_{t}=\omega(K_{t-1}) is determined by  L=K_{t-1}E_{t-1}\left[l(s_{t}^{i},\omega(K_{t-1}))\right]. We can then define aggregate capital income in period  t as  \Pi(K_{t-1})=K_{t-1}E_{t-1}\left[\tilde{f}(s_{t}^{i},\omega(K_{t-1}))\right]. By Lemma 1, an entrepreneur's consumption, investment and minimum payoff are linear in his wealth, making the distribution of wealth irrelevant for calculating aggregates. This permits the following recursive characterization of general-equilibrium dynamics:

Proposition 2   In equilibrium, the aggregate dynamics satisfy:
\displaystyle C_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{c}_{t}\Pi\left(K_{t-1}\right) (4.11)
\displaystyle K_{t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{k}_{t}\Pi\left(K_{t-1}\right) (4.12)
\displaystyle \frac{1}{\tilde{c}_{t}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle 1+\frac{1}{\tilde{c}_{t+1}}\beta^{\epsilon}\rho_{t}^{\epsilon-1} (4.13)
\displaystyle 1 \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{c}_{t}+\tilde{k}_{t} (4.14)

where  \tilde{k}_{t} is given by (4.5) and  \rho_{t} is given by (4.7) .
Equation (4.13) would hold in any model for an agent with Epstein-Zin preferences facing a sequence of risk-adjusted returns  \{\rho_{t}\}_{t=0}^{\infty}; in this paper, this sequence of risk-adjusted returns comes from the optimal allocation of savings to capital (which earns a return subject to idiosyncratic risk) and financial assets (which can partially insure that idiosyncratic risk).

Note that this system is recursive in  (K_{t-1},\tilde{c}_{t}). In particular, given  \tilde{c}_{t}, the market-clearing condition (4.14) can be used to determine  \tilde{k}_{t}. Next, equations (4.11) and (4.12) can be used to calculate  C_{t} and  K_{t}. Then the first-order conditions of (4.8) determine  \eta_{t} and  R_{t}, which in turn imply  \rho_{t}. Finally, (4.13) determines  \tilde{c}_{t+1}.

A steady state is a fixed point  (K,\tilde{c}) of the dynamic system (4.11)-(4.14) with  K>0 and  \tilde{c}>0.

5 Steady state analysis

I make the following assumption, as in Angeletos (2007).

Assumption 1.  F(K,L,s)=F(sK,L,1).

Assumption 1 implies that  \tilde{f}(s;\omega(K))=sF_{K}(K,1,1). An example of technology that satisfies Assumption 1 is Cobb-Douglas technology.

Proposition 3 (a)   There exists  \underline{\epsilon}\in[0,1) such that a steady state exists if and only if  \epsilon>\underline{\epsilon}.

(b) If a steady state exists, it is unique. In steady state  \tilde{w}=\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)s\} where  \tilde{n} satisfies:

\displaystyle E[\tilde{w}]=E[\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)s\}]=1. (5.1)

Aggregate capital is then determined by:
\displaystyle F_{K}=\frac{1}{\beta}\left(\mathbb{CE}[\tilde{w}]\right)^{\frac{1}{\epsilon}-1} (5.2)

and the interest rate is determined by:
\displaystyle \beta R=\frac{\left(\mathbb{CE}[\tilde{w}]\right)^{\frac{1}{\epsilon}}}{\left(\mathbb{CE}[\frac{\tilde{w}}{\tilde{n}}]\right)^{\gamma}}\leq1. (5.3)

Also,  \tilde{n}<1 and  \beta R<1 if and only if  P(\frac{1}{1-\theta})<1.
Proposition 3 shows that, in steady state, entrepreneurs bear idiosyncratic risk and the interest rate is less than entrepreneurs' discount rate if and only if there is a positive probability of a sufficiently high idiosyncratic productivity.5 To see why, note that when entrepreneurs borrow, they must keep at least  (1-\theta) share of profits in order to credibly promise repayment. This means that, even when the economy is in a steady state, an entrepreneur's wealth and consumption will grow after a sufficiently high realization of idiosyncratic productivity. However, growth in wealth and consumption after a high idiosyncratic shock is only consistent with a steady state if entrepreneurs' wealth and consumption decrease after a low idiosyncratic shock. Hence, if there is a positive probability of a sufficiently high productivity shock, the interest rate must be less than entrepreneurs' discount rate to encourage entrepreneurs to hedge less against low idiosyncratic shocks.

Hereafter, I will confine attention to economies which have a unique steady state. This is guaranteed by Assumption 2.

Assumption 2. If  P(\frac{1}{1-\theta})<1, then  \epsilon>\underline{\epsilon}\equiv(1+\frac{\log\beta}{\log\mathbb{CE}_{t}\left[\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)s\}\right]})^{-1}, where  \tilde{n} is determined by  E[\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)s\}]=1.

The threshold  \underline{\epsilon} in Assumption 2 is uniquely determined by preference parameters  \beta and  \gamma, the distribution of idiosyncratic productivity  P(s), and the ability of firms to borrow  \theta. The threshold  \underline{\epsilon} does not depend on the production function  F. It can be shown that  \underline{\epsilon}<1 and that  \underline{\epsilon} is increasing in  \beta and  \gamma and decreasing in  \theta.

