![]()
Skip to: [Printable
Version (PDF)]
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System PPP Rules, Macroeconomic (In)stability and LearningNOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/. Abstract: Governments in emerging economies have pursued real exchange rate targeting through Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) rules that link the nominal depreciation rate to either the deviation of the real exchange rate from its long run level or to the difference between the domestic and the foreign CPI-inflation rates. In this paper we disentangle the conditions under which these rules may lead to endogenous fluctuations due to self-fulfilling expectations in a small open economy that faces nominal rigidities. We find that besides the specification of the rule, structural parameters such as the share of traded goods (that measures the degree of openness of the economy) and the degrees of imperfect competition and price stickiness in the non-traded sector play a crucial role in the determinacy of equilibrium. To evaluate the relevance of the real (in)determinacy results we pursue a learnability (E-stability) analysis for the aforementioned PPP rules. We show that for rules that guarantee a unique equilibrium, the fundamental solution that represents this equilibrium is learnable in the E-stability sense. Similarly we show that for PPP rules that open the possibility of sunspot equilibria, a common factor representation that describes these equilibria is also E-stable. In this sense sunspot equilibria and therefore aggregate instability are more likely to occur due to PPP rules than previously recognized. Keywords: Small Open Economy, PPP rules, Multiple Equilibria, Sunspot Equilibria, Indeterminacy, Expectational Stability and Learning JEL Classification: C62, D83, E32, F41 *Email address: luis-felipe.zanna@frb.gov. This paper is based on a chapter of my Ph.D. dissertation at the University of Pennsylvania. I am grateful to Martín Uribe, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Frank Schorfheide for comments on early versions of this paper. I also thank David Bowman, George Evans and Dale Henderson for comments and suggestions. All errors remain mine. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the author and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. Return to text 1 IntroductionIt has been claimed that the real exchange rate is perhaps the most popular real target in developing economies. The reason is that policy makers in these economies are always concerned about avoiding losses in competitiveness in foreign markets, or similarly, about maintaining purchasing power parity (PPP). In order to achieve the real exchange target policy makers often follow PPP rules. Such rules link the nominal rate of devaluation of the domestic currency to the deviation of the real exchange rate from its long run level or to the difference between the domestic inflation rate and the foreign inflation rate. For instance, Calvo et al. (1995) argued that Brazil, Chile and Colombia followed such rules in the past. The characterization of the channels through which real exchange rate targeting affects the business cycles in emerging economies is a central issue in the design and implementation of the PPP rules. The theoretical literature about PPP rules has tried to disentangle these channels.1 One of these important attempts is made by Uribe (2003) who analyzes a PPP rule whereby the government increases the devaluation rate when the real exchange rate is below its steady-state level. He pursues a determinacy of equilibrium analysis and argues that PPP rules may lead to aggregate instability in the economy by inducing endogenous fluctuations due to self-fulfilling expectations. From the economic policy-design perspective, this result has important implications. It states that the aforementioned rules may open the possibility of sunspot equilibria and lead the economy to equilibria with undesirable properties such as a large degree of volatility. This implication in turn suggests that a determinacy of equilibrium analysis can be used to differentiate among rules favoring those that at least avoid sunspot equilibria by guaranteeing a unique equilibrium with a lower degree of volatility.2 Although appealing this argument is still far from complete and may suffer from some drawbacks. The reason is that in the typical determinacy of equilibrium analysis, it is implicitly assumed that agents can coordinate their actions and learn the equilibria (unique or multiple) induced by the rule. But relaxing this assumption may have interesting consequences for the design of PPP rules. On one hand, if agents cannot learn the unique equilibrium targeted by the rule then the economy may end up diverging from this equilibrium. But if this is the case then it is clear that there are some rules that although guaranteeing a unique equilibrium, do not insure that the economy will reach it.3 On the other hand, if agents cannot learn sunspot equilibria then one may doubt about the relevance of characterizing rules that lead to multiple equilibria as ``bad'' ones. After all, if agents cannot learn sunspot equilibria then they are less likely to occur. Therefore, it seems clear that a determinacy of equilibrium analysis of PPP rules should in principle be accompanied by a learnability of equilibrium analysis. Both analyses would help policy makers to distinguish and design PPP rules satisfying two requirements: uniqueness and learnability of the equilibrium. The first requirement would prevent the economy from achieving sunspot equilibria with undesirable properties such as a large degree of volatility. Whereas, the second requirement would guarantee that agents can indeed coordinate their actions on the equilibrium the policy makers are targeting. The present paper is motivated by the interest of studying if particular representations of the equilibria (unique or multiple) induced by PPP rules are learnable in the Expectational - Stability (E-Stability) sense proposed by Evans and Honkapohja (1999, 2001).4 5 In fact our purpose in the present paper is three-fold. First we study and disentangle the structural conditions of an open economy under which an Uribe-type PPP rule may generate multiple equilibria (real indeterminacy).6 We use a small open economy model with traded and non-traded goods. We assume flexible prices for the former and sticky prices for the latter. Under this set-up we show how the aforementioned conditions depend not only on the responsiveness of the rule to the real exchange rate but also on some important structural parameters of the economy. For instance we find that ceteris paribus, given the sensitivity of the rule to the real exchange rate, the lower the degree of openness of the economy (the lower the share of traded goods), the more likely that the rule will induce aggregate instability in the economy by generating multiple equilibria. In addition, keeping the rest constant, the lower (the higher) the degree of price stickiness (the degree of monopolistic competition) in the non-traded sector, the more likely