Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
International Finance Discussion Papers
Number 980, October, 2009--- Screen Reader
Version*
NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.
Abstract:
We study the impact that algorithmic trading, computers directly interfacing at high frequency with trading platforms, has had on price discovery and volatility in the foreign exchange market. Our dataset represents a majority of global interdealer trading in three major currency pairs in 2006 and 2007. Importantly, it contains precise observations of the size and the direction of the computer-generated and human-generated trades each minute. The empirical analysis provides several important insights. First, we find evidence that algorithmic trades tend to be correlated, suggesting that the algorithmic strategies used in the market are not as diverse as those used by non-algorithmic traders. Second, we find that, despite the apparent correlation of algorithmic trades, there is no evident causal relationship between algorithmic trading and increased exchange rate volatility. If anything, the presence of more algorithmic trading is associated with lower volatility. Third, we show that even though some algorithmic traders appear to restrict their activity in the minute following macroeconomic data releases, algorithmic traders increase their provision of liquidity over the hour following each release. Fourth, we find that non-algorithmic order flow accounts for a larger share of the variance in exchange rate returns than does algorithmic order flow. Fifth, we find evidence that supports the recent literature that proposes to depart from the prevalent assumption that liquidity providers in limit order books are passive.
Keywords: Algorithmic trading, volatility, liquidity provision, private information
JEL classification:F3, G12, G14, G15
The use of algorithmic trading, where computer algorithms directly manage the trading process at high frequency, has become common in major financial markets in recent years, beginning in the U.S. equity market more than 15 years ago. There has been widespread interest in understanding the potential impact of algorithmic trading on market dynamics, as some analysts have highlighted the potential for improved liquidity and more efficient price discovery while others have expressed concern that it may be a source of increased volatility and reduced liquidity, particularly in times of market stress. A number of articles and opinion pieces on the topic have recently appeared in the press, with most decrying practices used by some algorithmic traders in the equity market, and there have been calls for regulatory agencies in the United States and Europe to begin investigations.2 Despite this interest, there has been very little formal empirical research on algorithmic trading, primarily because of a lack of data where algorithmic trades are clearly identified. A notable exception is a recent paper by Hendershott, Jones, and Menkveld (2007), who get around the data constraint by using the flow of electronic messages on the NYSE as a proxy for algorithmic trading. They conclude that algorithmic trading on the NYSE, contrary to the pessimists' concerns, likely causes an improvement in market liquidity.3 In the foreign exchange market, there has been no formal empirical research on the subject. The adoption of algorithmic trading in the foreign exchange market is a far more recent phenomenon than in the equity market, as the two major interdealer electronic trading platforms only began to allow algorithmic trades a few years ago. Growth in algorithmic trading has been very rapid, however, and a majority of foreign exchange transactions in the interdealer market currently involve at least one algorithmic counterparty.
In algorithmic trading (AT), computers directly interface with trading platforms, placing orders without immediate human intervention. The computers observe market data and possibly other information at very high frequency, and, based on a built-in algorithm, send back trading instructions, often within milliseconds. A variety of algorithms are used: for example, some look for arbitrage opportunities, including small discrepancies in the exchange rates between three currencies; some seek optimal execution of large orders at the minimum cost; and some seek to implement longer-term trading strategies in search of profits. Among the most recent developments in algorithmic trading, some algorithms now automatically read and interpret economic data releases, generating trading orders before economists have begun to read the first line.
The extreme speed of execution that AT allows and the potential that algorithmic trades may be highly correlated, perhaps as many institutions use similar algorithms, have been cited as reasons for concerns that AT may generate large price swings and market instability. On the other hand, the fact that some algorithms aim for optimal execution at a minimal price impact may be expected to lower volatility. In this paper, we investigate whether algorithmic ("computer") trades and non-algorithmic ("human") trades have different effects on the foreign exchange market. We first ask whether the presence of computer trades causes higher or lower volatility and whether computers increase or reduce liquidity during periods of market stress. We then study the relative importance of human and computer trades in the process of price discovery and re-visit the assumption that liquidity providers are "uninformed."
We formally investigate these issues using a novel dataset consisting of two years (2006 and 2007) of minute-by-minute trading data from EBS in three currency pairs: the euro-dollar, dollar-yen, and euro-yen. The data represent the vast majority of global spot interdealer transactions in these exchange rates. An important feature of the data is that the volume and direction of human and computer trades each minute are explicitly identified, allowing us to measure their respective impacts.
We first show some evidence that computer trades are more highly correlated with each other than human trades, suggesting that the strategies used by computers are not as diverse as those used by humans. But the high correlation of computer trades does not necessarily translate into higher volatility. In fact, we find next that there is no evident causal relationship between AT and increased market volatility. If anything, the presence of more algorithmic trading appears to lead to lower market volatility, although the economic magnitude of the effect is small. In order to account for the potential endogeneity of algorithmic trading with regards to volatility, we instrument for the actual level of algorithmic trading with the installed capacity for algorithmic trading in the EBS system at a given time.
Next, we study the relative provision of market liquidity by computers and humans at the times of the most influential U.S. macroeconomic data release, the nonfarm payroll report. We find that, as a share of total market-making activity, computers tend to pull back slightly at the precise time of the release but then increase their presence in the following hour. This result suggests that computers do provide liquidity during periods of market stress.
Finally, we estimate return-order flow dynamics using a structural VAR framework in the tradition of Hasbrouck (1991a). The VAR estimation provides two important insights. First, we find that human order flow accounts for much of the long-run variance in exchange rate returns in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen exchange rate markets, i.e., humans appear to be the " informed" traders in these markets. In contrast, in the euro-yen exchange rate market, computers and humans appear to be equally " informed." In this cross-rate, we believe that computers have a clear advantage over humans in detecting and reacting more quickly to triangular arbitrage opportunities, where the euro-yen price is briefly out of line with prices in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen markets. Second, we find that, on average, computers or humans that trade on a price posted by a computer do not impact prices quite as much as they do when they trade on a price posted by a human. One possible interpretation of this result is that computers tend to place limit orders more strategically than humans do. This empirical evidence supports the literature that proposes to depart from the prevalent assumption that liquidity providers in limit order books are passive.4
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we introduce the EBS exchange rate data, describing the evolution over time of algorithmic trading and the pattern of interaction between human and algorithmic traders. In Section 3 we study the correlation of algorithmic trades. In Section 4 we analyze the relationship between algorithmic trading and exchange rate volatility. In Section 5 we discuss the provision of liquidity by computers and humans at the time of a major data release. In Section 6 we report the results of the high-frequency VAR analysis. We conclude in Section 7. Some robustness results are presented in the Appendix.
Today, two electronic platforms process the vast majority of global interdealer spot trading in the major currency pairs, one offered by Reuters, and one offered by EBS.5 These platforms, which are both electronic limit order books, have become essential utilities for the foreign exchange market. Importantly, trading in each major currency pair has over time become very highly concentrated on only one of the two systems. Of the most traded currency pairs, the top two, euro-dollar and dollar-yen, trade primarily on EBS, while the third, sterling-dollar, trades primarily on Reuters. As a result, the reference price at any moment for, say, spot euro-dollar, is the current price on the EBS system, and all dealers across the globe base their customer and derivative quotes on that price. EBS controls the network and each of the terminals on which the trading is conducted. Traders can enter trading instructions manually, using an EBS keyboard, or, upon approval by EBS, via a computer directly interfacing with the system. The type of trader (human or computer) behind each trading instruction is recorded by EBS, allowing for our study.6
We have access to AT data from EBS from 2003 through 2007. We focus on the sample from 2006 and 2007, because, as we will show, algorithmic trades were a very small portion of total trades in the earlier years. In addition to the full 2006-2007 sample, we also consider a sub-sample covering the months of September, October, and November of 2007, when algorithmic trading played an even more important role than earlier in the sample.7 We study the three most-traded currency pairs on the EBS system: euro-dollar, dollar-yen, and euro-yen.
The quote data, at the one-second frequency, consist of the highest bid quote and the lowest ask quote on the EBS system in these currency pairs, from which we construct one-second mid-quote series and compute one-minute exchange rate returns; all the quotes are executable and therefore represent the true price at that moment. The transactions data are at the one-minute frequency and provide detailed information on the volume and direction of trades that can be attributed to computers and humans in each currency pair. Specifically, the transactions volume data are broken down into categories specifying the "maker" and "taker" of the trades (i.e., human or computer), and the direction of the trades (i.e., buy or sell the base currency), for a total of eight different combinations. That is, the first transaction category may specify, say, the minute-by-minute volume of trade that results from a human taker buying the base currency by "hitting" a quote posted by a human maker. We would record this activity as the human-human buy volume, with the aggressor (taker) of the trade buying the base currency. The human-human sell volume is defined analogously, as are the other six buy and sell volumes that arise from the remaining combinations of computers and humans acting as makers and takers.
From these eight types of buy and sell volumes, we can
construct, for each minute, trading volume and order flow measures
for each of the four possible pairs of human and computer makers
and takers: human-maker/human-taker ,
computer-maker/human-taker
,
human-maker/computer-taker
, and
computer-maker/computer-taker
.8 That is,
the sum of the buy and sell volumes for each pair gives the
volume of trade attributable to that particular combination of
maker and taker (which we symbolize as,
or
, for example). The difference
between the buy and sell volume for each pair gives us the order
flow attributable to that maker-taker combination (which we
symbolize simply as
or
, for
example). The sum of the four volumes,
, gives the total volume of
trade in the market. The sum of the four order flows,
, gives the total (market-wide)
order flow.9 Throughout the paper, we will use the
expression " order flow" to refer both to the market-wide order
flow and to the order flows from other possible decompositions,
with the distinction clearly indicated. Importantly, the data allow
us to consider order flow broken down by the type of trader who
initiated the trade, human-taker order flow
and computer-taker order flow
.
The main goal of this paper is to analyze the effect algorithmic
trading has on price discovery and volatility in the foreign
exchange market. In our exchange rate data as in other financial
data, the net of signed trades from the point of view of the takers
(the market-wide order flow) is highly positively correlated with
exchange rate returns, so that the takers are considered to be more
" informed" than the makers. Thus, in our analysis of the
relative effects of human and computer trades in the market, we
consider prominently the order flow decomposition into human-taker
order flow and computer-taker order flow. However, we also consider
two other decompositions in our work. We consider the most
disaggregated decomposition of order flow
, as this decomposition allows
us to study whether the liquidity suppliers, who are traditionally
assumed to be " uninformed", are posting quotes strategically.
This situation is more likely to arise in our data, which comes
from a pure limit order book market, than in data from a hybrid
market like the NYSE, because, as Parlour and Seppi (2008) point
out, the distinction between liquidity supply and liquidity demand
in limit order books is blurry.10 We also decompose the data by
maker type (human or computer) in order to study whether computers
or humans are providing liquidity during the release of public
information, which are periods of high exchange rate volatility
and, often, market stress.
In our analysis, we exclude data collected from Friday 17:00 through Sunday 17:00 New York time from our sample, as activity on the system during these " non-standard" hours is minimal and not encouraged by the foreign exchange community. We also drop certain holidays and days of unusually light volume: December 24-December 26, December 31-January 2, Good Friday, Easter Monday, Memorial Day, Labor Day, Thanksgiving and the following day, and July 4 (or, if this is on a weekend, the day on which the U.S. Independence Day holiday is observed).
We show summary statistics for the one-minute returns and order flow data in Table 1. This table contains a number of noteworthy features. First, order flow, whether in total, broken down by human and computer takers, or broken down into the 4 possible pairs of makers and takers, is serially positively correlated, which is consistent with some informed trading models. For example, Easley and O'Hara (1987) model a situation where sequences of large purchases (sales) arise when insiders with positive (negative) signals are present in the market. He and Wang (1995) also show that insiders with good (bad) news tend to buy (sell) repeatedly until their private information is revealed in the prices. The positive serial correlation in order flow is also consistent with strategic order splitting, i.e. a trader willing to buy for informational or non-informational reasons and splitting his order to reduce market impact. Second, the standard deviations of the various order flows differ by exchange rates, by type of taker and across maker/taker pairs. These differences will be important in the interpretation of the upcoming VAR analysis and variance decompositions.