5.1 Effect of a credit crunch

The characterization of the economy's steady state in Proposition 3 immediately leads to the following result.

Proposition 4   Comparing steady-states for different values of firms' ability to borrow, a decrease in  \theta will lead to:

(a) a decrease in the minimum payoff  \tilde{n} and an increase in the riskiness of consumption; that is, the growth rate of idiosyncratic consumption with  \theta=\theta_{H} second-order stochastically dominates the growth rate of idiosyncratic consumption with  \theta=\theta_{L} if and only if  \theta_{H}>\theta_{L};

(b) a decrease in the interest rate, R;

(c) an increase in the (private) equity premium,  \frac{F_{K}(K)}{R};

(d) a decrease in aggregate capital if and only if the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is greater than one.

These changes will be strict if financial constraints bind in the new steady state.

When there is a decrease in  \theta, firms are forced to retain a greater share of profits in states of high idiosyncratic productivity. For this to be consistent with steady state condition (5.1), entrepreneurs must insure less against low productivity realizations; and (5.3) implies that a decrease in the interest rate is required if entrepreneurs are to save less against low-productivity states.

More specifically, consider the steady states associated with  \theta_{L} and  \theta_{H}, with  \theta_{L}<\theta_{H}, and suppose  P(\frac{1}{1-\theta_{L}})<1, so that financial constraints bind with positive probability in the  \theta_{L} steady state. Denote the productivity threshold above which financial constraints bind in the  \theta_{L} steady state by  s_{\theta_{L}}^{i*}. Then there will be a cutoff productivity  \hat{s}\in(s_{\theta_{L}}^{i*},\infty) such that: for any productivity  s^{i}<\hat{s}, the consumption growth rate in the  \theta_{L} steady state is lower than the consumption growth rate in the  \theta_{H} steady state; for any productivity  s^{i}>\hat{s}, the opposite holds. Hence, it follows that a decrease in  \theta leads to a simple increase in risk in the distribution of consumption growth.

According to (5.2), this increase in the riskiness of consumption leads to a decrease in aggregate capital if and only if the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is greater than one. This is because credit tightening leads to a decrease in the risk-adjusted return to saving, giving rise to opposing income and substitution effects; when the EIS is higher, the substitution effect is stronger.

Using Assumption 1 and (4.10), the equity premium can be written as:

\displaystyle \frac{F_{K}(K_{t})}{R_{t}}=\left[1-E_{t}\left[(1-\theta_{t})s\left(1-\Upsilon'\left(\frac{\tilde{w}_{t+1}}{\tilde{n}_{t}}\right)\right)\right]\right]^{-1} (5.4)

Thus, in the general-equilibrium steady state:
\displaystyle \frac{F_{K}}{R}=\left[1-E\left[\max\left\{ 0,(1-\theta)s\left(1-\Upsilon'\left(\frac{(1-\theta)s}{\tilde{n}}\right)\right)\right\} \right]\right]^{-1} (5.5)

With a shift from  \theta_{H} to  \theta_{L}, for each additional unit of investment, an entrepreneur has to retain a greater share of the upside risk. Moreover, bearing the risk associated with entrepreneurial investment is even less attractive in the  \theta_{L} steady state than in the  \theta_{H} steady state, because, in the  \theta_{L} steady state, the interest rate is lower and it is more expensive to hedge. Hence, as (5.5) shows, a decrease in  \theta leads to an increase in the equity premium.

In the remainder of this section, I will examine how the economy would react differently to a decrease in  \theta if the risk-free rate were held constant, as in a small open economy.

5.2 Understanding the endogenous decrease in the interest rate and its effects

To obtain a clearer understanding of Proposition 4, define a small-open-economy equilibrium as equivalent to the closed-economy equilibrium defined above, except that the bond-market clearing condition is replaced with an exogenously given interest rate.

Using the budget constraint (4.2) and Lemma 1, define the optimal debt policy as:

\displaystyle \frac{d_{t+1}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}}=\tilde{d}_{t+1}=\min\left\{ \tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})\tilde{k}_{t}-\tilde{n}_{t},\theta_{t}\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})\tilde{k}_{t}\right\} (5.6)

The aggregate dynamics in the small-open economy will satisfy:
\displaystyle \begin{bmatrix}C_{t}\\ K_{t}\\ D_{t+1} \end{bmatrix}=\begin{bmatrix}\tilde{c}_{t}\\ \tilde{k}_{t}\\ E_{t}[\tilde{d}_{t+1}] \end{bmatrix}\left(\Pi(K_{t-1})-D_{t}\right). (5.7)

as well as the optimality condition (4.13) and the first-order conditions of (4.8). A small-open-economy steady state is a fixed point of this system with  \tilde{c}>0 and  K>0.
Lemma 5   Suppose  \beta R<1 and  \theta<1.

(a) There exists  \underline{\epsilon}_{soe}\in(0,1) such that a small-open-economy steady state exists if and only if  \epsilon>\underline{\epsilon}_{soe}.