that the rule will lead to real indeterminacy. The second goal of this paper consists of showing that under real determinacy the fundamental solution that describes the unique equilibrium induced by the PPP rule is learnable in the E-stability sense.7 In addition we use the recent work by Evans and McGough (2003) to prove that under real indeterminacy some common factor representations of stationary sunspot equilibria are also E-stable.8 This result suggests that under some reasonable assumptions agents can learn and coordinate their actions to achieve sunspot equilibria, making them ``more likely'' to occur under PPP rules. In this sense these equilibria should not be perceived as mere mathematical and theoretical curiosities. The natural question that arises from these results is whether under a different timing of the PPP rule, it is possible for policy makers to design a simple rule that avoids sunspot equilibria but still induces a unique equilibrium whose characterization is learnable. In accord with the findings in the interest rate rule literature, we find that a PPP rule that is backward-looking in the sense of being defined in terms of the (deviation of the) past real exchange rate (from its long run level) satisfies these two requirements. Finally the third goal of this paper is associated with the original work by Dornbusch (1980, 1982) that studies how a PPP rule whereby the nominal exchange rate is linked to the (deviation of the) current domestic price level (from its long-run level), may affect the output price-level stability trade-off by playing a role as an absorber of fundamental shocks.9 We analyze a rule motivated by Dorbunsch's works assuming that the nominal devaluation rate is positively linked to the difference between the domestic and foreign CPI-inflation rates. In fact this specification tries to capture the previously mentioned stylized facts about PPP rules in Brazil, Colombia and Chile. As before we state the conditions under which this rule leads to real indeterminacy. We also show that the common factor representation of stationary sunspot equilibria as well as the fundamental solution that describes the unique equilibrium induced by the rule are learnable in the E-stability sense. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the set-up of a sticky-price model with its main assumptions. Section 3 pursues the determinacy of equilibrium analysis for a PPP rule defined in terms of the current real exchange rate. Section 4 deals with the learnability analysis for the aforementioned rule. Section 5 pursues all the previous analyses for a PPP rule defined in terms of the CPI-inflation rate. Finally Section 6 concludes. 2 A Sticky-Price Model2.1 The Household-Firm UnitConsider a small open economy inhabited by a large number of
identical household-firm units indexed by
where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() We assume that the non-traded good is a composite good. We
introduce monopolistic competition in the model by assuming that
the household-firm unit where ![]() ![]() We also assume that there are sticky prices in the production of
the non-traded good. This assumption is useful to understand the
last term of the intertemporal utility function (1). Following Rotemberg (1982) we suppose that the
household-unit dislikes having its price of non-traded goods grow
at a rate different from
The production of traded and non-traded goods only requires labor and uses the following technologies where ![]() ![]() ![]() where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() The law of one price holds for the traded good and to simplify
the analysis we normalize the foreign price of the traded good to
one. Therefore, the domestic currency price of traded goods
( Using equation (6) and defining the nominal devaluation rate as it is straightforward to derive the CPI-inflation rate, ![]() ![]() ![]() We define the real exchange rate ( From this definition of the real exchange rate we deduce that We assume that in each period where ![]() Using the previous assumptions the representative agent's flow constraint each period can be written as13 where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() To derive the period-by-period budget constraint of the representative agent, it is important to notice that total beginning-of-period wealth in the following period is given by and that ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Then we can use equations (12), (13) and (14) to derive the budget constraint of the representative agent as The agent is also subject to a Non-Ponzi game condition described by at all dates and under all contingencies, where ![]() ![]() ![]() with ![]() Under this sticky-price set-up the problem of the representative
agent is reduced to choose the sequences {
The first order conditions correspond to (15) and (16) both with equality and where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Finally we postpone the explanation of condition (23). The reason is that it will be used to derive the augmented Phillips curve for non-traded goods, that is actually one of the relevant equations for the determinacy and learnability of equilibrium analyses. 2.2 The GovernmentThe government issues two nominal liabilities: money,
where ![]() ![]() Finally we define the monetary policy as in Uribe (2003). The
government follows a PPP rule whereby the government sets the
nominal devaluation rate as a function of the deviation of the
current real exchange rate ( where ![]() ![]() 2.3 The EquilibriumWe will focus on a symmetric
equilibrium in which all the household-firm units choose the
same price for the good they produce. Therefore in equilibrium all
agents are identical and we can drop the index and ![]() ![]() We also assume free capital mobility. This implies that the following non-arbitrage condition must hold where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() But this result of a constant marginal utility and conditions (14 ) and (22) imply that where ![]() Utilizing (20), (23),
that corresponds to the augmented Phillips curve for the non-traded goods inflation.16 Furthermore applying the symmetry in equilibrium and recalling (30), we can rewrite (18), (19) and (21) as We proceed giving the definition of a symmetric equilibrium for a government that pursues a Ricardian fiscal policy and follows a PPP rule that responds to the current real exchange rate as described by (26). Definition 1 Given, 3 The Determinacy of Equilibrium AnalysisTo pursue the determinacy of equilibrium analysis we reduce the model further. To do so we can use conditions (33) and (34) to obtain that together with the PPP rule (26) and equations (5), (10), (31) and (32), are the only equations necessary to pursue the determinacy of equilibrium analysis in our model. They help us to find the stochastic processes ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() We point out that we do not need to consider in the determinacy
analysis equations (24) and (25). The reason is that under a Ricardian fiscal
policy, the intertemporal version of the government's budget
constraint in conjunction with its transversality condition will be
