Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
International Finance Discussion Papers
Number 869, August 2006 --- Screen Reader Version*
NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.
Abstract:
This paper analyzes panel data inference in predictive regressions with endogenous and nearly persistent regressors. The standard fixed effects estimator is shown to suffer from a second order bias; analytical results, as well as Monte Carlo evidence, show that the bias and resulting size distortions can be severe. New estimators, based on recursive demeaning as well as direct bias correction, are proposed and methods for dealing with cross sectional dependence in the form of common factors are also developed. Overall, the results show that the econometric issues associated with predictive regressions when using time-series data to a large extent also carry over to the panel case. However, practical solutions are more readily available when using panel data. The results are illustrated with an application to predictability in international stock indices.
Keywords: Cross-sectional dependence; Panel data; Pooled regression; Predictive regression; Stock return predictability.
JEL classification: C22, C23, G1.
Predictive regressions are important tools for evaluating and testing economic models. Although tests of stock return predictability, and the related market efficiency hypothesis, are probably the most common application, many rational expectations models can be tested in a similar manner (Mankiw and Shapiro, 1986). Traditionally, forecasting regressions have been evaluated in time-series frameworks. However, with the increased availability of data, in particular international financial and macroeconomic data, it becomes natural to extend the single time-series framework to a panel data setting.
It has gradually been discovered that the apparently simple linear regression model most often used for evaluating predictability in fact raises some very tough econometric issues. The high degree of persistence found in many predictor variables, such as the earnings- or dividend-price ratios in the prototypical stock return forecasting regression, is at the root of most econometric problems associated with predictive regressions. The near persistence of the regressors, coupled with a strong contemporaneous correlation between the innovations in the regressor and the regressand, causes standard OLS estimates to be inefficient and normal tests to have the wrong size. If the regressor is a unit-root process, the predictive regression becomes a cointegrating relationship and well established methods for dealing with endogenous regressors can be used. However, if the regressor is not a pure unit-root process, but rather a so called near-unit-root process, standard cointegration methods can yield misleading results (c.f. Cavanagh et al., 1995 and Elliot, 1998).2
In this paper, I analyze econometric inference in predictive regressions in a panel data setting, when the regressors are nearly persistent and endogenous. The main contributions are the derivations of the asymptotic properties of pooled estimators in forecasting equations and the proposal of new procedures to deal with the bias effects arising from the persistence and endogeneity of the regressors. New results for controlling for the effects of common factors in panels are also derived. The methods developed in the paper are used to test for stock-return predictability in a panel of international stock returns.
By pooling the data, the econometric issues encountered in the time-series case can, to some extent, be dealt with more easily. Intuitively, persistent regressors cause no problems when they are exogenous. When pooling the data, independent cross-sectional information dilutes the endogeneity effects, and thus potentially alleviates the bias effects seen in the time-series case. This intuition holds when no individual intercepts, or fixed effects, are allowed in the specification. In this case, the standard pooled estimator has an asymptotically normal distribution; the summing up over the cross-section in the pooled estimator eliminates the usual near unit-root asymptotic distributions found in the time-series case. It follows immediately that test statistics have standard distributions and normal inference can be performed.
However, when fixed effects are allowed for, the asymptotic properties of the pooled estimator change. The time-series demeaning of the data, which is implicit in a fixed effects estimation, causes the fixed effects estimator to suffer from a second order bias that invalidates inference from standard test-statistics. To correct for this bias, I develop an estimator based on the idea of recursive demeaning (e.g. Moon and Phillips, 2000, and Sul et al., 2005). When demeaning each time-series in the panel, information after time is used to form the time regressor; this induces a correlation between the lagged value of the demeaned regressor, used in the estimation of the predictive regression, and the error term in the forecasting equation, which gives rise to the second order bias in the fixed effects estimator. By using information only up till time in the demeaning of the regressor and only information after time in the demeaning of the dependent variable, the distortive effects arising from standard demeaning are eliminated. The estimator based on recursively demeaned data is shown to have an asymptotically normal distribution and standard inference can again be performed.