(b) If a steady state exists, it is unique and entrepreneurs are not perfectly insured.

Intuitively, if  \beta R<1 and financial constraints did not bind, then, over time, firms would be decumulating wealth, which is inconsistent with a steady state.6 As in the analysis of the closed economy, I hereafter confine attention to economies that have a unique steady state.

The next result shows how a small-open economy would respond to a decrease in  \theta.

Proposition 6   Suppose  \beta R<1. Consider the effects of a decrease in  \theta, holding the interest rate constant, as in a small open economy. Comparing across steady-states, this will lead to:

(a) no change in the riskiness of consumption growth; the steady-state consumption growth rate  \tilde{w}=\max\left\{ \tilde{n},(1-\theta)sF_{K}\tilde{k}\right\} is unchanged;

(b) a decrease in net leverage,  E[\tilde{d}], and expected profits per unit wealth,  F_{K}\tilde{k};

(c) an increase in the equity premium (and hence a decrease in aggregate capital).

Even though a decrease in  \theta mechanically implies that a smaller share of risky future profits can be sold to diversified investors, Proposition 6 states that a decrease in  \theta leads to no change in the distribution of steady-state consumption growth. The riskiness of consumption growth is unchanged because a decrease in  \theta endogenously leads to a decrease in risk-taking that exactly offsets the exogenous decrease in entrepreneurs' ability to hedge their risks. To see this, consider the steady-state version of the partial-equilibrium result (5.3):
\displaystyle \tilde{n}=(\beta R)^{\frac{1}{\gamma}}\mathbb{CE}\left[\tilde{w}\right]^{1-\frac{1}{\epsilon\gamma}} (5.8)

Clearly, with a constant interest rate, no change in the riskiness of consumption after a decrease in firms' ability to pledge is consistent with (5.8): the certainty-equivalent of the wealth growth rate is unchanged; the interest rate is unchanged; and the minimum payoff  \tilde{n} is unchanged. Intuitively, it is the interest rate that controls how costly it is for entrepreneurs to hedge idiosyncratic risk.

The response of the equity premium to a decrease in firms' ability to borrow, holding the interest rate constant, can then be seen from (5.4). Because the riskiness of consumption is unchanged,  \Upsilon'\left(\frac{\tilde{w}}{\tilde{n}}\right) is unchanged: shifting one unit of consumption from low-productivity states to high-productivity states is equally unattractive before and after the decrease in firms' ability to borrow. Nonetheless, mechanically, for each unit of physical capital that an entrepreneur holds, more consumption must be shifted from low-productivity states to high-productivity states. Correspondingly, the equity premium increases. Hence, aggregate capital decreases unambiguously.

Proposition 6 explains why the risk-free rate falls in a closed economy in response to a decrease in  \theta. Consider a small, open economy with  \beta R<1 and suppose that, in the initial steady state, its current account was in balance. In this small open economy, a decrease in  \theta leads to a persistent current-account surplus. The decrease in leverage,  E[\tilde{d}]=E[\min\{sF_{K}\tilde{k}-\tilde{n},\theta sF_{K}\tilde{k}\}], has a mechanical component and an endogenous one. Mechanically, the decrease in  \theta means that, for high realizations of next-period productivity, the share of next-period profits pledged must decrease, in order to satisfy the limited-enforcement constraint. In addition, the decrease in  \theta leads to an endogenous decrease in expected profits per unit wealth,  F_{K}\tilde{k}. Thus, a decrease in  \theta in the small open economy leads to a decrease in net leverage, which explains why, in the closed economy, the interest rate must fall in response to a decrease in  \theta.

The next proposition is the complement to Proposition 6: that is, Proposition 7 examines how a small-open economy is affected by changes in the risk-free rate.

Proposition 7   Consider the effect of a decrease in the interest rate, holding  \theta constant. Comparing across steady-states, this will lead to:

(a) a decrease in the minimum payoff  \tilde{n} and an increase in the riskiness of consumption growth;

(b) an increase in net leverage,  E[\tilde{d}], and expected profits per unit wealth,  F_{K}\tilde{k};

(c) an increase in the equity premium.

In the small open economy, a decrease in the interest rate, holding all other exogenous variables constant, leads to an increase in the riskiness of consumption growth. The intuition is clearest with standard expected utility, which features  \epsilon\gamma=1. With standard expected utility, the steady-state consumption growth rate for low productivity realizations equals  (\beta R_{t})^{\epsilon}, reflecting the usual tradeoff between consuming  R additional goods next period or one additional good today. Thus, a decrease in the risk-free rate leads to a decrease in insurance against low productivity realizations. In order for this to be consistent with steady state, expected profits per unit wealth must increase. Correspondingly, net leverage,  E[\tilde{d}]=\min\{sF_{K}\tilde{k}-\tilde{n},\theta sF_{K}\tilde{k}] increases as well.

As before, the response of the equity premium to a decrease in the interest rate, holding all other exogenous variables constant, can be seen from (5.4). Because the riskiness of consumption increases,  \Upsilon'\left(\frac{\tilde{w}}{\tilde{n}}\right) decreases: shifting one unit of consumption from low-productivity states to high-productivity states is more painful than before the decrease in the interest rate. Thus, even though there is no change in the amount, per unit of physical capital, of wealth that must be shifted from low-productivity states to high-productivity states, reducing insurance is more painful because of the decrease in the risk-free rate.