We show in Figure 1, from 2003 through 2007 for our three major
currency pairs, the fraction of trading volume where at least one
of the two counterparties was an algorithmic trader, i.e.
as a fraction of total
volume.11 From its beginning in 2003, the
fraction of trading volume involving AT grew by the end of 2007 to
near 60% for euro-dollar, and dollar-yen trading, and to about 80%
for euro-yen. Figure 2 shows, for our three currency pairs, the
evolution over time of the four different possible types of trades
(i.e.
,
,
, and
as fractions of the
total volume). By the end of 2007, in the euro-dollar and
dollar-yen markets, human to human trades, in black, accounted for
slightly less than half of the volume, and computer to computer
trades, in green, for about ten to fifteen percent. In euro-dollar
and dollar-yen, we note that
and
are about equal to each other, i.e.
computers " take" prices posted by humans, in red, about as often
as humans take prices posted by market-making computers, in blue.
The story is different for the cross-rate, the euro-yen currency
pair. By the end of 2007, there were more computer to computer
trades than human to human trades. But the most common type of
trade was computers trading on prices posted by humans. We believe
this reflects computers taking advantage of short-lived triangular
arbitrage opportunities, where prices set in the euro-dollar and
dollar-yen markets are very briefly out of line with the euro-yen
cross rate. In interpreting our results later in the paper, we will
keep in mind that trading volume is largest in the euro-dollar and
dollar-yen markets, and that price discovery happens mostly in
those markets, not in the cross-rate. Our conclusions based on the
euro-dollar and dollar-yen markets will then be more easily
generalized than those based on the euro-yen market. Table 2 tabulates the
averages of the volume fractions shown in Figures 1 and 2, both for
the full 2006-2007 sample and the shorter three-month
sub-sample.
We first investigate the proposition that computers tend to have trading strategies that are more correlated than those of humans. Since the outset of the financial turmoil in the summer of 2007, articles in the financial press have suggested that AT programs tend to be similarly designed, leading them to take the same side of the market in times of high volatility and potentially exaggerating market movements.12
One such instance may have happened on August 16, 2007, a day of
very high volatility in the dollar-yen market. On that day, the
Japanese yen appreciated sharply against the U.S. dollar around
6:00 a.m. and 12:00 p.m. (NY time), as shown in Figure 3. The
figure also shows, for each 30-minute interval in the day,
computer-taker order flow
in the top panel and human-taker order flow
in the lower panel. The two sharp exchange rate
movements mentioned happened when computers, as a group,
aggressively sold dollars and bought yen. We note that computers,
during these episodes, mainly traded with humans, not with other
computers. Human order flow at those times was, in contrast, quite
small, even though the overall trading volume initiated by humans
(not shown) was well above that initiated by computers (human
takers were therefore selling and buying dollars in almost equal
amounts). The " taking" orders generated by computers during
those time intervals were far more correlated than the taking
orders generated by humans. After 12:00 p.m., human traders, as a
whole, then began to buy dollars fairly aggressively, and the
appreciation of the yen against the dollar was partially reversed.
This is only a single example, of course, but it leads us to ask
how correlated computer trades and strategies have tended to be
overall.
We do not know precisely the exact mix of the various strategies used by algorithmic traders on EBS. Traders keep the information about their own strategies confidential, including, to some extent, from EBS, and EBS also keeps what they know confidential.13 However, one can get a general sense of the market and of the strategies in conversations with market participants. About half of the algorithmic trading volume on EBS is believed to come from what is often known as the " professional trading community," which primarily refers to hedge funds and commodity trading advisors (CTAs). These participants, until very recently, could not trade manually on EBS, so all their trades were algorithmic. Some hedge funds and CTAs seek to exploit short-lived arbitrage opportunities, including triangular arbitrage, often accessing several trading platforms. Others implement lower-frequency strategies, often grouped under the statistical arbitrage appellation, including carry trades, momentum trades, and strategies spanning several asset classes. Only a very small fraction of the trading volume in our sample period is believed to have been generated by algorithms designed to quickly react to data releases. The other half (approximately) of the algorithmic trading volume comes from foreign exchange dealing banks, the only participants allowed on the EBS system until 2003. Some of the banks' algorithmic trading is clearly related to activity on their own customer-to-dealer platforms, to automate hedging activity, and to minimizing the impact of the execution of large orders. But a sizable fraction is believed to be proprietary trading implemented algorithmically, likely using a mix of strategies similar to those employed by hedge funds and CTAs. Overall, market participants generally believe that the mix of algorithmic strategies used in the foreign exchange market differs from that seen in the equity market, where optimal execution algorithms are thought to be relatively more prevalent.
The August 16, 2007 episode shown above was widely viewed as the result of a sudden unwinding of the yen-carry trade, with hedge funds and proprietary trading desks at banks rushing to close risky positions and buying yen to pay back low-interest loans. The evidence in this case raises the possibility that many algorithmic traders were using fairly similar carry trade and momentum strategies at the time, leading to the high correlation of algorithmic orders and to sharp exchange rate movements. Of course, this is only one episode in our two-year sample. Furthermore, episodes of very sharp appreciation of the yen due to the rapid unwinding of yen carry trades have occurred on several occasions since the late 1990s, some obviously before algorithmic trading was allowed in the market. The sharp move of the yen in October 1998, including a 1-day appreciation of the yen against the dollar of about 7 percent, is the best-known example of such an episode. Next, we investigate whether there is evidence that, over the entire sample, the strategies used by algorithmic traders have tended to be more correlated than those used by human traders.
If computers and humans are indifferent between taking or making liquidity at a given point in time, then we should observe that computers and humans trade with each other in proportion to their relative presence in the market. If, on the other hand, computers tend to have more homogeneous trading strategies, we should observe computers trading less among themselves and more with humans. At the extreme, if all computers used the very same algorithms and had the exact same speed of execution, we would observe no trading volume among computers. Therefore, the fraction of trades conducted between computers contains information on how correlated their strategies are.14
To investigate the proposition that computers tend to have trading strategies that are more correlated than those of humans we pursue the following approach.We first consider a simple benchmark model that assumes random and independent matching of traders. This model allows us to determine the theoretical probabilities of the four possible trades: Human-maker/human-taker, computer-maker/human-taker, human-maker/computer-taker and computer-maker/computer-taker. We then make inferences regarding the diversity of computer trading strategies based on how the trading pairs we observe compare to those the benchmark model predicts.
In the benchmark model there are potential
human-makers (the number of humans that are standing ready to
provide liquidity),
potential human-takers,
potential computer-makers, and
potential computer-takers. For a given
period of time, the probability of a computer providing liquidity
to a trader is equal to
, which we label
for simplicity as
, and the probability of a computer
taking liquidity from the market is
. The
remaining makers and takers are humans, in proportions
and
, respectively. Assuming that
these events are independent, the probabilities of the four
possible trades, human-maker/human-taker,
computer-maker/human-taker, human-maker/computer-taker and
computer-maker/computer taker, are:
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
These probabilities yield the following identity,
which can be re-written as,
We label the first ratio,
, the "
human-taker" ratio and the second ratio,
, the "
computer-taker" ratio. In a world with more human traders (both
makers and takers) than computer traders, each of these ratios will
be greater than one, because
and
i.e., computers take
liquidity more from humans than from other computers, and humans
take liquidity more from humans than from computers. However, under
the baseline assumptions of our random-matching model, the identity
shown above states that the ratio of ratios,
, will be equal to one.
In other words, humans will take liquidity from other humans in a
similar proportion that computers take liquidity from humans.
Turning to the data, under the assumption that potential
human-takers are randomly matched with potential human-makers,
i.e., that the probability of a human-maker/human-taker trade is
equal to the one predicted by our model,
, we can now derive implications from observations of
, our ratio of ratios. In particular, finding
must imply that algorithmic strategies are more
correlated than what our random matching model implies. In other
words, for
we must observe that either
computers trade with each other less than expected (
) or that computers trade with humans more than expected (either
or
).
Our dataset allows us to estimate an ex-post proxy for
. Namely, for each trading day we estimate
and
, where
is the daily trading
volume between human makers and human takers, and so forth. In
Table 3 we show the
mean of the daily ratio of ratios,
for each
currency pair for the full sample and the three-month sub-sample.
In contrast to the above theoretical prediction that
, we find that for all
currency pairs
is statistically greater than
one. This result is very robust: in euro-dollar, all daily
observations of
are above one, and only a very
small fraction of the daily observations are below one for the
other currency pairs. The results thus show that computers do not
trade with each other as much as random matching would predict. We
take this as evidence that algorithmic strategies are likely less
diverse than the trading strategies used by human traders.
This finding, combined with the observed growth in algorithmic trading over time, may raise some concerns about the impact of AT on volatility in the foreign exchange market. As mentioned previously, some analysts have pointed to the possible danger of having many algorithmic traders take the same side of the market at the same moment. However, it is not a foregone conclusion that a high correlation of algorithmic strategies should necessarily lead to higher volatility or large swings in exchange rates. Both the high correlation of trading strategies and the widespread use of de-stabilizing strategies may need to be present to cause higher volatility. For instance, if many algorithmic traders use similar triangular arbitrage strategies, the high correlation of those strategies should have little impact on volatility, and may even lower volatility as it improves the efficiency of the price discovery process. Strategies designed to minimize the price impact of trades should also, a priori, not be expected to increase volatility. In contrast, if the high correlation reflects a large number of algorithmic traders using the same carry trade or momentum strategies, as in the August 2007 example shown at the beginning of this section, then there may be some reasons for concern. However, as noted earlier, episodes of sharp movements in exchange rates similar to that example have occurred in the past on several occasions, including well before the introduction of algorithmic trading in the foreign exchange market, suggesting that such episodes are a result of the dramatic unwinding of certain trading strategies, regardless of whether these strategies are implemented through algorithmic trading or not. In the next section, we explicitly investigate the relationship between the presence of algorithmic trading and market volatility.
In this section, we study whether the presence of algorithmic trading is associated with disruptive market behavior in the form of increased volatility. In particular, taking into account the potential endogeneity of algorithmic trading activity, we test for a causal relationship between the fraction of daily algorithmic trading relative to the overall daily volume, and daily realized volatility.
We first take an informal look at the data. Figure 4 shows monthly observations of annualized realized volatility (based on 1-minute returns) and of the fraction of algorithmic trading (the fraction of total trading volume involving at least one computer trader) for each of our currency pairs. As discussed earlier, there is a clear upward trend in the fraction of AT in the three currency pairs over 2006 and 2007. Realized volatility in euro-dollar, dollar-yen, and euro-yen declines slightly until mid-2007, and then rises in the second half of 2007, particularly sharply in the yen exchange rates, as the financial crisis begins.
In Figure 5, we study whether days with high market volatility
are also days with a higher-than-usual fraction of algorithmic
trading, and vice-versa. Using daily observations, we first sort
the data into increasing deciles of realized volatility (the decile
means are shown as bars in the graphs on the left).15 We
then calculate the mean fraction of AT for the days in each of
these deciles (shown as lines in the same graphs). To account for
the sharp upward trend in algorithmic participation over our
sample, the daily fraction of algorithmic trading is normalized: we
divide it by a -day moving average centered on the
chosen observation (a moving average from day
through day
, excluding day
). Next, we repeat the exercise, now sorting
the daily data into increasing deciles of the normalized fraction
of AT (the decile means are shown as bars in the graphs on the
right) and calculating mean realized volatility for the days in
each of these deciles (shown as lines in the same graphs). The
results in Figure 5 (both the graphs on the left and the graphs on
the right) show little or no relationship between the level of
realized volatility on a particular day and the normalized fraction
of AT on that same day. The highest decile in the euro-dollar
currency pair may be the only possible exception, with a slight
uptick evident in both volatility and AT activity. Finally, we note
that, in untabulated results, for each of the three currency pairs,
not one of the top 10 days in realized volatility is associated
with a top ten day in the share of (normalized) AT.
The simple analysis in Figure 5 does not point to any substantial systematic link between AT activity and volatility. However, this analysis ignores the possible, and likely, endogeneity of algorithmic activity with regards to volatility, and therefore does not address the question of whether there is a causal relationship between algorithmic trading and volatility. In the remainder of this section, we attempt to answer this question through an instrumental variable analysis.