Although the estimator based on recursive demeaning is asymptotically normally distributed, it gives up some efficiency by disregarding parts of the data in the demeaning process. An alternative approach to control for the bias in the standard fixed effects estimator is to directly estimate the bias term and subtract it from the original estimator. Monte Carlo simulations show that such a correction works very well in practice, and produces unbiased estimators as well as correctly sized tests with good power. This bias corrected fixed effects estimator thus provides a simple and relatively efficient way of dealing with the bias and size distortions induced by the near persistence and endogeneity of the forecasting variables.
The overall conclusion from the theoretical results and the supporting Monte Carlo simulations is that, in the typical panel data case, persistent and endogenous regressors will cause standard inference to be biased. In the time-series case, this result is well established and the results in this paper show that equal caution is required when working with panel data. However, unlike the time-series case, bias correction methods can be implemented in a relatively straightforward manner and normally distributed test-statistics can be achieved. Unbiased point estimates are also easily calculated, in contrast to the time-series case where the popular Bonferroni bound methods lead to correctly sized tests but not unique unbiased point estimates (Cavanagh et al., 1995, and Campbell and Yogo, 2005).
Another econometric issue that arises in the analysis of panels of financial or macroeconomic data is the potential presence of common factors. The standard panel data assumption of cross-sectional independence is often too restrictive, and I show how the framework in this paper can be extended to a setting where common factors are present in the data. These methods follow the work of Pesaran (2006) and extend his methods to a setting with nearly integrated regressors.
As an illustration of the methods derived in this paper, I consider the classical issue of stock return predictability. I use an international panel of returns from 18 different stock indices and the corresponding dividend- and earnings-price ratios, as well as the book-to-market values. The empirical results from the forecasting regressions with stock returns illustrate well the theoretical results derived in the paper. Based on the results from the standard fixed effects estimator, the evidence in favour of return predictability is very strong, using either of the three predictor variables. However, when using the robust methods developed here, the evidence disappears almost completely.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model, while Sections 3 and 4 derive the main asymptotic properties of the pooled estimators. The finite sample properties of the procedures developed in this paper are analyzed through Monte Carlo experiments in Section 5. Some generalizations of the econometric model are considered in Section 6, and Section 7 contains the empirical application to stock return predictability. Section 8 concludes and technical proofs are found in the appendix.
Following the work of Phillips and Moon (1999), results for the panel estimators are derived using sequential limits, which usually implies first keeping the cross-sectional dimension, , fixed and letting the time-series dimension, , go to infinity, and then letting go to infinity. Such sequential convergence is denoted . Subject to potential rate restrictions, such as , these results can generally be shown to hold as and go to infinity jointly, denoted , by showing that the sufficient conditions in Phillips and Moon (1999) are satisfied; proofs of such joint convergence are not pursued here, however. Otherwise, standard notation is used. denotes a Brownian motion with covariance matrix , signifies weak convergence, and denotes convergence in probability.
Consider a panel model with dependent variables , , , and the corresponding vector of regressors, , where is an vector. The behavior of and are modelled as follows,
This model is a panel analogue of the time-series models studied by Mankiw and Shapiro (1986), Cavanagh et al. (1995), Stambaugh (1999), Jansson and Moreira (2004), Lewellen (2004), and Campbell and Yogo (2005).
1.
2. where and
.
3. , and
4. for all and .