6 Transition dynamics

In this section, I study how the economy responds in the short run to the decrease in firms' ability to borrow. In the preceding analysis of the long-run response, I showed that a decrease in firms' ability to borrow leads to an increase in the equity premium and the riskiness of consumption. I also showed that steady-state aggregate capital may increase or decrease in response to a decrease in firms' ability to borrow, depending on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. These results raise a number of questions about the short-run dynamics. For example, one might conjecture that if entrepreneurs accumulate wealth over time in response to credit tightening, then there will be overshooting in the equity premium: the equity premium would shoot up at first, but this initial increase would be partially reversed over time.

6.1 No overshooting of the equity premium

Thus, in this section, I fully characterize the transition dynamics of the equity premium and the riskiness of consumption for any path for  \{\theta_{t}\}. It turns out that, due to a general-equilibrium effect, the equity premium and one measure of consumption riskiness do not display any over- or under-shooting in response to a decrease in firms' ability to borrow.

In this section, I explicitly denote the dependence of steady-state variables on the share of profits that firms are able to pledge in the long run; for example,  K(\theta) is steady state aggregate capital when  \lim_{t\rightarrow}\theta_{t}=\theta.

Proposition 8   At any date t, the equity premium and the coefficient of variation of period- t+1 consumption are the same as in the steady state with firms' ability to borrow equal to  \theta_{t}. More specifically,
\displaystyle \frac{F(K_{t})}{R_{t}}=\frac{F(K(\theta_{t}))}{R(\theta_{t})}
and the cumulative distribution function of  \frac{c_{t+1}^{i}}{E_{t}\left[c_{t+1}^{i}\right]} is the same as the c.d.f. of  \tilde{w}(\theta_{t}).
Proposition 8 implies that, in response to a permanent decrease in firms' ability to borrow, the equity premium and the the coefficient of variation of next-period consumption immediately jump to their new steady-state levels; there is no overshooting. During the transition, aggregate capital,  K_{t}, the minimum payoff,  \tilde{n}_{t}, and expected profits,  F_{K}(K_{t})\tilde{k}_{t}, may be changing, but the equity premium and the coefficient of variation of next-period consumption will remain constant after their initial jump to their new steady-state levels.

Another implication of Proposition 8 is that, at time  t, the future path for firms' ability to borrow,  \left\{ \theta_{\tau}\right\} _{\tau=t+1}^{\infty}, does not affect the period- t equity premium or the coefficient of variation of period- t+1 consumption, although it may affect period- t aggregate capital and consumption.

The absence of overshooting described in Proposition 8 is a general-equilibrium effect. The equity premium, given in (5.4), is greater when idiosyncratic consumption is riskier; that is, when  \frac{c_{t+1}^{i}}{E_{t}\left[c_{t+1}^{i}\right]} is more risky. Thus, the equity premium can overshoot (or undershoot) after a permanent shock only if the riskiness of consumption varies with aggregate capital. However, in the closed economy studied here, this is not possible. Consider a shock to aggregate capital, all else equal: if in response to the shock, entrepreneurs sought to take more risk by increasing leverage, this would lead to an increase in the supply of financial assets, leading entrepreneurs to hedge more and thus contradicting the premise that the aggregate wealth shock leads to more risk taking.

6.2 Understanding the role of the interest rate in the short run

It is interesting to consider the short-run dynamics of the risk-free rate and whether the equity premium and consumption riskiness increase more in the short-run than they would if the interest-rate were fixed. I address this questions for the special case in which the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is equal to one. With an EIS equal to one, the path for aggregate capital is unaffected by the path for collateral constraints and idiosyncratic uncertainty.

Proposition 9   Suppose that  \epsilon=1.

(a) The path for aggregate quantities  \{K_{t},C_{t}\}_{t=0}^{\infty} is unique and converges monotonically to the unique steady state, with  K=F_{K}^{-1}(\frac{1}{\beta}) and  C=(1-\beta)\Pi(K).

(b) Compare two economies, H and L, that are identical in their initial conditions and exogenous parameters, except that  \theta_{\tau}^{H}>\theta_{\tau}^{L}. Then  R_{\tau}^{H}>R_{\tau}^{L} and the period- \tau equity premium in economy L is greater than it would be if the period- \tau risk-free rate in economy L were exogenous and equal to  R_{\tau}^{H}.

Proposition 9 shows that, with the EIS equal to one, a decrease in firms' ability to pledge leads, on impact, to an endogenous decrease in the risk-free rate and that this decrease in the risk-free rate amplifies the concurrent increase in the equity premium. And because the equity premium depends on the riskiness of idiosyncratic consumption growth, Proposition 9 implies that the endogenous decrease in the risk-free rate also leads to greater risk-taking.7 The reason that a decrease in the risk-free rate in period- \tau leads to a larger equity premium in the short-run is similar to the reason that a decrease in the long-run risk-free rate leads to a larger equity premium in the long run. When the risk-free rate is low, hedging is expensive; thus entrepreneurs choose to hedge less and correspondingly they demand a higher equity premium.