The main challenge in identifying a causal relationship between algorithmic trading and volatility is the potential endogeneity of algorithmic trading. That is, although one may conjecture that algorithmic trading impacts volatility, it is also plausible that algorithmic trading activity may be a function of the level of volatility. For instance, highly volatile markets may present comparative advantages to automated trading algorithms relative to human traders, which might increase the fraction of algorithmic trading during volatile periods. In contrast, however, one could also argue that a high level of volatility might reduce the informativeness of historical price patterns on which some trading algorithms are likely to base their decisions, and thus reduce the effectiveness of the algorithms and lead them to trade less. Thus, one can not easily determine in what direction the bias will go in an OLS regression of volatility on the fraction of algorithmic trading. To deal with the endogeneity issue, we adopt an instrumental variable (IV) approach as outlined below.
We are interested in estimating the following regression equation,
where represents currency pairs and
, represents time.
is (log) realized daily volatility,
is the fraction of algorithmic trading at time
in currency pair
,
is either a time trend or a set of
time dummies that control for secular trends in the data, and
is an error term that is
assumed to be uncorrelated with
,
, but not necessarily with
. The large number of lags of volatility, which covers
the business days of the past month, is included to control for the
strong serial correlation in volatility (e.g. Andersen, Bollerslev,
Diebold, and Labys, 2003 and Bollerslev and Wright, 2000). The
exact definitions of
,
, and
are given below.
The main focus of interest is the parameter , which measures the impact of algorithmic trading
on volatility in currency pair
. However, since
and
may be correlated, due to the
potential endogeneity discussed above, the OLS estimator of
may be biased. In order to obtain
an unbiased estimate, we will therefore consider an instrumental
variable approach. Formally, we need to find a variable, or set of
variables,
, that is uncorrelated with
(validity of the instrument)
and correlated with
(relevance of the
instrument).
The instrument we propose to use is the fraction of trading floors equipped to trade algorithmically on EBS relative to the total number of trading floors linked to the EBS system.16 That is, in order to place algorithmic trades on EBS, a special user interface is required, and the total number of trading floors with such user interfaces thus provides a measure of the overall algorithmic trading " capacity" in the market. The ratio of these algorithmic trading floors to the total number of trading floors provides a measure of the potential fraction of algorithmic trading. Since setting up an algorithmic trading operation likely takes several months, the number of trading floors of each type is clearly exogenous with regards to daily market volatility; the fraction of AT trading floors is therefore a valid instrument. In addition, it is positively correlated with the fraction of algorithmic trading, and it provides a relevant instrument as seen from the tests for weak instruments discussed below.
Under the breakdown provided by EBS, there are three types of trading floors linked to the EBS system: purely algorithmic trading floors, purely manual trading floors, and dual trading floors, those equipped to handle both manual and algorithmic trades. We consider two natural instrumental variables: the fraction of pure AT trading floors over the total number of trading floors (including pure AT, manual, and dual ones), and the fraction of the sum of pure AT and dual trading floors over the total number. Since it is not obvious which variable is the better instrument, we use both simultaneously.17
The data on AT trading floors are provided on a monthly basis, whereas the data on realized volatility and algorithmic trading are sampled on a daily frequency. We therefore transform the trading floor data to daily data by repeating the monthly value each day of the month. Although this leads to a dataset of two years of daily data, the number of daily observations (498) overstates the effective number of observations, since the coefficient on AT participation will be identified from monthly variations in the instrumental variables. Transforming the instruments to a daily frequency is, however, more efficient than transforming all data to a monthly frequency, since the daily data help to identify the monthly shifts.
The instrumental variable regressions are estimated using
Limited Information Maximum Likelihood (LIML), and we test for weak
instruments by comparing the first stage statistic for the excluded instruments to the critical
values of Stock and Yogo's (2005) test of weak instruments. We use
LIML rather than two-stage least squares since Stock and Yogo
(2005) show that the former is much less sensitive to weak
instruments than the latter (see also Stock et al., 2002).
Volatility is measured as the daily realized volatility obtained from one minute returns; that is, the volatility measure is equal to the square root of the daily sum of squared one minute log-price changes. The use of realized volatility, based on high-frequency intra-daily returns, as an estimate of ex-post volatility is now well established and generally considered the most precise and robust way of measuring volatility. Although many older studies relied on five minute returns in order to avoid contamination by market microstructure noise (e.g. Andersen et al., 2001), recent work shows that sampling at the one-minute frequency, or even higher frequencies, does not lead to biases in liquid markets (see, for instance, the results for liquid stocks in Bandi and Russel, 2006, and the study by Chaboud et al., 2007, who explicitly examine EBS data on the euro-dollar exchange rate during 2005 and finds that sampling frequencies upwards of once every 20 seconds does not lead to noticeable biases). Here, we restrict ourselves to using minute-by-minute data.18 Following the common conventions in the literature on volatility modelling (e.g. Andersen, Bollerslev, Diebold, and Labys, 2003), the realized volatility is log-transformed to obtain a more well behaved time-series.
We consider two measures of the fraction of algorithmic trading,
, in a given currency pair: the
computer-participation fraction and the computer-taker fraction.
The first is simply the percent of the overall trading volume that
includes an algorithmic trader as either a maker or a taker
; that is, the percent of
trading volume where a computer is involved in at least one side of
the trade. In addition, we also consider an alternative measure
defined as the fraction of overall trading volume that is due to a
computer-taker
.
As seen in Figure 4, there is a clear secular trend in the computer-participation fraction,19 which is not present in realized volatility. Euro-dollar, dollar-yen, and euro-yen volatility is trending down at the beginning of the period and starts to trend up in the summer of 2007. In order to control for the trend in algorithmic trading in the regression, we include either a " linear quarterly" time trend or a full set of year-quarter dummies, one for each year-quarter pair in the data (8 dummies). That is, the linear quarterly time trend stays constant within each quarter and increases by the same amount each quarter, whereas the year-quarter dummies allows for a more flexible trend specification that can shift in arbitrary fashion from year-quarter to year-quarter. Both secular trend specifications are thus fixed within each quarter. This restriction is imposed in order to preserve the identification coming from the monthly instrumental variables. Using monthly, or finer, time dummies would eliminate the variation in the instrument and render the model unidentified. Although it is theoretically possible to include a monthly time trend, this would lead to very weak identification empirically.
The regression results are presented in Table 4. We present OLS and LIML-IV results, with either the quarterly trend or the year-quarter dummies included. We show in Panels A and B the results for the computer-participation volume, and in Panels C and D the results for computer-taker volume. We report results for the sample starting in January 2006 and ending in December 2007. In order to save space, we only show the estimates of the coefficients in front of the fraction of algorithmic trading volume variables.
The OLS results, which are likely to be biased due to the
aforementioned endogeneity issues, show a fairly clear pattern of a
positive correlation between volatility and AT participation, with
several positive and statistically significant coefficients. The
are fairly large, reflecting the
strong serial correlation in realized volatility, which is picked
up by the lagged regressors. There are also no systematic
differences between the quarterly trend and quarterly dummies
specifications.
Turning to the more interesting IV results, which control for the endogeneity bias, the coefficient estimates change fairly dramatically. All point estimates are now negative and some of them are statistically significant. Thus, if there is a causal relationship between the fraction of algorithmic trading and the level of volatility, all evidence suggests that it is negative, such that increased AT participation lowers the volatility in the market. The stark difference between the IV and OLS results shows the importance of controlling for endogeneity when estimating the causal effect of AT on volatility; the opposite conclusion would have been reached if one ignored the endogeneity issue. The evidence of a statistically significant relationship is fairly weak, however, with most coefficients statistically indistinguishable from zero. The more restrictive quarterly trend specification suggests a significant relationship for the euro-dollar and dollar-yen, but this no longer holds if one allows for year-quarter dummies.
To the extent that the estimated coefficients are statistically
significant, it is important to discuss the economic
magnitude of the estimated relationship between AT and volatility.
The regression is run with log volatility rather than actual
volatility, which makes it a little less straightforward to
interpret the size of the coefficients. However, some
back-of-the-envelope calculations can provide a rough idea. Suppose
that the coefficient on computer participation is about -0.01, which is in line with the coefficient estimates for
the euro-dollar. The average monthly shift in computer
participation in the euro-dollar is about 1.5 percentage points and
the average log-volatility in the euro-dollar is about (with returns calculated in basis points), which implies
an annualized volatility of about
percent.
Increasing the computer participation fraction by 1.5 percentage
points decreases log-volatility by 0.015 and
results in an annualized volatility of about 6.72. Thus, a typical change in computer participation might
change volatility by about a tenth of a percentage point in
annualized terms, a small effect.
The first stage statistics for the excluded
instruments in the IV regressions are also reported in Panels B and
D. Stock and Yogo (2005) show that this
statistic
can be used to test for weak instruments. Rejection of the null of
weak instruments indicates that standard inference on the
IV-estimated coefficients can be performed, whereas a failure to
reject indicates possible size distortions in the tests of the LIML
coefficients. The critical values of Stock and Yogo (2005) are
designed such that they indicate a maximal actual size for a
nominal sized five percent test on the coefficient. Thus, in the
case considered here with two excluded instruments and one
endogenous regressor, a value greater than
for
this
statistic indicates that the maximal size
of a nominal 5 percent test will be no greater than 10 percent,
which might be deemed acceptable; a value greater than 5.33 for the
statistic indicates a
maximal size of 15 percent for a nominal 5 percent test. In
general, the larger the
statistic, the stronger the
instruments. As is evident from the table, there are no signs of
weak instruments in the specification with a quarterly trend. There
are, however, signs of weak instruments in the case with
year-quarter dummies, for the euro-yen. This is not too surprising
given that the instruments only change on a monthly frequency, and
the year-quarter dummies therefore put a great deal of strain on
the identification mechanism. Importantly, though, the results for
the two major currency pairs are robust to any weak-instrument
problems and the reported coefficients and standard errors are
unbiased.
To sum up, the evidence of any causal effect of algorithmic trading on volatility is not strong, but what evidence there is points fairly consistently towards a negative relationship. There is thus no systematic statistical evidence to back the often-voiced opinion that AT leads to increased levels of market volatility. If anything, the contrary appears to be true.
In the previous section we discuss one of the major concerns regarding algorithmic trading, namely, whether AT causes exchange rate volatility. We now examine another major concern, whether AT improves or reduces liquidity during stress periods, when it is arguably needed the most. To answer this question, we cannot simply regress computer-maker volume, a proxy for liquidity provided by computers, on exchange rate volatility, a proxy for stress periods, because, as we discussed in the previous section, algorithmic volume and volatility are endogenous variables. In contrast to the previous section we do not estimate an IV regression, as there are no obvious instruments for volatility.20 Instead, we follow the event study literature and compare the liquidity provision by humans and computers during U.S. nonfarm payroll announcements, a period of exogenously heightened volatility, to the liquidity provision by both types of agents during non-announcement days. This comparison will help us determine who provides relatively more liquidity during stress periods. We note that, when we consider liquidity provision by humans and computers following other important macroeconomic news announcements, the results are qualitatively similar. However, we focus in this section on the nonfarm payroll announcement only, as it routinely generates the highest volatility of all US macroeconomic announcements.21
We consider two liquidity provision estimates: a one-minute
estimate and a one-hour estimate. The one-minute estimate is
calculated using volume observations from 8:30 a.m. to 8.31 a.m. ET
(when U.S. nonfarm payroll is released), while the one-hour
estimate is calculated using observations from 8:25 am to 9:24 am
ET. We define the one-minute (one-hour) liquidity provision by
humans, , as the sum of human-maker volume,
, divided by total volume during
that period, and the one-minute (one-hour) liquidity provision by
computers,
, as the sum of computer-maker volume,
, divided by total volume during
that period. Similar to the liquidity provision measures, we define
the one-minute volatility as the squared 1-minute return from 8:30
a.m. to 8.31 a.m. ET and the one-hour volatility as the sum of
squared 1-minute returns from 8:25 am to 9:24 am ET.