Assumption1 specifies that the innovation processes follow a martingale difference sequence (mds) with finite fourth moments. The regressor can be endogenous in the sense that and may be contemporaneously correlated. The common factors, , are assumed independent of the specific error components, and Assumption 2 specifies that the factor loadings are distributed independently of other random variables in the model. At the expense of some extra notation, the model could allow for a more general time-series structure in the innovation process ; the results in the paper would carry through with virtually no changes. The mds assumption for the errors in the dependent variables, , is standard in predictive regressions, and is often based on some orthogonality condition from an underlying rational expectations model. For instance, in financial forecasting regressions the mds assumption is motivated by the efficient markets hypothesis. The rank condition in Assumption 3 is used for identification in the estimation procedures that control for the common factors. It essentially states that all information regarding the common factors in the data can potentially be recovered from the innovation processes of the regressors. This condition turns out to be less restrictive than it seems, since it is the factors in the regressor errors that play the key role in the asymptotic properties of the pooled estimators. That is, a common factor that is only present in the dependent variable will not affect the analysis in any fundamental way. This is analyzed in more detail later in the paper.
It is also assumed that all the time-series in the panel share the same auto-regressive root, . This assumption is imposed due to the presence of the common factors in the regressors, which would make it difficult to allow for heterogenous persistence. The effects of relaxing this assumption are briefly discussed later in the paper. Given a common auto-regressive root, the process can be expressed in a convenient component form,
(3) |
Under Assumption 1, by standard arguments (Phillips and Solo, 1992), , where denote a dimensional Brownian motion. Further, by the results in Phillips (1987,1988), it follows that as , , where and . Analogous results hold for the time-series demeaned data, , with replaced by ; when there is no risk of confusion, the dependence of and on will be suppressed. The following lemma summarizes the key asymptotic results used in the paper.
(a) where , , and is the field generated by .
(b)
(c) where and
(d)
(e)
(f) where and
To understand the basic properties of the pooled estimator of , it is instructive to start with analyzing the case when there are no common factors in the data. That is, let and , for all . To estimate the parameter consider first the traditional pooled estimator when there are no individual effects, i.e. when for all .3 The pooled estimator is given by
(4) |
The pooled estimator of is thus asymptotically normally distributed and the limiting distribution depends on and . To perform inference, estimates of these parameters are required. Let , , and . The estimator is thus the panel equivalent of HAC estimators for long-run variances.
Standard tests can now be performed. For instance, the null hypothesis , for some , can be tested using a test. Let . Using the results derived above, it follows easily that under the null-hypothesis,
(6) |
Thus, when there are no fixed effects in the pooled regression, inference in the panel case becomes trivial since the pooled estimator is asymptotically normally distributed. This is in contrast with the time-series case where the OLS estimator has a non-normal asymptotic distribution which depends on unknown nuisance parameters.
In the above analysis, the individual intercepts were all assumed to be equal to zero. This section considers the effects on the pooled estimator when the are no longer zero and are allowed to vary across the panel.
Let and denote the time-series demeaned data. That is, and . The fixed effects pooled estimator, which allows for individual intercepts, is then given by
(7) |
(8) |
(9) |
(10) | ||
(11) |
The second order bias arises because the demeaning process induces a correlation between the innovation processes and the demeaned regressors .4 Intuitively, and are correlated because, in the demeaning of , information available after time is used. At the expense of some efficiency, one solution is therefore to use recursive demeaning of and (e.g. Moon and Phillips, 2000, and Sul et al., 2005). That is, define
and | (13) |
(14) |
(15) |
(16) |
To perform inference, let , , and . The test and Wald-test based on and will satisfy the usual properties and the results follow in the same manner as above.
The estimator gives up some efficiency through the recursive demeaning process. A more efficient approach would be to directly estimate the bias term in (12) and subtract it from the standard pooled estimator. A simple biased corrected estimator is given by
An estimate of is easy to obtain by averaging the estimates of obtained from time-series regressions. As discussed below, it is possible to consistently estimate using panel data, unlike in the time-series case.
The estimator proposed above relies on an estimate of . Moon and Phillips (2000) show how can be consistently estimated in equation (2) when is a scalar. The diagonal of can, of course, be estimated by the individual univariate estimates; thus, if one restricts to be diagonal, then an estimate of a matrix can be obtained using the methods of Moon and Phillips (2000).