7 Conclusion

A number of recent papers have studied the short- and long-run effects of shocks to collateral constraints in models that abstract from uninsured investment risk. At the same time, other papers have studied uninsured investment risk while ignoring borrowing constraints. In this paper, I characterized the economy's response to a shock to collateral constraints in a model with uninsured risk. In the model, credit tightening leads to an increase in the equity premium and the riskiness of consumption. I showed that, both immediately after the shock and in the long run, the equity premium and the riskiness of consumption increase more than they would if the risk-free rate were constant. Indeed, the long-run increase in the riskiness of consumption growth was shown to be a purely general-equilibrium effect: if the risk-free rate were constant (as in a small open economy), an endogenous decrease in risk-taking by entrepreneurs would, in the long run, completely offset the decrease in their ability to diversify. I also showed that the credit shock leads to a decrease in aggregate capital if the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is sufficiently high. Finally, I demonstrated that, due to a general-equilibrium effect, there is no "overshooting" in the equity premium: in response to a permanent decrease in firms' ability to pledge their future income, the equity premium immediately jumps to its new steady-state level and remains constant thereafter, even as aggregate capital adjusts over time. Because the results highlight how changes in the risk-free rate affect risk-taking and the equity premium, it would be useful to extend the model to understand the implications of uninsured investment risk for monetary policy and the optimal level of government debt.

Appendix A: Proofs

Proof of Lemma 1

Define

\displaystyle B(x_{t}^{i};t)=\max_{k_{t}^{i},\{w_{,t+1}^{i}\}}\Upsilon^{-1}E_{t}[\Upsilon U^{-1}V(w_{t+1}^{i};t+1)] (7.1)

subject to (4.2) and (4.3). Using (7.1), we can write (4.1) as:
\displaystyle V(w_{t}^{i};t)=\max_{x_{t}^{i}}U(w_{t}^{i}-x_{t}^{i})+\beta U(B(x_{t}^{i};t)). (7.2)

Conjecture the following solution:
\displaystyle V(w_{t}^{i};t) \displaystyle = \displaystyle U(a_{t}w_{t}^{i}) (7.3)
\displaystyle \frac{c_{t}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{c}_{t}  
\displaystyle \frac{k_{t}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{k}_{t}  
\displaystyle \frac{n_{t}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \tilde{n}_{t}  
\displaystyle \frac{w_{t+1}^{i}}{w_{t}^{i}} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \max\left\{ \tilde{n}_{t},(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i},\omega_{t+1})\tilde{k}_{t}\right\}  

where  a_{t},  \tilde{c}_{t},  \tilde{k}_{t}, and  \tilde{n}_{t} are time-varying but deterministic coefficients to be determined.

From (7.3), we have that

\displaystyle B(x_{t}^{i};t)=\max_{k_{t}^{i},n_{t}^{i}}a_{t+1}^{i}\mathbb{CE}_{t}(\max(n_{t}^{i},(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i};\omega_{t+1})k_{t}^{i})) (7.4)

subject to
\displaystyle E_{t}[\max(n_{t}^{i},(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i};\omega_{t+1})k_{t}^{i}]=E_{t}[\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i};\omega_{t+1})]k_{t}^{i}+R_{t}(x_{t}^{i}-k_{t}^{i}) (7.5)

Dividing the first-order condition with respect to  k_{t}^{i} by the first-order condition with respect to  n_{t}^{i}, one obtains:
\displaystyle \frac{n_{t}^{i}}{k_{t}^{i}}=\left[\frac{E_{t}\left[\max\left\{ 0,(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i};\omega_{t+1})\right\} \right]-\left(E_{t}[\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i};\omega_{t+1})]-R_{t}\right)}{E_{t}\left[\max\left\{ 0,((1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i};\omega_{t+1}))^{1-\gamma}\right\} \right]}\right]^{1/\gamma} (7.6)

where  s_{t+1}^{i*} is defined by  n_{t}^{i}=(1-\theta_{t})\tilde{f}(s_{t+1}^{i*},\omega_{t+1})k_{t}^{i}.

This, together with the linearity of (7.5), implies that the solutions  n_{t}^{i} and  k_{t}^{i} to (7.4)-(7.5) are linear in  x_{t}^{i} and that  B(x_{t}^{i};t) is linear in  x_{t}^{i}. In particular, we have  B(x_{t}^{i};t)=a_{t+1}\rho_{t}x_{t}^{i}, where  \rho_{t} is given by (4.7). Moreover, re-arranging (7.6), one obtains (4.10).

Substituting for  B(x_{t};t) into (7.2), one obtains:

\displaystyle V(w_{t}^{i};t)=U(w_{t}^{i}-x_{t}^{i})+\beta U(a_{t+1}\rho_{t}x_{t}^{i}).
Due to homotheticity, the solution of this problem will be of the form  x_{t}^{i}=(1-\tilde{c}_{t})w_{t}^{i}.