To compare liquidity provision by humans and computers during
announcement times to liquidity provision during (more tranquil)
non-announcement times, we could estimate the average liquidity
provision during announcement times and compare it to the average
liquidity provision during non-announcement times, with both means
taken over the entire sample period. However, as we discussed
previously, exchange rate trading volumes and the shares of
liquidity provision by humans and computers exhibit clear trends
over our sample, making the comparison of the two different means
problematic. Alternatively, and this is the methodology we follow,
on each announcement day we estimate the ratio of liquidity
provision on that day relative to the liquidity provision on days
surrounding the announcement. This amounts to using a
non-parametric approach to detrend the data. The time series of
these ratios will be stationary, and we can then test the
hypothesis that the ratio is greater than one. Specifically, we
divide the one-minute (one-hour) liquidity provision by humans,
, and computers,
, estimated on announcement day
by the
one-minute (one-hour) liquidity provision by humans,
, and computers,
,
respectively, estimated during the surrounding non-announcement day
period, defined as 10 business days before and after a nonfarm
payroll release date
. The liquidity provision
measures on the non-announcement days are calculated in the same
manner as on the announcement days, using data only for the periods
8:30 a.m. to 8.31 a.m. ET or 8:25 am to 9:24 am ET, for the
one-minute and one-hour measures, respectively.22 We follow the
same procedure with our one-minute and one-hour volatility
estimates.
Consistent with previous studies, we show in Table 5 Panel A that the
one-hour volatility on nonfarm payroll announcement days is 3 to 6
times larger than during non-announcement days. The one-minute
volatility is 15 to 30 times larger during announcement days
compared to non-announcement days. As expected, given the fact that
we focus on a U.S. data release, the volatility increase is smaller
in the cross-rate, the euro-yen exchange rate, than in the
euro-dollar and yen-dollar exchange rates. Focusing on the
statistically significant estimates, we show in Table 5 Panel B that, as
a share of total volume, human-maker volume tends to increase
during the minute of the announcement (the one-minute ratio
is greater than one),
while computer-maker volume tends to decrease (the one-minute ratio
is less than one).
Interestingly, this pattern is reversed when we focus on the
one-hour volume estimates for the euro-dollar and euro-yen exchange
rate markets. In relative terms, computers do not increase their
provision of liquidity as much as humans do during the minute
following the announcement. However, computers increase their
provision of liquidity relatively more than humans do over the
entire hour following the announcement, a period when market
volatility remains quite elevated.
We note that, over our sample period, the U.S. nonfarm payroll data releases were clearly the most anticipated and most influential U.S. macroeconomic data releases. They often generated a large initial sharp movement in exchange rates, followed by an extended period of volatility. The behavior of computer traders observed in the first minute could reflect the fact that many algorithms are not designed to react to the sharp, almost discrete, moves in exchange rates that often come at the precise moment of the data release. Some algorithmic traders may then prefer to pull back from the market a few seconds before 8:30 a.m. ET on days of nonfarm payroll announcements, resuming trading once the risk of a sharp initial price movement has passed. But the data show that algorithmic traders, as a whole, do not shrink back from providing liquidity during the extended period of volatility that follows the data releases.
In the previous three sections, we analyze questions that are primarily motivated by practical concerns regarding algorithmic trading, such as whether computer traders induce volatility or reduce liquidity. In this section we turn to questions that are driven more by the market microstructure literature, but that also lead to interesting practical insights regarding the effects and nature of algorithmic trading. In particular, we study price discovery within a vector autoregressive framework, which enables us to evaluate to what extent humans or computers represent the "informed" traders in the market. Our findings reveal several interesting features regarding the impact of algorithmic trades and the order placement behavior of computer traders.
We first investigate whether human or computer trades have a
more " permanent" impact on prices. To this end, we estimate
return-order flow dynamics in a structural vector autoregressive
(VAR) framework in the tradition of Hasbrouck (1991a), where
returns are contemporaneously affected by order flow, but order
flow is not contemporaneously affected by returns. Similar to
Hasbrouck's (1996) decomposition of program and nonprogram order
flow, we decompose order flow into two components: human-taker
and computer-taker
,
and thus we estimate for each currency
one return
equation and two order flow equations. In light of Evans and Lyons
(2008) findings, we estimate the structural VAR with U.S.
macroeconomic news surprises as exogenous variables that affect
both returns and order flow. Specifically, we estimate the
following system of equations for each currency
,
![]() ![]() |
(2) |
![]() ![]() |
|
![]() ![]() |
Here is the 1-minute exchange rate return
for currency
at time
;
is the currency
human-taker order flow at time
;
is the currency
computer-taker order flow at time
; and
is the macroeconomic news
announcement surprise for announcement
at time
defined as the difference between the
announcement realization and its corresponding market expectation.
We use Bloomberg's real-time data on the expectations and
realizations of
U.S. macroeconomic fundamentals
to calculate
. The
announcements we consider are similar to those in Andersen et al.
(2003, 2007) and Pasquariello and Vega (2007).23 Since units of
measurement vary across macroeconomic variables, we standardize the
resulting surprises by dividing each of them by their sample
standard deviation. Economic theory suggests that we should also
include foreign macroeconomic news announcements in equation
(2). However,
previous studies find that exchange rates do not respond much to
non-U.S. macroeconomic announcements, even at high frequencies
(e.g. Andersen et al., 2003), so we expect the omitted variable
bias in our specification to be small.
The underlying economic model is based on continuous time, and
we thus estimate the VAR using the highest sample frequency
available to us, minute-by-minute data. The estimation period is
restricted to the sample, and the
total number of observations for each currency pair is
in the full sample and
in the
three-month sub-sample (September, October and November of 2007).
In both samples, 20 lags are included in the estimated VARs, i.e.
.
Our specification in equation (2) does not allow human-taker order flow to contemporaneously affect computer-taker order flow or vice-versa. The advantage of this approach is that we can estimate the impulse response functions without giving more importance to a particular type of order flow, i.e., we do not need to assume a particular ordering of the human-taker and computer-taker order flow in the VAR. The disadvantage is that the human-taker and computer-taker order flow shocks may not be orthogonal. However, in our estimation this does not appear to be a problem, as our residuals are found to be approximately orthogonal (the correlation between the human-taker and computer-taker equation residuals are -0.001, -0.1 and -0.1 for the euro-dollar, yen-dollar, and euro-yen exchange rates respectively). As a robustness check, we also estimate the VAR with two different orderings. We first assume human-taker order flow affects computer-taker order flow contemporaneously, and then assume the opposite ordering. This latter approach allows us to compute upper and lower bound impulse responses. These results are presented in the Appendix, and show that the results presented here are not sensitive to alternative identification schemes in the VAR.
Before considering the impulse response functions and the
variance decompositions, we briefly summarize the main lessons from
the estimated coefficients in the VAR. Focusing on the return
equation, we find that minute-by-minute returns tend to be
negatively serially correlated, with the coefficient on the first
own lag varying between -0.08 and -0.15; there is thus some evidence of mean reversion in the
exchange rates at these high frequencies, which is a well-know
empirical finding. Both order flows are significant predictors of
returns. The price impact of the lagged order flows range from
around 4 to 18 basis points per
billion units of order flow (denominated in the base currency), as
compared to a range of approximately 28-100 basis
points in the contemporaneous order flow. As theory would predict,
we find that U.S. macroeconomic news announcements affect less the
euro-yen exchange rate (i.e., the of
regressing the euro-yen exchange rate on macroeconomic news
surprises and restricting the sample to announcement-only
observations is 23%) than the euro-dollar and dollar-yen exchange
rates (i.e., the
s of an announcement-only
sample are 60% and 59%, respectively). However, U.S. macroeconomic
news announcements still have an effect on the cross-rate to the
extent that the U.S. economy is more or less correlated with the
Japanese or the Euro-area economy.
Focusing on the order-flow equations, we find that the first own
lag in both order flow equations is always highly significant, and
typically around for all currency pairs. There is
thus a sizeable first-order autocorrelation in the human-taker and
computer-taker order flows. The coefficients on the first order
cross-lags in the order flow regressions are most often
substantially smaller than the coefficient on the own lag and vary
in signs. Lagged returns have a small but positive impact on order
flow, suggestive of a form of trend chasing by both computers and
humans in their order placement.
We note that despite the strongly significant estimates that are
recorded in the VAR estimations, the amount of variation in the
order flow and return variables that is captured by their lagged
values is very limited. The for the
estimated equations with only lagged variables are typically around
three to ten percent for the order flow equations, and between one
and three percent for the return equations. This can be compared to
an
of 20 to 30 percent when one includes
contemporaneous order flow.
As originally suggested by Hasbrouck (1991b), we use the impulse response functions to assess the price impact of various order flow types, and the variance decompositions to measure the relative importance of the variables driving foreign exchange returns. In Table 6 Panel A, we show the results from the impulse response analysis based on the estimation of equation (2), using the full sample for 2006-2007 and the three-month sub-sample, when the size of the shock is the same across the different types of order flow: a one billion base currency shock to order flow. We also show the results when the size of the shock varies according to the average size shock: a one standard deviation base currency shock to order flow (Table 6 Panel B). We show both the short-run (instantaneous) impulse responses, the long-run cumulative responses, and the difference between the two responses. The long-run statistics are calculated after 30-minutes, at which point the cumulative impulse responses have converged and can thus be interpreted as the long-run total impact of the shock. All the responses are measured in basis points. The standard errors reported in the tables are calculated by bootstrapping, using 200 repetitions.
Starting with a hypothetical shock of one billion base currency order flow, the results in Table 6 Panel A, show that the immediate response of prices to human-taker order flow is often larger than the immediate response to computer-taker order flow. This may partially be attributed to the fact that some of the algorithmic trading is used for the optimal execution of large orders at a minimum cost. Algorithmic trades appear to be successful in that endeavor, with computers likely breaking up the larger orders and timing the smaller trades to minimize the impact on prices. We emphasize, though, that the differences in price impact, which range from 1 to 8 basis points, are not very large in economic terms. Furthermore, we find that the result can be reversed in the long-run and in the three-month sub-sample. For example, the euro-dollar human-taker price impact is larger than the computer-taker price impact in the short-run, but the opposite is true in the long-run and in the three-month sub-sample.
In contrast to these results, the response to a hypothetical one standard deviation shock to the different order flows (Table 6 Panel B) consistently shows that in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen markets, humans have a bigger impact on prices than computers and the differences are relatively large. For example, a one standard deviation shock to human-taker order flow in the yen-dollar exchange rate market has an average long-run effect of 0.9 basis points compared to an average effect of 0.3 basis points for computer-taker order flow. Interestingly, the difference in price impact in the cross-rate, the euro-yen exchange rate, is very small. In this market, computers have a clear advantage over humans in detecting and reacting more quickly to triangular arbitrage opportunities so that a large proportion of algorithmic trading contributes to more efficient price discovery. It is then not so surprising that in this market computers and humans, on average, appear to be equally "informed."
In Table 7 we report the fraction of the total (long-run) variance in returns that can be attributed to innovations in human-taker order flow and computer-taker order flow.24 Following Hasbrouck (1991b), we interpret this variance decomposition as a summary measure of the informativeness of trades, and thus, in the current context, a comparison of the relative informativeness of the different types of order flow. Consistent with the results from the impulse response functions based on a one standard deviation shock to order flow, we find that in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen exchange rate markets human-taker order flow explains much more of the total variance in returns than computer-taker order flow. Specifically, human-taker order flow explains about 30 percent of the total variance in returns compared to only 4 percent explained by computer-taker order flow.
The fact that human-taker order flow explains a bigger portion
of total variance in returns is not surprising because human-taker
volume is about 75 percent of total volume in these two markets in
the full sample period and about 65 percent of total volume in the
three-month sub-sample (see Table 2). Moreover large
buy (sell) orders tend to be human-taker orders, i.e. we show in
Table 1 that the
standard deviation of human-taker order flow is twice as big as
that of the computer-taker order flow. But, do computers tend to
contribute " disproportionately" little to the long-run variance
in returns relative to their trading volume? To answer this
question we do a back-of-the-envelope calculation. We compute the
relative share of the explained variance that is due to
computer-taker order flow as the percent of total variation in
returns explained by computer-taker order flow divided by the
percent of total variation in returns explained jointly by both
human-taker and computer-taker order flow. For example, this
relative share is
(Table 7) in the
euro-dollar market. We can then compare this relative share to the
fraction of overall trading volume that is due to computer-taker
volume, which we show in Table 2. In the full
2006-2007 sample for the euro-dollar and the dollar-yen currency
pairs, the fraction of volume due to computer-takers is about twice
as large as the fraction of the explained long-run variance that is
due to computer-taker order flow. In the euro-yen, the fractions
are approximately equal. These results are fairly similar in the
three-month sub-sample, although the fraction of explained variance
has increased somewhat compared to the volume fraction. Thus, in
the two major currency pairs, there is evidence that computer-taker
order flow contributes relatively less to the variation in returns
than one would infer from just looking at the proportion of
computer-taker volume.