Consider the case of a scalar , and assume that is generated according to equation (2). Noting that it is natural to consider estimators of the form . The pooled estimator of is given by,
It is beyond the scope of this paper to formally consider the effects of common factors in the data on the estimator . However, Monte Carlo simulations not reported in the paper indicate that it also remains unbiased in the presence of common factors.
I now return to the general setup with common factors in the data. The following theorem summarizes the asymptotic properties of the standard pooled estimator, as well as the fixed effects estimator, when there are common factors.
Thus, in the presence of the general factor structure outlined in Assumptions 1 and 2, the standard pooled estimator exhibits a non-standard limiting distribution, although it is still consistent; standard tests can therefore not be used. Similarly, the limiting behavior of the fixed effects estimator is determined by the bias term arising from the time-series demeaning of the data, as well as an additional term that stems from the common factors in the data.
Based on the methods of Pesaran (2006), I propose an estimator that is more robust to cross-sectional dependence in the data. Write the model in matrix form,
(22) | ||
(23) |
The idea of Pesaran (2006) is to project the data onto the space orthogonal to the common factors, thereby removing the cross sectional dependence from the data used in the estimation. However, since the factors in are not observed in practice, an indirect approach is required.
Consider the following estimator of ,
(24) |
To form a better understanding behind the functioning of the above estimator, let , and . Also, let and Observe that,
(27) |
(28) |
The estimator thus achieves a convergence rate and an asymptotic mixed normal distribution. The mixed normality in this case arises from the common factors, which leads to a mixed normal rather than a normal distribution as in the case above with no common factors; a similar result is also noted in Jin (2004). Andrews (2005) provides an extensive discussion on convergence with common shocks. This theorem also extends the results for stationary data in Pesaran (2006) to the nearly integrated case, although using a somewhat different definition of the matrix. Allowing for fixed effects in the arguments, it is easy to show the following result.
(29) |
(30) |
(31) |
(32) |
The fixed effects transformation thus has an identical bias effect on the estimator that controls for common factors, and can also be corrected in an identical manner. Similarly, it could also be shown that using recursive demeaning on the data projected onto the cross-sectional means would be asymptotically mixed normally distributed, although these results are omitted here. and thus provide pooled estimators for predictive regressions that are asymptotically mixed normally distributed in the presence of common factors and with the allowance for fixed effects. Standard tests and Wald-tests can therefore be used; the variance-covariance matrix of or can be estimated in an analogous manner as described above for the case with no common factors, by simply using the defactored data. The practical implementation of , or , is thus very simple: Premultiply the data by , and use the resulting variables in the original procedures for and . Note that this also automatically facilitates the correct estimation of , which now represents the correlation between the cross-sectionally independent errors, and , rather than the correlation between the total innovation processes in the regressors and regressand.
The key assumption in deriving the results in Theorem 4 was the rank condition in Assumption 3. It essentially allows for the whole factor structure to be revealed through the innovations in the regressor variables alone. While this is a convenient assumption, since it does not require first stage estimates of the innovations in the regressand, it is also potentially limiting since it effectively restricts the factors in the dependent variable to be a subset of the factors in the regressors. However, it is easy to show that additional factors in the regressand do not fundamentally alter the above results.
Consider the following model, which is a generalization of the original model in equations (1) and (2),
(35) |
The limiting distribution changes but remains mixed normal and inference can be performed in an identical manner using standard test-statistics. The procedures derived in the previous subsection are thus robust to additional factors in the dependent variable.
To evaluate the small sample properties of the panel data estimators proposed in this paper, a Monte Carlo study is performed. In the first experiment, the properties of the point estimates are considered. Equations (1) and (2) are simulated for the case with a single regressor. The innovations are drawn from normal distributions with mean zero, unit variance, and correlations and ; there is no cross-sectional dependence. The slope parameter is set equal to and the local-to-unity parameter is set to . The sample size is given by . The small value of is chosen in order to reflect the fact that most forecasting regressions are used to test a null of , and any plausible alternative is often close to zero. The intercepts are set equal to zero but individual effects are still fitted for all the estimators, except the standard pooled one, in order to evaluate the second-order bias effects arising from demeaning. All results are based on 10,000 repetitions.