always satisfied. Moreover the stochastic processes
We can go further reducing and log-linearizing the model. Using equations (5), (10), (26), (31), (32), and (36) yields18 where ![]() ![]() ![]() and ![]() ![]() ![]() As we mentioned before in this analysis we only study the possibilities of real indeterminacy or real determinacy of the equilibrium. By real indeterminacy we mean a situation in which the behavior of one or more (real) variables of the model are not pinned down by the model. This situation implies that there are multiple equilibria and opens the possibility of the existence of sunspot equilibria. Before we analyze the conditions under which PPP rules may lead to real indeterminacy, it is worth constructing some intuition using the model of why these rules may induce equilibria in which expectations are self-fulfilled. In order to accomplish this task we can assume perfect foresight (no uncertainty). Then we rewrite equations (37) and (38) as ![]() Equation (43) implies that current inflation of non-traded goods is determined by the discounted sum of the expected future real exchange rates and nominal depreciation rates. The first term inside of the parenthesis is associated with future real exchange rates. It captures the fact that higher expected future real exchange rates make non-traded goods become relatively cheaper than traded goods. This leads to a higher expected future excesses of demand for non-traded goods to which the firm-unit responds raising the current price of non-traded goods up and therefore increasing the current non-traded goods inflation rate. On the other hand, the second term in (43) that is associated with future nominal depreciation rates captures the effect of the intertemporal price of consumption on the determination of the current non-traded goods inflation. In essence, expectations of nominal appreciation (negative nominal depreciation rates) decrease the nominal interest rate provided that the uncovered interest parity condition holds under perfect foresight. But a decrease in the nominal interest rate pushes the liquidity transaction costs down, which in turn expands consumption of non-traded (and traded) goods. This increase in consumption lead to a positive excess of demand for non-traded goods and therefore to a higher current inflation. Equation (44) simply describes the depreciation (or appreciation) of the real exchange rate as a difference between the nominal depreciation rate and the non-traded goods inflation rate. With these two last equations, equation (42) and the PPP rule,
Although this intuitive argument points out the possibility of self-fulfilling equilibria induced by a PPP rule, it is important to disentangle the conditions under which these equilibria are possible. The following proposition achieves this goal characterizing locally the equilibrium for the model described by equations (37)-(40). Proposition 1
Suppose the government follows a PPP rule that is
described by
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
Proof. See Appendix.
![]() From Proposition 1 it is clear that conditions under which PPP
rules lead to multiple equilibria do not simply depend on the
response coefficient
To understand the important role that some of the structural
parameters of the model may play in the determinacy of equilibrium
analysis, we study how the aforementioned threshold (
Corollary 1 Suppose the government follows a PPP rule given by
Proof. See Appendix.
![]() Using Proposition 1 and Corollary 1 we can understand the
effects of varying some of the structural parameters and the
semi-elasticity of the rule (
Notwithstanding the relevance of these analytical results, it is
crucial to investigate their quantitative importance. To accomplish
this we rely on a specific parametrization of the model. Since this
exercise is merely indicative we borrow some values of the
parameters from previous studies about emerging and small open
economies.22
Following Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe's (2001) study about
Mexico we assign the following values to some of the relevant
structural parameters of the model:
Table 1
The results of our exercises are presented in Figure 1, where ``I'' stands for real indeterminacy and ``D'' stands for real determinacy. As can be observed, this figure confirms the results in Proposition 1 and Corollary 1 showing how significant these results are in quantitative terms. Consider the top left panel. From this panel we can infer the following. Suppose that the government in response to a 1 per cent appreciation of the real exchange rate, devalues the nominal exchange rate by 2 percent. In other words, assume that the semi-elasticity of the PPP rule is -2. Whereas this PPP rule may induce multiple equilibria in an economy whose degree of openness is 0.2, the same rule leads to a unique equilibrium in an economy whose degree of openness is 0.6. Similar inferences can be pursued from the top right and bottom left panels of Figure 1. That is although a rule with semi-elasticity of -2 guarantees a unique equilibrium in an economy with a degree of monopolistic competition of 5 (a degree of price stickiness of 5), the same rule induces multiple equilibria when the aforementioned degree corresponds to 15 (2). Although it is not possible to derive an analytical result to
see how varying the implied nominal depreciation target (
To finalize this section we want to point out that similar
qualitative results to the ones presented in this section can be
obtained if the PPP rule is defined in terms of the real
depreciation rate. That is
4 The Learnability AnalysisThe importance of the result from the previous section, that a PPP rule may induce aggregate instability by generating multiple equilibria in the economy, stems from the fact that such rule opens the possibility of expectations driven fluctuations in economic activity. In particular, the model may admit self-fulfilling rational expectations equilibria driven by extraneous processes known as sunspots.25 However the previous results, as the ones in Uribe (2003), do not discuss the attainability of these PPP rule induced sunspot equilibria. They do not even mention how attainable the unique equilibrium is. Strictly speaking, and regardless of real determinacy or real indeterminacy, it is not clear whether and how agents may coordinate their actions in order to achieve a particular equilibrium in the model. The purpose of this section is to address this issue. We want to study the potential of agents to learn the unique equilibrium characterized by the fundamental solution and sunspot equilibria described by a common factor solution. Figure 1: This figure shows
how the local determinacy of equilibrium varies with respect to the
semi-elasticity of the rule (
Description of Figure 1Figure 1 shows the combinations of the
semi-elasticity of the rule and other structural parameters of the
model under which there is a unique equilibrium (real determinacy)
whose Minimal State Variable (MSV) representation is learnable in
the E-stability sense. These combinations are denoted by `` D-ES''.