We now turn to examine whether liquidity providers post quotes
strategically. To this end we augment equation (2) and decompose
order flow into four components. Specifically, we estimate the
following system of equations for each currency
![]() ![]() |
(3) |
![]() ![]() |
where is the 1-minute exchange rate return
for currency
at time
;
,
is
the currency
human-maker/human-taker order flow at
time
;
is
the currency
computer-maker/human-taker order flow
at time
;
is
the currency
human-maker/computer-taker order flow
at time
;
is
the currency
computer-maker/computer-taker order
flow at time
;
is the
macroeconomic news announcement surprise for announcement
at time
.25
In addition to identifying whether traders, on average, have a
more permanent impact on prices when trading with humans than with
computers, this specification also allows us to observe the effect
order flow has on prices when, for instance, no party has a speed
advantage, i.e. both parties are humans or both parties are
computers, and when either the maker has a speed advantage,
, or the taker has a speed advantage,
. This distinction may be particularly
useful when analyzing the cross-rate, where computers likely have a
clear advantage over humans in detecting short-lived triangular
arbitrage opportunities.
Starting with a hypothetical shock of one billion base currency
order flow, the results in Table 8 Panel A show
that there is no clear pattern in which order flow impacts prices
the most. However, the dynamics of the VAR system help reveal an
interesting finding: There is a consistent and often large
short-run over-reaction to and
shocks. That is, as seen in Table 8, the short run
response to a
or
order flow shock
is always larger than the long-run response, and sometimes
substantially so. The euro-dollar in the sample covering September,
October, and November of 2007 provides an extreme case where the
initial reaction to a one billion dollar
shock
is a 22 basis point move, but the long-run cumulative reaction is
just 6 basis points. Interestingly, the opposite pattern is true
for the
order flow shocks, where there is always
an initial under-reaction in returns. To the extent that an
over-reaction of prices to order flow is suggestive of the presence
of liquidity traders, these impulse response patterns suggest that
computers provide liquidity when the probability of trading with an
informed trader is low.26
The response to a hypothetical one standard deviation shock to
the different order flows consistently shows that
order flow has a bigger impact on prices than
order flow (Table 8 Panel B) and
that the differences are large. In particular, a one standard
deviation shock to
order flow has an average
long-run effect of 0.6 basis points across currencies compared to a
one standard deviation shock to
order flow, which
has an average effect of 0.1 basis points. Interestingly, we
observe that when humans trade with other humans they influence
prices more than when they trade with computers (the impact of
on prices is bigger than the impact of
on prices), and when computers trade with
other computers they influence prices less than when they trade
with humans (the impact of
on prices is
smaller than the impact of
on prices). Our
interpretation is that computers provide liquidity more
strategically than humans, so that the counterparty cannot affect
prices as much. This interpretation is consistent with the
over-reaction of prices to
and
order flow described above: Computers appear to provide
liquidity when adverse selection costs are low. This finding
relates to the literature that proposes to depart from the
prevalent assumption that liquidity providers in limit order books
are passive.27
We also find that the price response to order flow varies across currencies as these markets differ along several dimensions. Trading volume is largest in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen markets, compared to the euro-yen market, and price discovery clearly happens mostly in the two largest markets. In the cross-rate market, the euro-yen, computers have a speed advantage over humans in profiting from triangular arbitrage opportunities, where prices set in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen markets are very briefly out of line with the euro-yen rate. Consistent with this speed advantage we observe that human-maker/computer-taker order flow has a larger price impact in the cross-rate market than in the other two markets.
In addition to the impulse response functions, we also report
the long-run forecast variance decomposition of returns in Table 9 for both the
full sample and the three-month sub-sample. Consistent with the
impulse response functions to a one standard deviation shock to
order flow, the order flow makes up the dominant
part of the variance share in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen
exchange rate markets. In the last three months of the sample, this
share has generally decreased. The share of variance in returns
that can be attributed to the
order flow is
surprisingly small, especially in the latter sub-sample, given that
this category of trades represents a sizeable fraction of overall
volume of trade during the last months of 2007, as seen in Table 2. The mixed order
flow (
and
order flow)
typically contributes with about the same share to the explained
variance in the euro-dollar and dollar-yen exchange rate markets.
In contrast, in the euro-yen exchange rate market
order flow makes up the dominant part of the variance share, which
is consistent with our discussion of computers taking advantage of
triangular arbitrage opportunities in this market.
Overall, about to
percent of the total variation in returns can be attributed to
shocks to the four order flows. However, in most currency pairs,
very little of this ultimate long-run price discovery that occurs
via order flow does so via the
order flow.
Similar to Table 7, we also report
in Table 9 the
fraction of the explained share of the return variance that can be
attributed to the different order flow combinations. Comparing
these to the fraction of overall volume that is due to these
combinations of computers and humans, reported in Table 2, gives an idea
of whether the different order flow combinations contribute
proportionately to the variance in returns. It is clear that
order flow tends to contribute
disproportionately little to the long-run variance of returns, and
that
order flow often contributes
disproportionately much.
Using highly-detailed high-frequency trading data for three major exchange rates over 2006 and 2007, we analyze the impact of the growth of algorithmic trading on the spot interdealer foreign exchange market. We focus on the following questions: (i) Are the algorithms underlying the computer-generated trades similar enough to result in highly correlated strategies, which some fear may cause disruptive market behavior? (ii) Does algorithmic trading increase volatility in the market, perhaps as a result of the previous concern? (iii) Do algorithmic traders improve or reduce market liquidity at times of market stress? (iv) Are human or computer traders the more " informed" traders in the market, i.e. who has the most impact on price discovery? (v) Is there evidence in this market that the liquidity providers (the " makers") and not just the liquidity " takers", are informed, and do computer makers post orders more strategically than human makers?
The first three questions directly address concerns that have been raised recently in the financial press, especially in conjunction with the current crisis, while the last two questions relate more to the empirical market microstructure literature on price discovery and order placement. Together, the analysis of these questions brings new and interesting results to the table, both from a practical and academic perspective, in an area where almost no formal research has been available.
Our empirical results provide evidence that algorithmic trades are more correlated than non-algorithmic trades, suggesting that the trading strategies used by the computer traders are less diverse than those of their human counterparts. Although this may cause some concerns regarding the disruptive potential of computer-generated trades, we do not find evidence of a positive causal relationship between the proportion of algorithmic trading in the market and the level of volatility; if anything, the evidence points towards a negative relationship, suggesting that the presence of algorithmic trading reduces volatility. As for the provision of market liquidity, we find evidence that, compared to non-algorithmic traders, algorithmic traders reduce their share of liquidity provision in the minute following major data announcements, when the probability of a price jump is very high. However, they increase their share of liquidity provision to the market over the entire hour following these announcements, which is almost always a period of elevated volatility. This empirical evidence thus suggests that computers do provide liquidity during periods of market stress.
To address the last two questions (price discovery and order placement), we use a high-frequency VAR framework in the tradition of Hasbrouck (1991a). We find that non-algorithmic trades account for a substantially larger share of the price movements in the euro-dollar and yen-dollar exchange rate markets than would be expected given the sizable fraction of algorithmic trades. Non-algorithmic traders are the " informed" traders in these two markets, driving price discovery. In the cross-rate, the euro-yen exchange rate market, we find that computers and humans are equally " informed," likely because of the large proportion of algorithmic trades dedicated to search for triangular arbitrage opportunities. Finally, we find that, on average, computer takers or human takers that trade on prices posted by computers do not impact prices as much as they do when they trade on prices posted by humans. One interpretation of this result is that computers place limit orders more strategically than humans do. This finding dovetails with the literature on limit order books that relaxes the common modeling assumption that liquidity providers are passive.
Overall, this study therefore provides essentially no evidence to bolster the widespread concerns about the effect of algorithmic trading on the functioning of financial markets. The lesson we take from our analysis of algorithmic trading in the interdealer foreign exchange market is that it is more how algorithmic trading is used and what it is predominantly designed to achieve that determines its impact on the market, and not primarily whether or not the order flow reaching the market is generated at high frequency by computers. In the global interdealer foreign exchange market, the rapid growth of algorithmic trading has not come at the cost of lower market quality, at least not in the data we have seen so far. Given the constant search for execution speed in financial markets and the increasing availability of algorithmic trading technology, it is likely that, absent regulatory intervention, the share of algorithmic trading across most financial markets will continue to grow. Our study offers hope that the growing presence of algorithmic trading will not have a negative impact on global financial markets.
The impulse responses and variance decompositions in the above VAR analyses are derived under the assumption that there are no contemporaneous interactions between the different order flow components. This identifying assumption is appealing because it treats the order flow components symmetrically and ensures that the results are not driven by the ordering of the order flows in the VAR. On the other hand, it cannot be ruled out that one order flow component affects another one contemporaneously within the one-minute timespan over which each observation is sampled. If this is the case, the VAR specification that we use above would be too restrictive and the resulting impulse responses and variance decompositions would likely be biased. As discussed above, given the fairly low correlation that we observe in the VAR residuals for the different order flow equations, this does not appear to be a major concern, but since these correlations are not identical to zero it is still possible that other identification schemes would lead to different conclusions.
In this section we therefore perform a comprehensive robustness check of the VAR results by calculating upper and lower bounds on the impulse responses and variance decompositions. In particular, we consider all possible orderings of the order flows in the VARs, while imposing a triangular structure. That is, we still assume that returns are ordered last in the VAR and are thus affected contemporaneously by all order flow components, but we then consider all possible orderings for the different order flows. In the case where we split order flow into human and computer order flow, this results in just two different specifications--one where computer order flow affects human order flow contemporaneously but contemporaneous human order flow has no impact on computer order flow, and the opposite specification where human order flow affects computer order flow contemporaneously. In the case with four different order flows, there are 24 different orderings, when one allows for all possible triangular identification schemes, only imposing that returns are ordered last. From each of these specifications, we calculate impulse responses and variance decompositions. The minimum and maximum of these over all specifications are reported in Tables A1 and A2 for the two order flow case and in Tables A3 and A4 in the four order flow case.
Starting with the simpler case with order flow split up into human or computer order flow, Tables A1 and A2 confirm our conjecture that the low correlation in the VAR residuals render the VAR specification very robust to the ordering of the order flows. The min-max intervals shown in the two tables are generally very tight and all of our earlier qualitative conclusions that we draw from our preferred structural VAR specification holds also under these alternative orderings.
Turning to the VAR analysis with four separate order flow, the
number of possible orderings increases dramatically to 24. This
large number of possible specifications inevitably results in wider
min-max intervals, even though the correlations in the VAR
residuals are generally small. In order to usefully interpret these
results, we check whether our main qualitative conclusions from our
preferred structural specification analyzed above also holds up, in
a min-max sense, under all possible orderings. Our first main
result in the above analysis was that there is an initial
over-reaction to and
shocks and
an initial under-reaction to
shocks. As seen
in Table A3,
these findings are mostly supported by the min-max results as well.
The only exceptions recorded are for the euro-yen cross rate, where
the under-reaction to
and
shocks is also much weaker in the original results in Table 8. It is also
evident from Table A3, Panel B, that
the min-max results support the finding that a one standard
deviation shock to
has a substantially bigger
impact on returns than a
shock. In addition, Table A3, Panel
B, also shows that the impact of the
shock tends
to be larger than the
impact, and the
impact tends to be smaller than the
impact. Finally, the results in Table A3 also
mostly support the finding that the reactions to
order flow are greater in the euro-yen cross currency than in the
two main currency pairs, although some overlap is seen for the one
standard deviation shock in Panel B.
Table A4 shows the
corresponding min-max results for the variance decomposition.
Again, our main conclusions are mostly supported in a min-max
sense. makes up the largest share of the
explained variance in the two main currency pairs in the full
sample, although in the three-month sub-sample there is some
overlap between the min-max intervals for the
order flow and the
order flow.
always contributes a very small share of the explained
variance and
always contributes a fairly
substantial share in the cross currency.