Four different estimators are considered: the pooled estimator with no fixed effects, , the fixed effects estimator using standard demeaning, , the recursively demeaned pooled estimator, , and the bias corrected estimator . The bias correction in the estimator is estimated by , where is the panel estimate of the local-to-unity parameter and is estimated as with the covariance between the residuals from a time-series estimation of equation (1) and the quasi-differenced regressors, . In general, the standard pooled estimator does not work well when the differ across , but is used as a comparison here.
The results are shown in Figure 1. All estimators, except , are virtually unbiased. The estimator , which uses standard demeaning to account for individual effects, exhibits a rather substantial bias when the absolute value of the correlation is large. The recursively demeaned estimator, , suffers from a lack of efficiency, but it is well centered around the true value.
The second part of the Monte Carlo study concerns the size and power of the pooled tests. The same setup as above is used but, in order to calculate the power of the tests, the slope coefficient now varies between and . Figure 2 shows the average rejection rates of the percent two-sided tests, evaluating a null of ; that is, the power curves of the tests. Panel A in Table 1 shows the average sizes of the nominal percent tests under the null hypothesis of for the two sided tests corresponding to the four different estimators considered above. Again, the results are based on 10,000 repetitions.
Apart from the test based on the standard fixed effects estimator, all tests perform well in terms of size, although they all tend to over reject the null hypothesis somewhat. Table 1 and the power curves in Figure 2 clearly show the effects of the second order bias in the fixed effects estimator. The three other tests all exhibit decent power properties although the test based on has lower power than the bias corrected estimator.
In summary, the simulation evidence shows the importance of controlling for the second order bias arising from fitting individual intercepts in the pooled regression; the estimator based on recursive demeaning appears to do well and results in test-statistics with correct size and decent power properties. The bias correction of the fixed effects estimator also appears to work well, producing nearly unbiased results and correctly sized tests with good power. Overall, the simulations confirm the analytical results previously derived.
In this section, I repeat the Monte Carlo experiments above, with the exception that there is now a common factor in the innovations. In particular, equations (1) and (2) are now simulated with a single regressor and a single common factor , drawn from a standard normal distribution. The factor loadings, and , are also normally distributed with means of minus one and plus one, respectively, and standard deviations equal to in both cases. The innovations in the returns and regressor processes are formed as and , respectively, where are drawn from standard normal distributions; the scaling by is performed in order to achieve an approximate unit variance in the innovations which enables easier comparison with the cross-sectionally independent case. As before, the correlation between and is set to and . Note that no longer represents the overall correlation between the innovations, but rather that between the cross-sectionally independent parts of the innovations. In addition, I allow to vary across according to a normal distribution with mean and standard deviation equal to . Otherwise, the setup is identical to that used in the case with no common factors. Again, all results are based on repetitions.
The results are shown in Panels B and C of Table 1 and in Figures 3-6. Panel B in Table 1 and Figures 3 and 4 show the outcomes of the Monte Carlo experiments when the model generated with common factors is estimated using the standard estimators , and , that do not control for cross-sectional dependence; since now varies across the panel, the standard pooled estimator without fixed effects is not considered. Figure 3 shows that and are still fairly unbiased, in accordance with the asymptotic result in Theorem 3, but they are much more variable than in the case with no common factors and exhibit a non-normal distribution. The real downside from not controlling for the cross-sectional dependence is seen in the size of the tests displayed in Panel B of Table 1 and in the power curves in Figure 3. It is clear that when the common factors are ignored in the estimation process, the actual size of the corresponding tests is very far from the nominal size of percent, with rejection rates between and percent under the null.
Panel C in Table 1 and Figures 5 and 6 show the same results for the estimators , and , which control for the common factors; represents the estimator with recursive demeaning using defactored data. The distributions of the point estimates, as seen in Figure 5, are now much better behaved and normal looking, as well as much more peaked than in Figure 3. The tests also possess better size and power properties, although there is a slight tendency to over-reject when is large in absolute numbers. As before, the standard fixed effects estimator exhibits a finite sample bias and extremely poor size properties.