The figure also shows the combinations of these parameters under
which there are multiple equilibria (real indeterminacy) and
sunspot equilibria whose Common Factor (CF) representation is
learnable in the E-stability sense. We denote these combinations by
`` I-ES''. Figure 1 has four panels. We proceed to describe each
panel. The top-left panel shows the combinations for the
semi-elasticity of the rule (
The top-right panel shows the combinations for the
semi-elasticity of the rule (
The bottom-left panel shows the combinations for the
semi-elasticity of the rule (
The bottom-right panel shows the combinations for the
semi-elasticity of the rule (
As a criterion of ``learnability'' of an equilibrium we will use the concept of ``E-stability'' proposed by Evans and Honkapohja (1999, 2001). That is, an equilibrium is ``learnable'' if it is ``E-Stable''.26 Consequently we start by assuming that agents in our model no longer are endowed with rational expectations. Instead they have adaptive rules whereby agents form expectations using recursive least squares updating and data from the system. Then we derive the conditions for expectational stability (E-stability). In our analysis we will focus on the expectational stability concept for the following reasons. First, in models that display a unique equilibrium (real determinacy models), Marcet and Sargent (1989) and Evans and Honkapohja (1999, 2001) have shown that under some general conditions, the notional time concept of expectational stability of a rational expectation equilibrium governs the local convergence of real time adaptive learning algorithms. Specifically they have shown that under E-stability, recursive least-squares learning is locally convergent to the rational expectations equilibrium. Second, Evans and McGough (2003) have numerically argued that under some assumptions about the parameters of a linear stochastic univariate model, with a predetermined variable, the same argument applies when this model displays sunspot equilibria. Formally they have stated that under a strict subset of the structural parameter space, there exist stationary sunspot equilibria that are locally stable under least square learning provided that agents use a common factor representation for their estimated law of motion. We adapt the methodology of Evans and Honkapohja (1999, 2001) and Evans and McGough (2003) to pursue the learnability (E-stability) analysis. Accordingly we need to define the concept of E-stability. In order to define it we give an idea of the methodology we apply for the case of real determinacy. To grasp the methodology, it becomes useful to reduce our model to the following linear stochastic difference equations system. Use (37), (38), (39) and (40) to rewrite the model as where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Iterating forward this law of motion and using it to eliminate all the forecasts in the model we can derive the implied actual law of motion (ALM) ![]() Then we obtain the T-mapping
![]() ![]() For the case of sunspot equilibria we apply the same methodology but in that case the PLM is augmented by the sunspot and its particular structure. In particular we will focus on the common factor representation proposed by Evans and McGough (2003). Due to space constraint we refer the readers to the aforementioned references for a detailed explanation.29 It is important to observe that a fundamental part in the
learnability analysis consists of making explicit what agents know
when they form their forecasts. In the E-stability analysis
literature it is common to assume that when agents form their
expectations
We proceed to present the results of the learnability analysis for the fundamental solution of the model (45) in the following Proposition. Proposition 2
Suppose the government follows a PPP rule that is
described by
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Proof. See Appendix.
![]() Proposition 2 points out that when the model displays a unique equilibrium (real determinacy) then the fundamental solution is E-stable. This is the reason of denoting as ``D-ES'' the regions of the four panels of Figure 1 for which the model displays not only real determinacy but also E-stability. The importance of this result stems from the fact that policy makers will face less difficulties in implementing PPP rules that lead to a unique equilibrium since they know that agents will coordinate on that equilibrium and the macroeconomic system will not diverge away from the targeted equilibrium. It is also possible to show that under real indeterminacy the fundamental solution or MSV solution can be E-stable. However in this case policy makers will face other difficulties. In particular under multiple equilibria there might be self-fulfilling rational expectations equilibria driven by extraneous processes known as sunspot. These equilibria may be characterized by undesirable features such as larger volatility of macroeconomic variables suggesting that policy makers should avoid rules that in principle may induce multiple equilibria. Although the previous argument may sound appealing, it may
suffer from some drawbacks. For instance, it is not clear whether
agents are able to coordinate their actions on a particular sunspot
equilibria. To clarify this issue the next proposition illustrates
that some particular representations of stationary sunspot
equilibria can be E-stable. To simplify the analysis and to be able
to derive analytical results we assume that
Proposition 3
Suppose the government follows a PPP rule that is
described by
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
Proof. See Appendix.
![]() Proposition 3 demonstrates that some common factor
representations of sunspot equilibria induced by PPP rules are
learnable in the sense of E-stability. We would like to emphasize
the important role that the common factor representations proposed
by Evans and McGough (2003) play in the learnability analysis. To
see this, observe that the typical stationary sunspot equilibrium
representation,
Our results from the real determinacy and learnability of
equilibrium analyses pose the question of whether changing the
timing of the PPP rule avoids sunspot equilibria and still induces
a unique equilibrium that is E-stable. Similarly to the findings in
the interest rate rule literature, we find that a PPP rule that is
backward-looking in the sense of being defined in terms of the past
real exchange rate satisfies these two requirements.32 A backward-looking PPP rule can be
described as
where ![]() and ![]() The following proposition summarizes the aforementioned result. Proposition 4
Suppose the government follows a backward-looking PPP
rule that is described by
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
Proof. See Appendix.