The envelope condition is:

\displaystyle a_{t}^{1-\frac{1}{\epsilon}}=\tilde{c}_{t}^{-\frac{1}{\epsilon}}. (7.7)

Taking the first-order condition, using the envelope condition, and rearranging, one obtains:
\displaystyle \frac{1}{\tilde{c}_{t}}=1+\frac{1}{\tilde{c}_{t+1}}\beta^{\epsilon}\rho_{t}^{\epsilon-1}. (7.8)

Forward iteration of (7.8) implies (4.6).

Finally, to verify (7.3), one must confirm that

\displaystyle U(a_{t}w_{t}^{i})=U(\tilde{c}_{t}w_{t}^{i})+\beta U(\mathbb{CE}_{t}\left(a_{t+1}\tilde{w}_{t+1}w_{t}^{i}\right)).
Substituting from  \rho_{t}=\frac{1}{1-\tilde{c}_{t}}\mathbb{CE}_{t}\left[\tilde{w}_{t+1}\right], where  \rho_{t} is defined as in 4.7, one has

\displaystyle U(a_{t}w_{t}^{i})=U(\tilde{c}_{t}w_{t}^{i})+\beta U(a_{t+1}w_{t}^{i}(1-\tilde{c}_{t})\rho_{t}).
Dividing both sides by  U(w_{t}^{i}) and using the envelope condition (7.7), one obtains (7.8).  \diamondsuit

Proof of Proposition 3

From assumption 1, one obtains  \Pi(K_{t})=F_{K}(K_{t})K_{t}. Setting  K_{t}=K_{t-1}=K in (4.12), one obtains the steady-state condition:

\displaystyle F_{K}(K)\tilde{k}=1. (7.9)

Hence, in steady state,  \tilde{w}=\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)s\} and (5.1) holds. If  \theta>0, there is a unique  \tilde{n}\in(0,1] that satisfies (5.1). If  \theta=0, there may be more than one  \tilde{n} that satisfies (5.1). However, consider  \tilde{w}'=\max\{\tilde{n}',(1-\theta)s\} and $ \tilde{w}, where  \tilde{n}' and $ \tilde{n} both satisfy (5.1). If  \theta=0, then $ \tilde{w}'=\tilde{w} almost everywhere.

Using (4.7) and (7.8), one can write:

\displaystyle 1-\tilde{c}_{t}=\beta\mathbb{CE}_{t}\left[\tilde{w}_{t+1}\right]^{1-\frac{1}{\epsilon}}(\frac{\tilde{c}_{t}}{\tilde{c}_{t+1}})^{\frac{1}{\epsilon}} (7.10)

Then, setting  \tilde{c}_{t}=\tilde{c}_{t+1}=\tilde{c} in (7.10), one obtains
\displaystyle \tilde{c}=1-\beta\mathbb{CE}\left[\tilde{w}\right]^{1-\frac{1}{\epsilon}} (7.11)

From (7.11), observe that  \tilde{c}=1-\beta>0 if  \tilde{n}=1. If  \tilde{n}<1, then  \mathbb{CE}\left[\tilde{w}\right]\in(0,1). Hence, if  \tilde{n}<1, there exists  \underline{\epsilon}=(1+\frac{\log\beta}{\log\mathbb{CE}\left[\tilde{w}\right]})^{-1}<1 such that  \tilde{c}>0 if  \epsilon>\underline{\epsilon}.

Using (4.14), (7.9) and (7.11), one obtains (5.2). Next, using (4.2) , (7.6) and (7.11) , one obtains (5.3). Note that  s^{i*}=\frac{\tilde{n}}{1-\theta}. If  P(\frac{1}{1-\theta})<1, then:  \tilde{n}<1;  P(s^{i*})\leq P(\frac{1}{1-\theta})<1; and, from (5.3),  \beta R<1. If  P(\frac{1}{1-\theta})=1, then:  \tilde{n}=1;  P(s^{i*})=P(\frac{1}{1-\theta})=1; and from, (5.3),  \beta R=1.  \diamondsuit

Proof of Proposition 4

I will compare the steady states corresponding to two different values for firms' ability to borrow:  \theta_{H} and  \theta_{L}<\theta_{H}.

Suppose that  P(\frac{1}{1-\theta_{L}})<1. Denoting explicitly the dependence of steady-state policies on  \theta and using (5.1), one obtains that  \tilde{n}(\theta_{H})>\tilde{n}(\theta_{L}). This result, together with (5.5), implies that  \frac{F_{K}(\theta_{H})}{R(\theta_{H})}<\frac{F_{K}(\theta_{L})}{R(\theta_{L})}.