In summary, these robustness checks show that our main VAR used for examining price discovery (equation (2)), using human and computer order flows, is not particularly sensitive to the exact identification scheme that is used. The results presented in Tables 6 and 7 thus appear to be robust to alternative orderings in the VAR. Our second VAR specification (equation (3)), which we use to analyze strategic liquidity provision, is a little more sensitive to the exact identification scheme used, but the min-max results are still overall very supportive of our main conclusions.
Table A1
Min-max impulse responses from the VAR specification with human-taker and computer-taker order flow.
The table shows the minimum and maximum triangular impulse responses for returns as a result of shocks to the human-taker
order flow or computer-taker
order flow, denoted H-taker and C-taker in the table
headings, respectively. In Panel A we show the return response, in
basis points, to a one-billion base-currency shock to one of the
order flows. In Panel B we show the return response, in basis
points, to a one standard deviation shock to one of the order
flows. We show the results for the full 2006-2007 sample and for
the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September,
October, and November of 2007. For each currency pair we show the
short-run (immediate) response of returns; the corresponding
cumulative long-run response of returns, calculated as the
cumulative impact of the shock after 30 minutes; and the difference
between the cumulative long-run response in returns minus the
immediate response of returns, i.e., we provide the extent of
over-reaction or under-reaction to an order flow shock. There are a
total of
minute-by-minute observations in the
full two-year sample and
observations in the
three-month sub-sample.
Table A1, Panel A: One billion base-currency shock
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C | 3-month sub-sample: H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C -taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Long run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Difference |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Short run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Long run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Difference |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Short run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Long run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Difference |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Table A1, Panel B: One standard deviation shock
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Long run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Difference |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Short run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Long run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Difference |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Short run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Long run |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Difference |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Table A2
Min-max variance decompositions
from the VAR specification with human-taker and computer-taker
order flow. The table shows the minimum and maximum triangular
long-run variance decomposition of returns, expressed in percent
and calculated at the 30 minute horizon. That is, the table shows
the proportion of the long-run variation in returns that can be
attributed to shocks to the human-taker order flow and the computer-taker
order
flow, denoted H-taker and C-taker in the table headings,
respectively. For each currency pair we show the actual variance
decomposition, and the proportion of the
variance in returns that can be attributed to each order flow type.
That is, we re-scale the variance decompositions so that they add
up to 100 percent. We show results for the full 2006-2007 sample
and for the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from
September, October, and November of 2007. There are a total of
minute-by-minute observations in the
full two-year sample and
observations in the
three-month sub-sample.
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Variance decomposition |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Proportion of explained share |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Variance decomposition |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Proportion of explained share |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Variance decomposition |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Proportion of explained share |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Table A3
Min-max impulse responses from the
VAR specification with all four human/computer-maker/taker order
flow combinations. The table shows the minimum and maximum
triangular impulse responses for returns as a result of shocks to
the human-maker/human-taker order flow ,
computer-maker/human-taker order flow
,
human-maker/computer-taker order flow
, or
computer-maker/computer-taker order flow
,
denoted in obvious notation in the table headings. The results are
based on estimation of equation (3), using
minute-by-minute data. In Panel A we show the return response, in
basis points, to a one-billion base-currency shock to one of the
order flows. In Panel B we show the return response, in basis
points, to a one standard deviation shock to one of the order
flows. We report the results for the full 2006-2007 sample and for
the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September,
October, and November of 2007. For each currency pair we show the
short-run (immediate) response of returns; the corresponding
cumulative long-run response of returns, calculated as the
cumulative impact of the shock after 30 minutes; and the difference
between the cumulative long-run response in returns minus the
immediate response of returns, i.e., we provide the extent of
over-reaction or under-reaction to an order flow shock. There are a
total of
minute-by-minute observations in the
full two-year sample and
observations in the
three-month sub-sample.
Table A3, Panel A: One billion base-currency shock
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run | [27.33,33.32] | [18.63,53.71] | [15.26,45.85] | [20.49,52.41] | [20.21,27.69] | [17.49,47.57] | [17.01,42.58] | [12.66,38.58] |
USD/EUR: Long run | [29.89,34.83] | [8.21,46.56] | [22.08,50.08] | [12.17,47.64] | [24.08,30.77] | [7.50,42.68] | [25.64,49.51] | [-4.72,26.10] |
USD/EUR: Difference | [1.05,2.88] | [-10.48,-7.05] | [2.69,7.20] | [-9.13,-3.56] | [2.26,4.55] | [-10.15,-4.71] | [4.31,9.43] | [-17.81,-11.64] |
JPY/USD: Short run | [43.11,51.88] | [39.54,95.65] | [19.41,60.20] | [51.93,83.64] | [41.51,54.04] | [40.20,94.60] | [23.08,64.84] | [61.16,89.94] |
JPY/USD: Long run | [46.68,54.24] | [29.22,89.09] | [25.02,63.23] | [43.96,77.69] | [46.49,57.52] | [36.14,90.68] | [19.96,59.37] | [44.83,71.65] |
JPY/USD: Difference | [2.25,3.71] | [-10.42,-6.47] | [1.75,5.81] | [-8.45,-4.72] | [3.48,4.98] | [-7.41,-1.59] | [-7.05,-2.82] | [-18.43,-15.85] |
JPY/EUR: Short run | [102.33,123.80] | [30.23,132.09] | [78.32,121.12] | [99.99,113.19] | [138.95,178.40] | [30.01,147.48] | [90.10,137.21] | [86.01,101.70] |
JPY/EUR: Long run | [115.86,137.80] | [25.52,136.33] | [84.82,129.72] | [91.10,105.26] | [159.08,198.13] | [20.15,146.71] | [96.18,144.85] | [86.58,102.72] |
JPY/EUR: Difference | [13.37,14.59] | [-4.75,4.27] | [6.14,8.73] | [-8.89,-7.87] | [18.60,21.43] | [-9.86,-0.77] | [4.46,7.81] | [0.53,1.67] |
Table A3, Panel B: One standard deviation shock
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run | [0.4906,0.6497] | [0.1545,0.4421] | [0.1276,0.3793] | [0.0551,0.1454] | [0.3895,0.5839] | [0.1739,0.4644] | [0.1823,0.4469] | [0.0481,0.1498 |
USD/EUR: Long run | [0.5365,0.6791] | [0.0681,0.3832] | [0.1847,0.4143] | [0.0327,0.1321] | [0.4641,0.6489] | [0.0746,0.4164] | [0.2747,0.5157] | [-0.0179,0.1014] |
USD/EUR: Difference | [0.0202,0.0537] | [-0.0868,-0.0580] | [0.0214,0.0609] | [-0.0246,-0.0099] | [0.0468,0.0919] | [-0.1008,-0.0460] | [0.0432,0.1029] | [-0.0677,-0.0452] |
JPY/USD: Short run | [0.6273,0.8020] | [0.2540,0.5984] | [0.1395,0.4108] | [0.1244,0.2043] | [0.6484,0.9038] | [0.3427,0.7866] | [0.2224,0.5924] | [0.2306,0.3453] |
JPY/USD: Long run | [0.6793,0.8384] | [0.1877,0.5574] | [0.1799,0.4315] | [0.1053,0.1898] | ]0.7261,0.9619] | [0.3080,0.7540] | [0.1923,0.5424] | [0.1690,0.2751] |
JPY/USD: Difference | [0.0347,0.0547] | [-0.0669,-0.0405] | [0.0118,0.0418] | [-0.0203,-0.0116] | [0.0581,0.0777] | [-0.0576,-0.0143] | [-0.0633,-0.0272] | [-0.0708,-0.0597] |
JPY/EUR: Short run | [0.4281,0.5356] | [0.0847,0.3515] | [0.3459,0.5018] | [0.1549,0.1755] | [0.5595,0.7502] | [0.1084,0.5103] | [0.5330,0.7700] | [0.2191,0.2590] |
JPY/EUR: Long run | [0.4847,0.5963] | [0.0715,0.3628] | [0.3746,0.5374] | [0.1412,0.1632] | [0.6405,0.8332] | [0.0728,0.5076] | [0.5690,0.8128] | [0.2206,0.2616] |
JPY/EUR: Difference | [0.0565,0.0620] | [-0.0133,0.0114] | [0.0250,0.0362] | [-0.0138,-0.0122] | [0.0775,0.0884] | [-0.0356,-0.0027] | [0.0244,0.0466] | [0.0014,0.0043] |
Table A4
Min-max variance decompositions from the VAR specification with all four human/computer-maker/taker order flow combinations. The table shows the minimum and maximum triangular long-run variance decomposition of returns, expressed in percent and calculated at the 30 minute horizon. That is, the table shows the proportion of the long-run variation in returns that can be attributed to shocks to the human-maker/human-taker order flow (HH), computer-maker/human-taker order flow (CH), human-maker/computer-taker order flow (HC), and computer-maker/computer-taker order flow (CC), denoted in obvious notation in the table headings. We show the actual variance decomposition, and the proportions of the explained variance in returns that can be attributed to each order flow type. That is, we re-scale the variance decompositions so that they add up to 100 percent. We present results for the full 2006-2007 sample and for the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September, October, and November of 2007. There are a total of 717,120 minute-by-minute observations in the full two-year sample and 89,280 observations in the three-month sub-sample.
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/C-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Variance decomp. | [16.15, 28.28] | [1.64, 13.06] | [1.16, 9.71] | [0.21, 1.42] | [10.90, 24.29] | [2.22, 15.27] | [2.50, 14.24] | [0.23, 1.63] |
USD/EUR: Proportion | [7.42, 83.05] | [4.80, 38.36] | [3.42, 28.51] | [0.63, 4.17] | [32.50, 72.41] | [6.61, 45.52] | [7.46, 42.43] | [0.69, 4.85] |
JPY/USD: Variance decomp. | [15.61, 25.47] | [2.57, 14.16] | [0.85, 6.77] | [0.61, 1.65] | [12.00, 23.18] | [3.34, 17.45] | [1.51, 10.04] | [1.52, 3.40] |
JPY/USD: Proportion | [48.22, 78.70] | [7.94, 43.74] | [2.64, 20.92] | [1.90, 5.10] | [35.04, 67.65] | [9.74, 50.94] | [4.40, 29.29] | [4.44,9.91] |
JPY/EUR: Variance decomp. | [7.29, 11.38] | [0.29, 4.89] | [4.73, 9.95] | [0.95, 1.22] | [7.02, 12.58] | [0.29, 5.83] | [6.41, 13.31] | [1.07, 1.50] |
JPY/EUR: Proportion | [37.25, 58.18] | [1.49, 24.98] | [24.19, 50.87] | [4.87, 6.24] | [30.40, 54.54] | [1.26, 25.27] | [27.79, 57.67] | [4.66, 6.49] |
Albuquerque, R., and Miao, J., 2008, Advanced Information and Asset Prices, Working Paper Boston University.
Andersen, T.G., and T. Bollerslev, 1998, Deutsche Mark-Dollar Volatility: Intraday activity patterns, macroeconomic announcements, and longer run dependencies, Journal of Finance 53, 219-265.
Andersen, T.G., T. Bollerslev, F.X. Diebold, and H. Ebens, 2001. The distribution of realized stock return volatility, Journal of Financial Economics 61, 43-76.
Andersen, T.G., T. Bollerslev, F.X. Diebold, and P. Labys, 2003. Modeling and Forecasting Realized Volatility, Econometrica 71, 579-625.
Andersen, T.G., T. Bollerslev, F.X. Diebold, and C. Vega, 2003. Micro Effects of Macro Announcements: Real-Time Price Discovery in Foreign Exchange, American Economic Review 93, 38-62.
Andersen, T.G., T. Bollerslev, F.X. Diebold, and C. Vega, 2007. Real-time price discovery in global stock, bond, and foreign exchange markets, Journal of International Economics 73, 251-277.
Angel, J., 1992, Limit versus Market Orders, working paper, Georgetown University.
Bandi, F.M., and J.R. Russel, 2006. Separating microstructure noise from volatility, Journal of Financial Economics 79, 655-692.
Berger, D.W., A.P. Chaboud, S.V. Chernenko, E. Howorka, and J.H. Wright, 2008. Order Flow and Exchange Rate Dynamics in Electronic Brokerage System Data, Journal of International Economics 75, 93-109.