In summary, the estimator , and , which were designed to control for cross-sectional dependence, appear to work reasonably well in small samples, although there is a small bias and over-rejection when is large. Compared to the estimators that do not take the common factors into account, there is a huge improvement, however.
One dimension along which the model in this paper can be generalized is to allow the auto-regressive root to vary across , such that each time-series possesses a root , where may be modelled as a random variable. Most of the analysis will carry through in this setting, with the limiting expressions being expectations also over the . Problems arise in the bias correcting exercises, however. For instance, the bias-corrected fixed effects estimator, , relies on an estimate of , but when the are no longer identical, panel methods cannot be used to form estimates of the individual . In particular, an estimate of is needed. An approximate estimate of is given by . Hjalmarsson (2005) shows that, in general, the pooled estimator of Moon and Phillips (2000) will be an upward biased estimator of when the are non-identical. By Jensen's inequality, , so the bias term will be underestimated by this approximation. The upward bias in the estimate of , based on the Moon and Phillips (2000) estimator, will thus to some extent counteract the downward bias induced by Jensen's inequality. Alternatively, the estimator , which is based on recursive demeaning, could be used instead since it requires no knowledge of the .
The heterogenous also cause some difficulties when dealing with the common factors. When the are not identical, it is no longer possible to write and the subsequent analysis becomes more involved and is outside the scope of this paper.
To illustrate the methods developed in this paper, I consider the question of stock-return predictability in an international data set. The data are obtained from the MSCI database and consist of a panel of total returns for stock markets in 18 different countries and three corresponding forecasting variables: the dividend- and earnings-price ratios as well as the book-to-market values. With varying success, all three of these variables have been used extensively in tests of stock-return predictability for U.S. data (e.g. Campbell and Shiller, 1988, Fama and French 1988, Lewellen, 2004, and Campbell and Yogo, 2005), and to a lesser degree in international data (e.g. Ang and Bekaert, 2003, and Campbell, 2003). All three of these forecasting variables are highly persistent, and since they are all valuation ratios, their innovations are likely to be highly correlated with the innovations to the returns process. The data are on a monthly basis and the returns data span the period 1970.1 to 2002.12, whereas not all forecasting variables are available for this whole time-period, or for all countries. In particular, I have data for stock indices in the following countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Hong Kong, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Singapore, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK, and the USA.5 The dividend price ratio is available for all countries except Hong Kong and for the entire sample period from 1970.1 onwards. The earnings price ratio is available for all countries except Italy and Switzerland, from 1974.12 onwards. The book-to-market value is available for all countries from 1974.12 onwards. The forecasting variables are the valuation ratios provided by MSCI, with earnings representing cash earnings.
All returns and forecasting variables are expressed in U.S. dollars, and excess returns over the 1-month U.S. T-bill rate are calculated. The dependent variable in all regressions is thus excess returns over the U.S. short rate. Finally, all data are log-transformed.
The results from the pooled forecasting regressions are shown in Table 2. Panel A displays the results when there is no control for common factors, whereas the results in Panel B are based on the methods developed for dealing with cross-sectional dependence.
The estimates of and the estimates of the correlation between the innovations in the returns and predictor processes show that the forecasting variables are clearly near-unit processes and highly endogenous. Starting with the results in Panel A, the standard pooled fixed effects estimator, , delivers highly significant estimates and clearly rejects the null-hypothesis of no predictability. Given the high persistence and endogeneity found in the data, however, these results are likely to be upward biased and as seen from the estimates based on the estimator using recursive demeaning, and the bias corrected fixed effects estimator, , the significance disappears when controlling for the bias induced by the time-series demeaning in the fixed effects estimator.