Next, I will show that a decrease in  \theta generates a mean-preserving spread in  \tilde{w}. Note that, in steady state,  \tilde{w} is the growth rate of idiosyncratic wealth and the growth rate of idiosyncratic consumption. Denote by  G(x) the cumulative distribution function of  \tilde{w}(\theta)=\max\{\tilde{n}(\theta),(1-\theta)s\}. Observe that  E\left[\tilde{w}(\theta_{H})\right]=E\left[\tilde{w}(\theta_{L})\right]=1. Furthermore,

\displaystyle G(x;\theta_{L})-G(x;\theta_{H})=\begin{Bmatrix}=0 & if & x<\tilde{n}(\theta_{L})\ >0 & if & x\in(\tilde{n}(\theta_{L}),\tilde{n}(\theta_{H}))\ \leq0 & if & x>\tilde{n}(\theta_{H}) \end{Bmatrix}.
Thus, a decrease in  \theta generates a mean-preserving spread in  \tilde{w}. This implies that  \mathbb{CE}\left[\tilde{w}(\theta_{H})\right]>\mathbb{CE}\left[\tilde{w}(\theta_{L})\right]. Then, from (5.2), we have that  K(\theta_{L})<K(\theta_{H}) if and only if  \epsilon>1. Finally, (5.3) and  \tilde{n}(\theta_{H})>\tilde{n}(\theta_{L}) imply that  R(\theta_{H})>R(\theta_{L}).  \diamondsuit

Proof of Lemma 5

In this proof, I will assume that  s is a continuous random variable and that  P(s) has positive support over  (0,\infty). However, the more general proof is very similar.

In a small open economy,  \tilde{n} and  F_{K}\tilde{k} are uniquely determined by the steady-state condition  E[\tilde{w}]=E[\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)sF_{K}\tilde{k}\}]=1 and (5.3), which is a partial-equilibrium steady-state condition. Define a function  z(x) by  E\left[\max\{z(x),sx\}\right]=1, where the domain of  x is  [0,1]. Observe that:  z(0)=1;  z(1)=0;  z is continuous; and  z is strictly decreasing in  x. Write (5.3) as:

\displaystyle \beta R=\frac{\left(\mathbb{CE}[\max\{z(x),sx\}]\right)^{\frac{1}{\epsilon}}}{\left(\mathbb{CE}[\max\{1,s\frac{x}{z(x)}\}]\right)^{\gamma}}\equiv H(x) (7.12)

Note that:  H(0)=1;  \lim_{x\rightarrow1}H(x)=0; and  H is strictly decreasing in  x. Thus, associated with any  BR<1 there is a unique value for  F_{K}\tilde{k} and a unique value for  \tilde{n}<1 that satisfy  E[\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)sF_{K}\tilde{k}\}]=1 and (5.3). Then (4.10) determines the unique value of aggregate capital.

From (7.11), observe that  \tilde{c}>0 if  \epsilon>\underline{\epsilon}=(1+\frac{\log\beta}{\log\mathbb{CE}_{t}\left[\tilde{w}\right]})^{-1}, where  \tilde{w}=\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)sF_{K}\tilde{k}\}.  \diamondsuit

Proof of Proposition 6

From (7.12), one observes that  x and  z(x) do not depend on  \theta. Hence, a decrease in  \theta leads to a decrease in  F_{K}\tilde{k} and has no effect on  \tilde{n}. (5.4) implies that a decrease in  \theta leads to an increase in  \frac{F_{K}}{R}.  \diamondsuit

Proof of Proposition 7

From (7.12), we see that a decrease in  R leads to an increase in  x and thus a decrease in  z(x). Hence, a decrease in  R leads to an increase in  F_{K}\tilde{k} and a decrease in  \tilde{n}. (5.4) implies that a decrease in  R leads to an increase in  \frac{F_{K}}{R}. Because  \tilde{n} decreases and  F_{K}\tilde{k} increases, one obtains that a decrease in  R leads to a simple increase in risk in  \tilde{w}=\max\{\tilde{n},(1-\theta)sF_{K}\tilde{k}\}.  \diamondsuit

Proof of Proposition 8

As in the main text, I explicitly denote the dependence of steady-state variables on the share of profits that firms are able to pledge in the long run; for example,  K(\theta) is steady state aggregate capital when  \lim_{t\rightarrow}\theta_{t}=\theta.

Financial market clearing implies:

\displaystyle E[\tilde{d}_{t}]=E[\min\{sF_{K}(K_{t})\tilde{k}_{t}-\tilde{n}_{t},\theta_{t}sF_{K}(K_{t})\tilde{k}_{t}\}]=0
which determines a unique value for  \frac{F_{K}(K_{t})\tilde{k}_{t}}{\tilde{n}_{t}}, with  \frac{F_{K}(K_{t})\tilde{k}_{t}}{\tilde{n}_{t}}=\frac{F_{K}(K(\theta_{t}))\tilde{k}(\theta_{t})}{\tilde{n}(\theta_{t})}=\frac{1}{\tilde{n}(\theta_{t})}. Then, from 5.4, we have  \frac{F_{K}(K_{t})}{R_{t+1}}=\frac{F_{K}(K(\theta_{t}))}{R(\theta_{t})}.