Biais, B., Hillion, P., and Spatt, C., 1995, An empirical analysis of the limit order book and the order flow in the Paris Bourse, Journal of Finance, 50, 1655-1689.
Bollerslev T., and J.H. Wright, 2000. Semiparametric estimation of long-memory volatility dependencies: The role of high-frequency data, Journal of Econometrics 98, 81-106.
Bloomfield, R., M. O'Hara and G. Saar, 2005, The " Make or Take" Decision in an Electronic Market: Evidence on the Evolution of Liquidity, Journal of Financial Economics 75, 165-199.
Chaboud, A., B. Chiquoine, E. Hjalmarsson, and M. Loretan, 2007. Frequency of Observation and the Estimation of Integrated Volatility in Deep and Liquid Markets, Journal of Empirical Finance, Forthcoming.
Chakravarty, S., and C. Holden, 1995, An Integrated Model of Market and Limit Orders, Journal of Financial Intermediation 4, 213-241.
Easley, D., and O'Hara, M., 1987, Price, trade size, and information in securities markets, Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 69-90.
Evans, M., and R. Lyons, 2002. Order Flow and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political Economy 110, 170-180.
Evans, M., and R. Lyons, 2008. How is Macro News Transmitted to Exchange Rates?, Journal of Financial Economics 88, 26-50.
Goettler, R., C. Parlour and U. Rajan, 2007, Microstructure effects and asset pricing, working paper, UC Berkeley.
Harris, L., 1998, Optimal Dynamic Order Submission Strategies in Some Stylized Trading Problems, Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments 7, 1-76.
Hasbrouck, J., 1991a. Measuring the information content of stock trades, Journal of Finance 46, 179-207.
Hasbrouck, J., 1991b. The summary informativeness of stock trades: An econometric analysis, Review of Financial Studies 4, 571-595.
Hasbrouck, J., 1996. Order characteristics and stock price evolution: An application to program trading, Journal of Financial Economics 41, 129-149.
He, H., and J. Wang, 1995, Differential information and dynamic behavior of stock trading volume, Review of Financial Studies, 8, 919-972.
Hendershott, T., C.M. Jones, and A.J. Menkveld, 2007. Does algorithmic trading improve liquidity?, working paper, University of California, Berkeley.
Kaniel, R., and H. Liu, 2006, So What Orders do Informed Traders Use?, Journal of Business 79, 1867-1913.
Kumar, P., and D. Seppi, 1994, Limit and Market Orders with Optimizing Traders, working paper, Carnegie Mellon University.
Madhavan, A., Richardson, M., and Roomans, M., 1997, Why do security prices change? A transaction-level analysis of NYSE stocks, Review of Financial Studies, 10, 1035-1064.
Milgrom, P., and Stokey, N., 1982, Information, trade and common knowledge, Journal of Economic Theory, 26, 17-27.
Parlour, Christine, and Seppi, Duane, 2008, Limit Order Markets: A Survey, Handbook of Financial Intermediation & Banking, ed. A.W.A. Boot and A.V. Thakor, forthcoming.
Pasquariello, Paolo, and Vega, Clara, 2007, Informed and Strategic Order Flow in the Bond Markets, Review of Financial Studies, 20, 1975-2019.
Stock, J.H., J.H. Wright, and M. Yogo, 2005. A Survey of Weak Instruments and Weak Identification in Generalized Method of Moments, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 20, 518-529.
Stock, J.H., and M. Yogo, 2005. Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression, in D.W.K. Andrews and J.H. Stock, eds., Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 80-108.
Stoffman, Noah, 2007. Who Trades With Whom? Individuals, Institutions, and Returns. Unpublished Manuscript.
Table 1
Summary statistics for the
one-minute return and order flow data. The mean and standard
deviation, as well as the first-order autocorrelation, , are shown for each variable and currency pair. The
returns are expressed in basis points and the order flows in
millions of the base currency. The summary statistics are given for
both the full 2006-2007 sample, as well as for the three-month
sub-sample, which only uses observations from September, October,
and November of 2007. The first two rows for each currency show the
summary statistics for returns and the total market-wide order
flow. The following two rows give the results for the order flows
broken down into human-takers and computer-takers and the last four
rows show the results for the order flow decomposed into each
maker-taker pair. There are a total of 717, 120
observations in the full two-year sample and
observations in the three-month sub sample. We show
the statistical significance of the first order autocorrelation.
The
,
, and
represent significance at the
1, 5, and 10 percent level, respectively.
Full 2006-2007 Sample: Mean | Full 2006-2007 Sample: Std. dev. | Full 2006-2007 Sample: ![]() | 3-month sub sample: Mean | 3-month sub sample: Std. dev. | 3-month sub sample: ![]() | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Returns | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Total order flow ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: H-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: C-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: H-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: C-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Returns | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Total order flow ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
|
JPY/USD: H-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: C-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: H-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: C-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Returns | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Total order flow | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: H-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: C-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: H-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: C-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Table 2
Summary statistics for the fractions of trade volume attributable to different trader combinations. The table shows the fraction of the total volume of trade that is attributable to different combinations of makers and takers. Results for the full 2006-2007 sample as well as for the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September, October, and November of 2007, are shown. We show the average of the daily fractions, calculated by summing up across all minutes within a day, and the standard deviations of those daily fractions. For each currency, the first row shows the fraction of the total volume of trade where a computer was involved on at least one side of the trade (i.e. as a maker or a taker). The second row shows the fraction of the total volume where a human acted as a taker, the third row shows the fraction of the total volume where a computer acted as a taker, and the following four rows shows the fractions broken down by each maker-taker pair.
Full 2006-2007 Sample: Mean | Full 2006-2007 Sample: Std. dev. | 3-month sub sample: Mean | 3-month sub sample: Std. dev. | |
---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: C-participation ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: H-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: C-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: H-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: C-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: C-participation ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: H-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: C-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: H-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: C-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: C-involved ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: H-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: C-maker/H-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: H-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: C-maker/C-taker ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Table 3
Estimates of the ratio . The table reports the mean estimates of the ratio
, where
and
.
is the daily trading volume between human-makers and human-takers,
is the daily trading volume between
human-makers and computer-takers,
is
the daily trading volume between computer-makers and human-takers,
and
is the daily trading volume between
computer-makers and computer-takers. We report the mean of the
daily ratio
and the standard errors are shown in
parantheses below the estimate. We also show the number of days
that had a ratio that was less than one. We report the results for
the full 2006-2007 sample and the three-month sub-sample, which
only uses data from September, October, and November of 2007. The
,
, and
represent a statistically significant
deviation from one at the 1, 5,
and 10 percent level, respectively.
Full 2006-2007 sample | 3-month sub sample | |
---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Mean of daily ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Standard Error | ![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: No. of days with ![]() | 0 | 0 |
USD/EUR: No. of obs | 498 | 62 |
JPY/USD: Mean of daily ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Standard Error | ![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: No. of days with ![]() | 15 | 4 |
JPY/USD: No. of obs | 498 | 62 |
JPY/EUR: Mean of daily ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Standard Error | ![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: No. of days with ![]() | 4 | 0 |
JPY/EUR: No. of obs | 498 | 62 |
Table 4
Regressions of realized volatility
on the fraction of algorithmic trading. The table shows the results
from estimating the relationship between daily realized volatility
and the fraction of algorithmic trading, using daily data from 2006
and 2007. Robust standard errors are given in parentheses below the
coefficient estimates. The left hand side of the table shows the
results with a quarterly time trend included in the regressions and
the right hand side of the table shows the results with
year-quarter time dummies (i.e., eight time dummies, one for each
quarter in the two years of data) included in the regressions.
Panels A and B show the results when the fraction of algorithmic
trading is measured as the fraction of the total trade volume that
has a computer involved on at least one side of the trade (i.e. as
a maker or a taker). Panels C and D show the results when only the
fraction of volume with computer taking is used. In addition to the
fraction of algorithmic trading and the control(s) for secular
trends, 22 lags of volatility are also included in every
specification. In all cases, only the coefficient on the fraction
of algorithmic trading is displayed. Panels A and C show the
results from a standard OLS estimation, along with the . Panels B and D show the results from the IV
specification estimated with Limited Information Maximum Likelihood
(LIML). In Panels B and D, the Stock and Yogo (2005)
test of weak instruments are also shown. The critical
values for Stock and Yogo's (2005) F-test are designed such that
they indicate a maximal actual size for a nominal sized five
percent test on the coefficient in the LIML estimation. Thus, in
order for the actual size of the LIML test to be no greater than
10% (15%), the
F-statistic should exceed 8.68 (5.33). There are a total of
daily
observations in the data. The
,
, and
represent significance at the
1, 5, and 10 percent level, respectively.
With quarterly time trend: USD/EUR | With quarterly time trend: JPY/USD | With quarterly time trend: JPY/EUR | With year-quarter time dummies: USD/EUR | With year-quarter time dummies: JPY/USD | With year-quarter time dummies: JPY/EUR | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A. Fraction of volume with any computer participation, OLS estimation - Coeff. on AT | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Panel A. Fraction of volume with any computer participation, OLS estimation - ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel B. Fraction of volume with any computer participation, IV estimation - Coeff. on AT |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Panel B. Fraction of volume with any computer participation, IV estimation - F-Stat | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel C. Fraction of volume with computer-taking, OLS estimation - Coeff. on AT | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Panel C. Fraction of volume with computer-taking, OLS estimation -![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel D. Fraction of volume with computer-taking, IV estimation - Coeff. on AT |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Panel D. Fraction of volume with computer-taking, IV estimation - F-Stat | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Table 5
We report the mean ratio of the exchange rate volatility (Panel A) and liquidity provision by humans and by computers (Panel B) estimated during announcement days relative to that estimated during non-announcement days. The one-hour measure is estimated using observations from 8:25 am to 9:24 am ET and the one-minute measure is estimated using 8:30 am to 8:31 am ET observations. Announcement days are defined as nonfarm payroll announcement days and non-announcement days are defined as 10 business days before and after the nonfarm payroll announcement. In each panel, we report the chi-squared and p-value of the Wald test that the ratio is equal to 1. In Panel C we report the chi-squared and p-value of the Wald test that the liquidity provision of humans during announcement days relative to non-announcement days is similar to the liquidity provision of computers. The statistics are estimated using data in the full sample from 2006 to 2007 and there are 23 observations (April 6, 2007 nonfarm payroll announcement is missing because it falls on Good Friday, when trading in the foreign exchange market is limited). Human liquidity provision, , is defined as the sum of human-maker/human-taker volume plus human-maker/human-taker volume divided by total volume. Computer liquidity provision, , is defined as the sum of computer-maker/computer-taker volume plus computer-maker/human-taker volume divided by total volume. The ***,** and * represent significance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent level, respectively.
USD/EUR: Hour | USD/EUR: Minute | JPY/USD: Hour | JPY/USD: Minute | JPY/EUR: Hour | JPY/EUR: Minute | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Volatility - ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel A: Volatility - ![]() ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel A: Volatility - p-value | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel B: Liquidity Provision - Liquidity provision by humans, ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel B: Liquidity Provision - Liquidity provision by computers, ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel B: Liquidity Provision - ![]() ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel B: Liquidity Provision - p-value | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
0 | ![]() |
![]() |
Panel C: Comparison of Liquidity Provision between Humans and Computers - ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel C: Comparison of Liquidity Provision between Humans and Computers - ![]() ![]() | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Panel C: Comparison of Liquidity Provision between Humans and Computers - p-value | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
Table 6
Impulse responses from the VAR
specification with human-taker and computer-taker order flow. The
table shows the impulse responses for returns as a result of shocks
to the human-taker order flow or
computer-taker
order flow, denoted H-taker
and C-taker in the table headings, respectively. The results are
based on estimation of equation (2), using
minute-by-minute data. In Panel A we show the return response, in
basis points, to a one-billion base-currency shock to one of the
order flows. In Panel B we show the return response, in basis
points, to a one standard deviation shock to one of the order
flows. We show the results for the full 2006-2007 sample and for
the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September,
October, and November of 2007. For each currency pair we show the
short-run (immediate) response of returns; the corresponding
cumulative long-run response of returns, calculated as the
cumulative impact of the shock after 30 minutes; and the difference
between the cumulative long-run response in returns minus the
immediate response of returns, i.e., we provide the extent of
over-reaction or under-reaction to an order flow shock. There are a
total of 717, 120 minute-by-minute observations in the
full two-year sample and 89, 280 observations in the
three-month sub-sample. We show in parenthesis the standard errors
of the difference between the short-run and long-run response.