In Panel B, the regression estimates are based on the methods controlling for common factors across the different markets. For the dividend price ratio, the standard fixed effects estimate is now even more significant, but the statistics for the two other estimates, and , are in fact both negative and insignificant. For the earnings-price ratio and the book-to-market ratio, the results from the fixed effects estimator become less strong when controlling for common factors and the two other estimators are both negative for both variables. Overall, the case for stock-return predictability in this international data set, using either of the three predictor variables, must be considered very weak.
The empirical results shown here again illustrate the difficulties of performing inference in regressions with persistent and endogenous variables, and that these difficulties also prevail when a panel of data, rather than a single time-series, is available. Indeed, judging by the vast difference between the estimates and test statistics resulting from the standard fixed effects estimator and those from the robust estimators, it is clear that the bias effects can be as large in panel estimations as in time-series regressions.
A panel data extension of the traditional linear forecasting model is considered. I analyze a setup where the regressors are nearly persistent processes and potentially endogenous, which captures the essential characteristics of many empirical situations. It is shown that when no fixed effects are present, the standard pooled estimator is asymptotically normal and standard inference can be performed; the cross-sectional information effectively dilutes the endogeneity effects that are present in the standard time-series case and as the cross-sectional dimension grows large, these effects disappear altogether. However, when individual intercepts, or fixed effects, are estimated, the endogeneity of the regressors cause the pooled estimator to have a second order bias. To control for these effects, an alternative pooled estimator based on the concept of recursive demeaning is proposed. Alternatively, a bias corrected version of the standard fixed effects estimator is also proposed. Following the work of Peseran (2006), I also extend the results to a setting that allows for cross-sectional dependence in the form of common factors in the panel.
Monte Carlo evidence suggests that the proposed estimators have good finite sample properties and also shows that, in a typical setup, the distortions to the standard fixed effects estimator can be quite severe when the regressors are endogenous. An application to predictability in international stock-returns also illustrates that failure to account for the endogeneity and persistence in the regressors can lead to highly biased inference.
The results in this paper provide an important extension to the existing literature on time-series methods for predictive regressions and show that a careful analysis of the impact of nearly persistent and endogenous regressors is required also in the panel data case.
1. and are of order
2. and are of order
3. and are of order
(b) Similarly, as
(c) Observe that
(d) As before, as
(e) As ,
(f) The result follows in an identical manner to that in (c).
2. Similar to above, as ,
3. follows directly from Lemma 2 in Pesaran (2006). Further, as
Panel A: No common factors
Estimator | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Panel B: Common factors with no correction
Estimator | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Panel C: Common factors using correction
Estimator | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: No correction for common factors
Variable | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel B: Correction for common factors
Variable | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1. I am very grateful to Peter Phillips for providing much useful advice. Other helpful comments have been provided by Don Andrews, Lennart Hjalmarsson, Randi Hjalmarsson, Yuichi Kitamura, Vadim Marmer, Alex Maynard, Taisuke Otsu, Robert Shiller, Kevin Song, Pär Österholm, as well as participants in the summer workshop and econometrics seminar at Yale University, the finance seminar at Göteborg University, and the European Summer Meeting of the Econometric Society in Vienna. Tel.: +1-202-452-2426; fax: +1-202-263-4850; email: [email protected]. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the author and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. Return to text
2. The literature on time-series forecasting regressions is very large. Some examples are Mankiw and Shapiro (1986), Nelson and Kim (1993), Goetzman and Jorion (1993), Cavanagh et al. (1995), Stambaugh (1999), Janson and Moreira (2004), Lewellen (2004), Polk et al. (2004), and Campbell and Yogo (2005). Many of these studies are primarily concerned with tests of stock-return predictability, although the results are generally applicable to more general forecasting regressions. Return to text
3. The results developed below also hold in the case with a common non-zero intercept . Return to text
4. The phenomenon is analogous to that found by Moon and Phillips (2000), in their estimation of local-to-unity roots in panels with incidental trends. Return to text
5. Hong Kong is, of course, not a country. Return to text
This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text