Next, observe that

\displaystyle \frac{c_{t+1}^{i}}{E[c_{t+1}^{i}]} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \max\{\frac{\tilde{n}_{t}}{F_{K}(K_{t})\tilde{k}_{t}},(1-\theta_{t})s\}  
  \displaystyle = \displaystyle \max\{\tilde{n}(\theta_{t}),(1-\theta_{t})s\}=\tilde{w}(\theta_{t})  

and hence the distribution of  \frac{c_{t+1}^{i}}{E_{t}[c_{t+1}^{i}]} (conditional on period- t information and unconditionally) is equal to the distribution of  \tilde{w}(\theta_{t}).  \diamondsuit

Proof of Proposition 9

Proof of Part (a). From (4.6) and the assumption that  \epsilon=1, one observes that  \tilde{c}_{t}=1-\beta for all  t. Then, from (4.14), one obtains that  \tilde{k}_{t}=\beta. Moreover, from (4.12), we have that steady state capital satisfies  F_{K}(K)=\frac{1}{\beta} and that the growth rate of aggregate capital is given by  \frac{K_{t+1}}{K_{t}}=\beta F_{K}(K_{t}), so that convergence is monotonic.

Proof of Part (b). Propositions 4 and 8 imply that  \frac{F_{K}(K_{\tau}^{L})}{R_{\tau}^{L}}>\frac{F_{K}(K_{\tau}^{H})}{R_{\tau}^{H}}. From part (a), we have that  K_{\tau}^{L}=K_{\tau}^{H} and hence  R_{\tau}^{H}>R_{\tau}^{L}.

Finally, consider an economy in which firms' ability to borrow is given by  \left\{ \theta_{t}^{L}\right\} _{t=0}^{\infty} but the period- \tau interest rate is exogenous and equal to  R_{\tau}^{H}. Suppose, by contradiction, that the period- \tau equity premium in this hypothetical economy were greater than the period- \tau equity premium in economy  L. Then, because  R_{\tau}^{H}>R_{\tau}^{L}, we have that period- \tau aggregate capital in this economy is less than period- \tau aggregate capital in economy  L. Because aggregate capital in period- \tau-1 is identical in the hypothetical economy and in economy  L, this implies that period- \tau net leverage in the hypothetical economy is less than period- \tau net leverage in economy  L, which is given by  E[\tilde{d}_{\tau+1}^{L}]=0. Equation (5.4) then implies that the period- \tau equity premium in the hypothetical economy is greater than the period- \tau equity premium in economy  L, a contradiction.  \diamondsuit


Footnotes

* Federal Reserve Board. I thank Vasia Panousi, Alp Simsek, Francisco Vazquez-Grande and various seminar participants for helpful comments. I am particularly grateful to George-Marios Angeletos, Ricardo Caballero, Guido Lorenzoni and Iván Werning for their advice and encouragement. Any views expressed here are those of the author and need not represent the views of the Federal Reserve Board or its staff. Contact: [email protected] Return to Text
1. More specifically, they define the entrepreneurial investment wedge as the tax on investment in a representative-agent economy that would make the Euler equation hold for the aggregate consumption of firm owners. Return to Text
2. It is without loss of generality to restrict attention to one-period promises. To see this, note that, if firms traded promises due in up to  n>1 periods in the future, a firm could replicate the cash flows from any set of multi-period promises by making a one-period promise in period- t (due in period- t+1) with a face value equal to the total expected value of the period- t+1 through period- t+n promises, discounted to period  t+1 using the spot-rate curve derived from  \{R_{\tau}\}_{\tau=t+1}^{t+n-1}. The entrepreneur would not renege on this set of one-period promises if the entrepreneur would not renege on the original set of multi-period promises. Rampini and Viswanathan (2010) make a similar point in a partial-equilibrium setting with a constant risk-free rate and a constant ability of firms to borrow against capital. Return to Text
3. In the case of standard expected utility, for productivity realizations below the threshold  s_{t+1}^{i*}, the consumption growth rate of entrepreneur  i is equal to  (\beta R_{t})^{\epsilon}, reflecting the usual tradeoff between consuming  R additional goods next period or one additional good today. Return to Text
4. The entrepreneur is indifferent between a decrease in period- t consumption and a decrease (with equal expected value) in consumption in any states  s^{i,t+1} with  s_{t+1}^{i}\leq s_{t+1}^{i*}. Return to Text
5. Note that if  \theta>0, there is a unique  \tilde{n} that satisfies (5.1). If  \theta=0, there may be more than one  \tilde{n} that satisfies (5.1); however, if  \tilde{n}' and $ \tilde{n} both satisfy (5.1), it will be the case that $ \tilde{w}'=\max\{\tilde{n}',(1-\theta)s\}=\tilde{w} almost everywhere. See the proof of Proposition 3 for more detail. Return to Text
6. If  \beta R=1, then there are multiple steady-state equilibria, but each features the same aggregate capital and perfect consumption insurance. Return to Text
7. More specifically, the distribution of  \frac{c_{\tau+1}^{i,H}}{E_{\tau}[c_{\tau+1}^{i,H}]} represents a simple increase in risk relative to the distribution of  \frac{c_{\tau+1}^{i,L}}{E_{\tau}[c_{\tau+1}^{i,L}]}, as implied by Proposition 8. Moreover, the distribution of  \frac{c_{\tau+1}^{i,L}}{E_{\tau}[c_{\tau+1}^{i,L}]} represents a simple increase in risk relative to the distribution that would occur in economy  L if the period- \tau risk-free rate were exogenous and equal to  R_{\tau}^{H}. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text