These standard errors are calculated by bootstrapping, using 200
repetitions.
Table 6, Panel A: One billion base-currency shock
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C -taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C -taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Table 6, Panel B: One standard deviation shock
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C -taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C -taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Table 7
Variance decompositions from the VAR specification with human-taker and computer-taker order flow. The table provides the long-run variance decomposition of returns, expressed in percent and calculated at the 30 minute horizon, based on estimation of equation (2), using minute-by-minute data. That is, the table shows the proportion of the long-run variation in returns that can be attributed to shocks to the human-taker order flow and the computer-taker order flow, denoted H-taker and C-taker in the table headings, respectively. For each currency pair we show the actual variance decomposition, and the proportion of the variance in returns that can be attributed to each order flow type. That is, we re-scale the variance decompositions so that they add up to 100 percent. We show results for the full 2006-2007 sample and for the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September, October, and November of 2007. There are a total of minute-by-minute observations in the full two-year sample and observations in the three-month sub-sample. We show in parenthesis the standard errors calculated by bootstrapping, using 200 repetitions.
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Variance decomposition | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
USD/EUR: Proportion of explained share | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Variance decomposition | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Proportion of explained share | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Variance decomposition | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Proportion of explained share | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Table 8
Impulse responses from the VAR
specification with all four human/computer-maker/taker order flow
combinations. The table shows the impulse responses for returns as
a result of shocks to the human-maker/human-taker order flow
, computer-maker/human-taker order flow
, human-maker/computer-taker order flow
, or computer-maker/computer-taker
order flow
, denoted in obvious notation in
the table headings. The results are based on estimation of equation
(3), using
minute-by-minute data. In Panel A we show the return response, in
basis points, to a one-billion base-currency shock to one of the
order flows. In Panel B we show the return response, in basis
points, to a one standard deviation shock to one of the order
flows. We report the results for the full 2006-2007 sample and for
the three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September,
October, and November of 2007. For each currency pair we show the
short-run (immediate) response of returns; the corresponding
cumulative long-run response of returns, calculated as the
cumulative impact of the shock after 30 minutes; and the difference
between the cumulative long-run response in returns minus the
immediate response of returns, i.e., we provide the extent of
over-reaction or under-reaction to an order flow shock. There are a
total of 717, 120 minute-by-minute observations in
the full two-year sample and 89, 280 observations
in the three-month sub-sample. We show in parenthesis the standard
errors of the difference between the short-run and the long-run
response. These standard errors are calculated by bootstrapping,
using 200 repetitions.
Table 8, Panel A: One billion base-currency shock
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/C-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Table 8, Panel B: One standard deviation shock
USD/EUR: Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | USD/EUR: Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/H-taker | USD/EUR: Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/C-taker | USD/EUR: Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/C-taker | USD/EUR: 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/H-taker | USD/EUR: 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/H-taker | USD/EUR: 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/C-taker | USD/EUR: 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
USD/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/USD: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Short run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Long run | ![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
![]() |
JPY/EUR: Difference | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Table 9
Variance decompositions from the
VAR specification with all four human/computer-maker/taker order
flow combinations. The table provides the long-run variance
decomposition of returns, expressed in percent and calculated at
the 30 minute horizon, based on estimation of equation (3), using
minute-by-minute data. That is, the table shows the proportion of
the long-run variation in returns that can be attributed to shocks
to the human-maker/human-taker order flow ,
computer-maker/human-taker order flow
,
human-maker/computer-taker order flow
, and
computer-maker/computer-taker order flow
,
denoted in obvious notation in the table headings. We show the
actual variance decomposition, and the proportions of the
variance in returns that can be
attributed to each order flow type. That is, we re-scale the
variance decompositions so that they add up to 100 percent. We
present results for the full 2006-2007 sample and for the
three-month sub-sample, which only uses data from September,
October, and November of 2007. There are a total of 717, 120 minute-by-minute observations in the full two-year
sample and
observations in the three-month
sub-sample. We show in parenthesis the standard errors, which are
calculated by bootstrapping, using 200 repetitions.
Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/H-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: H-maker/C-taker | Full 2006-2007 sample: C-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/H-taker | 3-month sub-sample: H-maker/C-taker | 3-month sub-sample: C-maker/C-taker | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USD/EUR: Variance decomp. | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
USD/EUR: Proportion | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Variance decomp. | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/USD: Proportion | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Variance decomp. | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
JPY/EUR: Proportion | ![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
![]() ![]() |
Figure 1: 50-Day moving averages of participation rates of algorithmic traders
Figure 2: 50-day Moving Averages of Participation Rates Broken Down into Four Maker-Taker Pairs
Figure 3: Dollar-Yen market on August 16, 2007
Figure 4: Volatility and Algorithmic Market Participation
*Daily realized volatility is based on 1-minute returns. We show monthly observations
**Share of algorithmic trading is at a monthly frequency
Figure 5: Deciles of Realized Volatility and AT Participation
1. Chaboud, Hjalmarsson, and Vega are with the Division of International Finance, Federal Reserve Board, Mail Stop 20, Washington, DC 20551, USA. Chiquoine is with the Investment Fund for Foundations, 97 Mount Auburn Street, Cambridge MA 02138, USA. Please address comments to the authors via e-mail at alain.p.chaboud@frb.gov, bchiquoine@tiff.org, erik.hjalmarsson@frb.gov and clara.vega@frb.gov. We are grateful to Terrence Hendershott and Albert Menkveld for their valuable insights, to EBS/ICAP for providing the data, and to Nicholas Klagge and James S. Hebden for their excellent research assistance. We also benefited from the comments of Gordon Bodnar, Charles Jones, Luis Marques, Dagfinn Rime, Alec Schmidt, John Schoen, Noah Stoffman, and of participants in the Spring 2009 Market Microstructure NBER conference, San Francisco AEA 2009 meetings, the SAIS International Economics Seminar, the SITE 2009 conference at Stanford, and the Barcelona EEA 2009 meetings. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. Return to text
2. See, for instance, " Rewarding Bad Actors," by Paul Krugman, New York Times, August 3, 2009, " High-Frequency Trading Grows, Shrouded in Secrecy," Time, August 5, 2009, and " Don't Set Speed Limits on Trading," by Arthur Levitt Jr., Wall Street Journal, August 18, 2009. Return to text
3. We also note a paper by Hasbrouck (1996) on program trading, where he analyzes 3 months of data where program trades can be separately identified from other trades. He concludes that both types of orders have an approximately equivalent impact on prices. Algorithmic trading is not exactly equivalent to program trading, though it is a close cousin. In principle, a program trade could be generated by a trader's computer and then the trade conducted manually by a human trader. Our definition of AT refers to the direct interaction of a trader's computer with an electronic trading platform, that is the automated placement of a trade order on the platform. Return to text
4. For example, Chakravarty and Holden (1995), Kumar and Seppi (1994), Kaniel and Liu (2006), and Goettler, Parlour and Rajan (2007) allow informed investors to use both limit and market orders. Bloomfield, O'Hara and Saar (2005) argue that informed traders are natural liquidity providers, and Angel (1994) and Harris (1998) show that informed investors can optimally use limit orders when private information is sufficiently persistent. Return to text
5. EBS has been part of the ICAP group since 2006. Return to text
6. EBS uses the name " automated interface" (AI) to describe trading activity directly generated by a computer, activity we call AT. Return to text
7. We do not use December 2007 in the sub-sample to avoid the influence of year-end effects. Return to text
8. The naming convention for " maker" and " taker" reflects the fact that the " maker" posts quotes before the " taker" chooses to trade at that price. Posting quotes is, of course, the traditional role of the market-" maker." Return to text
9. There is a very high correlation in this market between trading volume per unit of time and the number of transactions per unit of time, and the ratio between the two does not vary much over our sample. Order flow measures based on amounts transacted and those based on number of trades are therefore very similar. Return to text
10. Parlour and Seppi (2008) note that in a limit order book investors with active trading motives, some of which are " informed" traders, may choose to post limit orders that are more aggresive than those a disinterested liquidity provider would use but less aggresive than market orders. Return to text
11. The data in Figures 1 and 2 are 50-day moving averages of daily values, highlighting the broad trends over time. Return to text
12. See, for instance, " Algorithmic Trades Produce Snowball Effects on Volatility," Financial Times, December 5, 2008. Return to text
13. EBS requires that new algorithmic traders on its system first test their algorithms in simulated conditions. EBS then routinely monitors the trading practices of its customers. A high number of excessively short-lived quotes (flashing) is discouraged, as is a very low ratio of trades to quotes. Return to text
14. Stoffman (2007) uses a similar method to estimate how correlated individual investor strategies are compared to institutional investor strategies. Return to text
15. With 498 daily observations, the first 9 deciles each include 50 observations, and the highest decile contains 48 observations. Return to text
16. More precisely, we actually observe a time series of the number of EBS " deal codes" of each type over our sample period. Generally speaking, EBS assigns a deal code to each trading floor equipped with at least one of its terminals, and records whether they are equipped to trade algorithmically or not. These data are confidential. Return to text
17. Regressions not reported here show that using the fraction of pure AT trading floors as a single instrument gives qualitatively similar results to those presented below based on both instruments. Using the fraction of the sum of both pure and dual AT trading floors as a single instrument also leads to the same qualititative conclusion, but with more signs of weak instruments. Return to text
18. Using realized volatility based on five-minute returns leads to results that are very similar to those reported below for the one-minute returns, and the qualitative conclusions are identical. Return to text
19. The same is true for the computer-taker fraction, not shown in the figure. Return to text
20. One could consider macroeconomic news announcements as potential instruments for volatility. However, macroeconomic news announcements are exogeneous variables that cause both foreign exchange rate volatility and liquidity changes. Since we cannot assume that the effect macroeconomic news announcements have on liquidity is only due to the effect macroeconomic news announcements have on volatility, the exclusion restriction required by IV estimation is violated. Return to text
21. Andersen and Bollerslev (1998), among others, refer to the nonfarm payroll report as the " king" of announcements, because of the significant sensitivity of most asset markets to its release. Return to text
22. For simplicity, we label the 10 business days before and after the nonfarm payroll announcement as non-announcement days. However, during this 20-day period there are both days with no macroeconomic news and days with news. For instance, every Thursday, including the day before the monthly nonfarm payroll number is released, initial jobless claims are released. Thus, our estimation will likely be biased towards not finding statistically different behavior across the two periods. As we show in Table 5, volatility is, on average, much lower during this 20-day period than on nonfarm payroll days, and therefore the period still serves as a good benchmark. Return to text
23. Our list of U.S. macroeconomic news announcements is the same as the list of announcements in Andersen et al. (2007) and Pasquariello and Vega (2007) with the addition of three announcements: unemployment rate, core PPI and core CPI. Andersen et al. (2007) and Pasquariello and Vega (2007) use International Money Market Services (MMS) data on the expectations of U.S. macroeconomic fundamentals. In contrast, we use Bloomberg data because the MMS data are no longer available after 2003. Bloomberg provides survey data similar to those MMS previously provided. Return to text
24. The variance decompositions are virtually identical in the short- and long-run and thus we only show the long-run decomposition results. Return to text
25. In the Appendix, we analyze the robustness of this structural VAR by also estimating impulse responses and variance decompositions from all possible triangular identification schemes, only imposing that returns are ordered last in the VAR. Return to text
26. Dynamic learning models with informed and uninformed investors predict that prices will temporarily over-react to uninformed order flow and under-react to informed order flow (e.g., Albuquerque and Miao, 2008). We note that the over- and under-reaction of prices to a particular type of order flow is different from the over- and under-reaction of prices to public news, which are both considered a sign of market inefficiency. Order flow types are not public knowledge, so that agents cannot trade on this information. Return to text
27. For example, Chakravarty and Holden (1995), Kumar and Seppi (1994), Kaniel and Liu (2006), and Goettler, Parlour and Rajan (2007) allow informed investors to use both limit and market orders. Bloomfield, O'Hara and Saar (2005) argue that informed traders are natural liquidity providers and Angel (1994) and Harris (1998) show that informed investors can optimally use limit orders when private information is sufficiently persistent. Return to text
This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text