![]() 5 PPP Rules Defined in Terms of The CPI-InflationIn this section we analyze a different type of PPP rule. We study rules whereby the government in response to an increase in the CPI-inflation, increases the nominal depreciation rate. The motivation to consider this type of rule is twofold. First, from an empirical point of view, Calvo et al. (1995) mention that starting in 1968, Brazil's government implemented a rule by which the exchange rate was adjusted as a function of the difference between domestic and U.S. inflation. In addition, between 1985 and 1992, Chile used an exchange rate band whose trend was determined by the difference between the domestic inflation rate and a measure of the average inflation in the rest of the world. Second, from a theoretical point of view, Dornbusch (1980, 1982) conceives PPP rules as a means to introduce the necessary real flexibility to cope with intrinsic (fundamental) uncertainty in a world that faces nominal rigidities. He defines a PPP rule as a function whereby the nominal exchange rate is positively linked to the domestic price index. We try to capture the aforementioned stylized facts and some of
the flavor of Dornbusch's work by defining a rule whereby the
nominal depreciation rate is positively linked to the difference
between the domestic CPI inflation ( where ![]() As before we proceed in the following way. First we will prove that such rule may induce aggregate instability in the economy by generating multiple equilibria and opening the possibility of sunspot equilibria. Specifically we will study and disentangle the conditions under which this rule leads to real indeterminacy or to real determinacy. Second, we will study the ``learnability'' properties not only of the fundamental solution but also of the common factor representation of stationary sunspot equilibria. The following proposition summarizes the conditions under which the aforementioned PPP rule induces either real determinacy or real indeterminacy in the model. Proposition 5
Suppose the government follows a PPP rule given by
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
Proof. See Appendix.
![]() Proposition 5 suggests that multiple equilibria are also
possible for PPP rules that depend on the current CPI-inflation. In
particular it points out that a necessary condition for these rules to cause real
indeterminacy is that the response coefficient to the CPI-
inflation be less than one. That means that in response to a one
percent increase in the CPI-inflation rate, the government raises
the nominal devaluation rate in less than one percent.
Interestingly such response seems to be feasible in the practice of
economic policy. However in order to generate real indeterminacy
the nominal depreciation response coefficient,
Corollary 2 Suppose the government follows a PPP rule given by
Proof. See Appendix.
![]() Using Proposition 5 and Corollary 2 we can breakdown the effects
of varying some of the structural parameters of the model and the
PPP rule response coefficient to CPI-inflation
Under the parametrization of Table 1 we construct Figure 2 that
corroborates these results quantitatively. To some extent it also
validates numerically how likely is that the aforementioned PPP
rule may destabilize the economy by generating multiple equilibria.
Moreover although it is not possible to derive an analytical result
to see how varying the implied nominal depreciation target (
It is also important to observe that similar qualitative results
to the ones described in Proposition 5 and Corollary 2 can be
obtained if the PPP rule is defined in terms of the non-traded
goods inflation rate. That is
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Description of Figure 2Figure 2 shows the combinations of the PPP rule response coefficient to the CPI-inflation and other structural parameters of the model under which there is a unique equilibrium (real determinacy) whose Minimal State Variable (MSV) representation is learnable in the E-stability sense. These combinations are denoted by `` D-ES''. The figure also shows the combinations of these parameters under which there are multiple equilibria (real indeterminacy) and sunspot equilibria whose Common Factor (CF) representation is learnable in the E-stability sense. We denote these combinations by `` I-ES''. In addition the figure shows the combinations that imply the non-existence of an equilibrium denoted by `` N''. Figure 2 has four panels. We proceed to describe each panel. The top-left panel shows the combinations for the PPP rule
response coefficient to the CPI-inflation (
The top-right panel shows the combinations for the PPP rule
response coefficient to the CPI-inflation (
The bottom-left panel shows the combinations for the PPP rule
response coefficient to the CPI-inflation (
The bottom-right panel shows the combinations for the PPP rule
response coefficient to the CPI-inflation (
We proceed by pursuing the learnability analysis. As argued
before this analysis is useful to evaluate the attainability of the
possible unique equilibrium and multiple equilibria induced by the
PPP rule. We use equations (37), (38), (39) and the
log-linearized versions of (8) and
where ![]() ![]() ![]() As before in order to pursue the learnability analysis we use the methodology proposed by Evans and Honkapohja (1999, 2001). We derive some E-stability conditions and check whether a particular representation of the equilibrium under analysis satisfies or violates them. The following proposition summarizes the results. Proposition 6
Suppose the government follows a PPP rule that is
described by
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
Proof. See Appendix.
![]() Proposition 6 states that when the PPP rule under study induces a unique equilibrium then this equilibrium represented by the fundamental solution, also known as the MSV solution, is learnable in the E-stability sense. This result is important since it means that given that the rule induces a unique equilibrium then agents will be able to coordinate on that particular equilibrium and therefore the economy will converge towards it over time. In addition as was demonstrated in Proposition 2, it is also possible to prove for PPP rules defined in terms of the CPI-inflation, that even under real indeterminacy the fundamental solution is still E-stable. However under real indeterminacy there are other equilibria such as stationary sunspot equilibria whose feasibility is worth evaluating in terms of learnabiliy. Accordingly, the second part of Proposition 6 shows that a common factor representation of stationary sunspot equilibria is learnable in the sense of E-stability. This result is interesting for two reasons. First, as mentioned before, it suggests that sunspot equilibria induced by PPP rules are more likely to occur. Second, it warns policy makers about some of the negative consequences of implementing PPP rules that respond to inflation. Dornbusch (1980, 1982) conceived PPP rules as a means to introduce the necessary real flexibility to cope with intrinsic (fundamental) uncertainty in an economy with nominal rigidities. In contrast our result points out that such PPP rules may open the possibility of learnable representations of sunspot equilibria aggravating the effects of extrinsic (non-fundamental) uncertainty in an economy with nominal rigidities. 6 ConclusionsIn this paper we establish and disentangle the conditions under which PPP rules lead to real (in)determinacy in a small open economy that faces nominal rigidities. We find that besides the specification of the rule, structural parameters such as the share of traded goods (that measures the degree of openness of the economy) and the degrees of imperfect competition and price stickiness in the non-traded sector play a crucial role in the determinacy of equilibrium. More importantly to evaluate the relevance of the determinacy results we also pursue a learnability (E-stability) analysis. We show that for rules that guarantee a unique equilibrium the fundamental solution that describes this equilibrium is learnable in the E-stability sense. Similarly we show that for PPP rules that open the possibility of sunspot equilibria, some common factor representations of these equilibria are also E-stable. That is, agents can coordinate their actions and learn some representations of stationary sunspot equilibria. In this sense these equilibria are more likely to occur under PPP rules than previously recognized and therefore these rules are more prone to cause aggregate instability in the economy. Dornbusch (1980, 1982) conceived PPP rules as a means of introducing the real flexibility necessary to cope with intrinsic (fundamental) uncertainty in an economy with nominal rigidities. Our results indicate that PPP rules must be chosen with care in order to avoid the possibility of ``learnable'' sunspot equilibria and the associated aggravation of the effects of extrinsic (non-fundamental) uncertainty. In other words, PPP rules should satisfy two stability requirements: uniqueness and learnability. On one hand, the rule should avoid sunspot equilibria that are usually associated with undesirable properties such as a large degree of volatility. On the other hand, the rule should guarantee that agents can indeed coordinate their actions on the equilibrium the policy makers are targeting and that the economy will not in fact diverge away from this target. There are some possible extensions of the analysis presented in this paper. First, one may consider extending the model to have two traded goods: a domestic one and a foreign one. This will enrich the analysis making the model more similar to the ones in Dornbusch (1980, 1982). Under this set-up one can explore how our results may vary when the government responds to different measures of inflation in the PPP rule. Second one may study how our determinacy and learnability of equilibrium results may be affected by following the approach by Preston (2003). That is, instead of imposing the assumption of non-rational expectations on the derived log-linearized model, we may impose this assumption as a primitive one of the model. This assumption implies that agents do not have a complete economic model with which to derive true probability laws since they do not know other agents' tastes and beliefs. In this case agents solve multi-period decision problems whereby their actions depend on forecasts of macroeconomic conditions many periods into the future. We leave these extensions for further research. 7 AppendixLemma 1 In
a Proof. First we recall from Azariadis (1993) that a
sufficient condition for such a linearized system to have real
eigenvalues is that
![]() To prove b) we start by noting that
To prove c) we point out that
7.1 Proof of Proposition 1Proof. To prove all the parts of the proposition we use
(37), (38), (39) and (40) to derive the
following system
![]()
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
respectively. Using these expressions we obtain
where ![]() All these expressions together with
To prove part a) we proceed as follows. Observe that since
To prove b) we note that from
Finally to prove c) we use the fact that
7.2 Proof of Corollary 1Proof. First use the steady state description and the
definition of
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() 7.3 Proof of Proposition 2Proof. To prove a) we proceed in the following way.
First, we rewrite the first equation in (45) as
where ![]() ![]() ![]() whose roots are denoted by ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() where ![]() Third, using these relationships and the proof in Proposition 1,
it is trivial to show that under real determinacy, the unique
equilibrium of the model (45)
characterized by the fundamental solution (47)
with
Fourth, we derive the E-stability conditions. Consider the model (45) and assume that the agents follow a perceived law of motion (PLM) that in this case of real determinacy corresponds to the fundamental solution ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Moreover using (60) we can rewrite these conditions as Finally recall that in the proof of Proposition 1 we derived
that real determinacy is associated with one explosive eigenvalue
For
Then defining
7.4 Proof of Proposition 3Proof. This proof builds on Evans and McGough (2003).
First, we rewrite the model (45) as
where ![]() ![]() ![]() whose roots are denoted by ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Second, we point out that following Propositions 3 and 4 in
Evans and McGough (2003), it is simple to prove that the process
Third, we derive the E-stability conditions adapting the
analysis of Evans and McGough (2003). In particular, note that we
assume that agents knows
where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Moreover using (66) and noting that
However note that for the last E-stability condition, it is
always true that for the common factor representation we have that
either
Fourth, we recall our result from the beginning of this proof
that states that under real indeterminacy the roots are
To prove part a) we use the fact that for
To prove part b) we utilize the fact that for
7.5 Proof of Proposition 4Proof. To prove a) first we write the characteristic
equation associated with (50) as
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
where ![]() ![]() Third note that if either
Fourth it is straightforward to prove that the fundamental
solution
![]() It is simple to see that the E-stability conditions are
satisfied given
To prove b) it is enough to note that if
7.6 Proof of Proposition 5Proof. To prove all the parts of the proposition we use
(37), (38), (39) and the log-linearized versions of (8) and
![]() ![]()
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
respectively. Using these expressions we obtain
where ![]() ![]() ![]() To prove part a) we proceed as follows. Observe that since
To prove b) consider the assumption
For
Now consider the assumption
Therefore under either
Finally to prove c) we start by observing that
On the other hand, for the second case we have that since
Therefore in both cases we have concluded that the steady-state
is a source. Hence
7.7 Proof of Corollary 2Proof. First, observe that
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
where ![]() ![]() ![]() 7.8 Proof of Proposition 6Proof. First, observe that the characteristic equation
associated with (54) is
whose roots are denoted by ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Third we use these relationships to prove a). Since under real
determinacy in the proof of Proposition 5 we have that either
Fourth, it is simple to show that under real determinacy, the
unique equilibrium of the model (54)
characterized by the fundamental solution (56)
with
Fifth, we derive the E-stability conditions. However the
procedure is the same as the one explained in the proof of
Proposition 2. We only rename
Sixth to prove b) we start by noting that in (68) we have that
Seventh, we point out that following Propositions 3 and 4 in
Evans and McGough (2003), it is simple to prove that the process
8 ReferencesAdams, C. and D. Gros (1986), ``The Consequences of Real Exchange Rate Rules for Inflation: Some Illustrative Examples, IMF Staff Papers, 33, 439-476. Azariadis, C. (1993), Intertemporal Macroeconomics, Blackwell, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Benhabib, J., S. Schmitt-Grohé and M. Uribe (2001), ``Monetary Policy Rules and Multiple Equilibria,'' American Economic Review, 91, 167-184. Blanchard, O. and C. Kahn (1980), ``The Solution of Linear Difference Models Under Rational Expectations,'' Econometrica, 48, 1305-1312. Bullard, J. and K. Mitra, (2002), ``Learning About Monetary Policy Rules,'' Journal of Monetary Economics, 49, 1105-1129. Calvo, G. (1983), ``Staggering Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,'' Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383-398. Calvo, G., Reinhart, C. and C. Vegh (1995), ``Targeting the Real Exchange Rate: Theory and Evidence,'' Journal of Development Economics, 47:1, 97-134. Carlstrom, C. and T. Fuerst (2001), ``Timing and Real Indeterminacy in Monetary Models,'' Journal of Monetary Economics, 47:2, 285-298. Clarida, J., J. Gali and M. Gertler (2000), ``Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory,'' Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 147-180. Clarida, J., J. Gali and M. Gertler (2001), ''Optimal Monetary Policy in Open Versus Closed Economies: An Integrated Approach,'' American Economic Review, 91 (2), 253-257. Dornbusch, R.(1980), Open Economy Macroeconomics, New York: Basic. Dornbusch, R.(1982), ``PPP Exchange Rate Rules and Macroeconomic Stability,'' Journal of Political Economy, 90:3, 158-165. Dib, A. (2001), ``An Estimated Canadian DSGE Model with Nominal and Real Rigidities,'' Bank of Canada, Working Paper, 26. Dupor, B. (2001), ``Investment and Interest Rate Policy,'' Journal of Economic Theory, 98, 85-113. Evans, G, and S. Honkapohja (1986), ``A Complete Characterization of ARMA Solutions to Linear Rational Expectations Models,'' Review of Economic Studies, 53, 227-239. Evans, G, and S. Honkapohja (1992), ``On theRobustness of Bubbles in Linear RE Models,'' International of Economic Review, 33, 1-14. Evans, G, and S. Honkapohja (1999), ``Learning Dynamics,'' in Handbook of Macroeconomics, eds. J. Taylor and M. Woodford, Elsevier, Amsterdam, Vol. 1, 449-542. Evans, G, and S. Honkapohja (2001), Learning and Expectations, Princeton University Press, New Jersey. Evans, G, and B. McGough (2003), ``Stable Sunspot Solutions in Model with Predetermined Variables,'' Manuscript, University of Oregon, Forthcoming Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. Gali, J. and T. Monacelli (2004), ``Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy,'' CREI, Manuscript. Keynes, J. M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, Macmillan, London. Kimbrough, K. (1986), ``The Optimal Quantity of Money Rule in the Theory of Public Finance,'' Journal of Monetary Economics, 18, 277-284. Lizondo, J. (1991), ``Real Exchange Rate Targets, Nominal Exchange Rate Policies, and Inflation,'' Revista de Análisis Económico, 6, 5-22. Marcet, A., and T. Sargent (1989), ``Convergence of Least-Square Learning Mechanisms in Self-Referential Linear Stochastic Models,'' Journal of Economic Theory, 48, 337-368. McCallum, B. (1983), ``On Nonuniqueness in Linear Rational Expectations Moldels: An Attempt at Perspective,'' Journal of Monetary Economics, 11, 134-168. Montiel, A. and J. Ostry (1991), ``Macroeconomic Consequences of Real Exchange Rate Targeting in Developing Economies,'' IMF Staff Papers, 38, 872-900. Preston, B. (2003), ``Learning About Monetary Policy Rules when Long-Horizon Expectations Matter,'' Manuscript, Columbia University. Rotemberg, J. (1982), ''Sticky Prices in the United States,``Journal of Political Economy, 90(6), 1187-1211. Rotemberg, J. and M. Woodford (1999), ``Interest-Rate Rules in an Estimated Sticky-Price Model,'' in Monetary Policy Rules, edited by John B. Taylor, Chicago, National Bureau of Economic Research. Schmitt-Grohé, S. and M. Uribe (2001), ``Stabilization Policy and the Costs of Dollarization,'' Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 33, 482-509. Uribe, M. (2003), ``Real Exchange Rate Targeting and Macroeconomic Instability,'' University of Pennsylvania, Manuscript, Journal of International Economics, Forthcoming. Woodford, M. (2003), Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Princeton University Press, New Jersey. Zanna, L. F. (2003a), ``Interest Rate Rules and Multiple Equilibria in the Small Open Economy: The Role of Non-Traded Goods,'' IFDP #785, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Zanna, L. F. (2003b), ``International Economics, Monetary Rules and Multiple Equilibria'' Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Pennsylvania. Footnotes1. See Dornbusch (1980,1982), Adams and Gros (1986), Lizondo (1991), Montiel and Ostry (1991) and Calvo et al. (1995), among others. Return to text 2. This idea is not specific to PPP rules. In fact the idea that a rule that leads to indeterminacy of equilibrium may be seen as undesiderable has been emphasized by recent studies about interest rate rules. See Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2001), Carlstrom and Fuerst (2001), Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000), Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) and Woodford (2003) among others. Return to text 3. Bullard and Mitra (2002) have emphasized the importance of this point in the interest rate rule literature. Return to text 4. Henceforth we will use the terms `` learnability'', `` E-stability'' and `` expectational stability'' interchangeably in this paper. Return to text 5. Evans and Honkapoja (1999, 2001) have argued that a unique equilibrium and sunspot equilibria are not `` fragile'' if they are learnable in the sense of E-stability. Technically what they propose is to assume that agents in the model initially do not have rational expectations but are endowed with a mechanism to form forecasts using recursive learning algorithms and previous data from the economy. Then they develop some E-stability conditions which govern whether or not a given rational expectations equilibrium is aymptotically stable under least squares learning. Return to text 6. From now on we will use the terms `` multiple equilibria'' and `` real indeterminacy'' (a `` unique equilibrium'' and `` real determinacy'') interchangeably. By real indeterminacy we mean a situation in which the behavior of one or more (real) variables of the model is not pinned down by the model. This situation implies that there are multiple equilibria and opens the possibility of the existence of sunspot equilibria. Return to text 7. This fundamental solution is also well-known as the Minimal State Variable solution. See McCallum (1983). Return to text 8. The common factor representation is an alternative representation of a Rational Expectations Equilibria. See Evans and Honkapoja (1986). Return to text 9. Dornbusch (1980,1982) uses a Mundell and Fleming small open economy model with sticky wages á la Taylor and finds that the aformentioned PPP rule affects the output price-level stability trade-off through two different channels. On one hand, it tries to maintain constant the real exchange rate stabilizing net exports and therefore the demand side. On the other hand, it affects the supply side by its effect on the price of imported intermediate goods. Dornbusch shows that in such a model if the economy is hit by supply shocks then the price volatility always increases with tighter PPP rules. If the demand channel dominates the supply channel then the PPP rule reduces the volatility of output. But if the supply channel dominates the demand channel then the volatility of output is increased. Return to text 10. The set-up of this model is very similar to Uribe (2003) and Zanna (2003a). However we endogenize labor in both sectors and introduce technology shocks. Moreover we use specific functional forms to be able to convey the main message of this paper. In particular we assume separability in terms of both types of consumption. A CES utility function will not affect the qualitative results of this paper but will make the derivation of our analytical results cumbersome. Return to text 11. For the first part of the paper we will assume that agents have rational expectations. However for the E-stability analysis we will relax this assumption. Return to text 12. Benhabib et al. (2001a,b) and Dupor (2001) also follow this approach to model price stickiness. An alternative approach follows Calvo (1983). Our results are invariant to this approach. Return to text 13. We follow Woodford (2003) to construct the budget constraint of the representative agent. Return to text 14. This price is equal to its output cost (=1) plus a term that is a function of the opportunity cost of holding wealth in monetary form. Return to text 15. Note that as a consequence of the aforementioned contingent claims that completely span the uncertainty about productivity shocks the model abstracts from wealth effects due to current account imbalances. In this respect the model is similar to the ones in Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2001) and Gali and Monacelli (2004). Return to text 16. We would have derived a similar augmented Phillips curve if we had follow Calvo's (1983) approach. Return to text 17. Note that the spirit of the PPP
rule and the assumption that 18. Observe that we have not
included equation
19. Here we assume that
20. It is important to remember that in the log-linearized set-up all the variables are expressed as deviations from their steady state level. Return to text 21. It is possible to do the same
exercise with respect to other structural parameters such as the
share of labor in the production function (
22. Note that for this exercise we do not need to assign values to all the parameters. We only present the parametrization of the relevant parameters. Return to text 23. There is no clear consensus about the value that this parameter must take in emerging economies. One of the reasons is the lack of studies that have tried to estimate Phillips curves for these economies and that may give information about possible values for this parameter. Even for an industrialized economy such as Canada, this parameter varies between 2.80 and 44.07, depending on the model specification (type of nominal and real rigidities). See Dib (2001). Return to text 24. See Zanna (2003b). Return to text 25. The idea of expectation driven fluctuations dates back to Keynes (1936). Return to text 26. It is important to observe that for models with multiple stationary equilibria this statement lacks of technical formality. As pointed out by Evans and McGough (2003) for a model with multiple equilibria, a rational expectations equilibrium may have different representations. Therefore one should not strictly speak of learnable rational expectations equilibrium, but whether a rational expectations equilibrium representation is learnable (E-stable). Return to text 27. The Minimal State Variable (MSV) solution according to McCallum (1983). Return to text 28. Observe that this definition
suggests that to prove E-stability of a fixed point corresponds to
prove that all the eigenvalues of the matrix of derivatives
29. The proof of learnability of common factor representations of sunspot equilibria in this paper also goes over this methodology. Return to text 30. Note that strictly speaking
since we are assuming that the economy starts at ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() 31. Note that
NOT introducing the constant 32. Forward-looking PPP rules defined in terms of the expected future real exchange rate still open the possibility of sunspot equilibria as shown in Zanna (2003b). Return to text 33. This is also the specification in Montiel and Ostry (1991). Return to text 34. See Zanna (2003b). Return to text 35. Under real indeterminacy it is
also possible to prove that there is an equilibrium characterized
by fundamental solution (56) with
36. Excluding a constant
37. One can analyze either of the
forms because the eigenvalues of 38. Note that
39. One can analyze either of the
forms because the eigenvalues of This version is optimized for use by screen readers. A printable pdf version is available. |