Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
International Finance Discussion Papers
Number 1036, November 2011--- Screen Reader
Version*
NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.
Abstract:
Monetary policy objectives and targets are not necessarily stable over time. The regime switching literature has typically analyzed and interpreted changes in policymakers' behavior through simple interest rate rules. This paper analyzes policy regime switches explicitly modeling policymakers' behavior and objectives. We show how current monetary policy is affected and should optimally respond to alternative regimes. We also show that changes in the parameters of simple rules do not necessarily correspond to changes in policymakers' preferences. In fact, capturing and interpreting regime changes in preferences through interest rate rules can lead to misleading results.
Keywords: Monetary policy, regime witches, unstable objectives.
JEL classification: E32, E42, E52
The analysis of policy regime switches has been central to several economic problems. The debate on the existence and sources of the great moderation is a clear example.1 Regime switches have also been examined in the context of rational expectations determinacy (e.g. Davig and Leeper (2007), Farmer et al. (2009)) and DSGE estimation (e.g. Owyang and Ramey (2004), Davig and Doh (2008), Bianchi (2010)). Building on relatively standard New Keynesian models, this literature has typically modeled policymakers' behavior with time varying or Markov-switching simple instrument rules.
The extensive use of simple rules in both theoretical and empirical studies is justified by several reasons: their simplicity and potential for practical use, their fairly good performance when compared to the optimal policy, and their robustness across several model specifications.2 However, simple rules are reduced form representations of policymakers' behavior, and cannot be used to identify the structural sources of behavioral changes. Reduced form representations limit the differentiation between factors the central bank can and can not control. This limitation is relevant at the time of distinguishing between monetary regimes, and assessing the central bank's performance (e.g. "good policy" vs. "good luck").
In a rational expectations equilibrium - given the forward looking nature of economic agents and decisions - the possibility of future regime switches affects the economy immediately. Therefore, this possibility should also be internalized by the central bank, which can react with an appropriately chosen policy.3 In other words, following the Lucas (1976) critique, policymakers' behavior is not invariant to the presence of alternative regimes. For these reasons, we study the effects of regime switches when the central bank behavior is determined through an endogenous decision process.
A natural source of policy regime switches is a change in policymakers' preferences, in terms of the relative weight assigned to different objectives and the desired targets. Objectives and targets can change over time due to a variety of reasons. Policy objectives may change with appointments of governors and central bank staff, who may have different views from their predecessors. Also, even among academic economists there is scope for different opinions and evolving theories on the benefits of output vs. inflation stabilization, and what is, in practice, the exact output level that should be targeted.4
We first consider two regimes differing in the relative weight assigned to inflation stabilization. The optimal policy response shows that policymakers try to counteract the effects generated by alternative regimes. The possibility of a future dovish regime induces the hawkish regime to increase the inflation response to cost-push shocks, through an accommodation effect. At the same time, the hawkish regime tries to anchor inflation expectations by promising to be even more hawkish in the future. The immediate effect is a sharper output contraction, which is the opposite of what the dovish regime is aiming for. We also examine the optimal policy response when regime changes are delayed or regard other targets.
Characterizing policy through an endogenous process enables us to examine whether the switches in simple interest rate rules identified in the data are likely to stem from changes in policymaker's preferences. Imposing a structure on the policymakers' decision process amounts to imposing restrictions on the possible switches in the resulting policies.
We find that changes in simple rules parameters cannot be interpreted solely as changes in policymakers' preferences. Intuitively, changes in policymaker's preferences imply a movement along the policy frontier, where reducing the volatility of one variable implies increasing the volatility of another variable. Instead, switches in simple interest rate rules often imply movements of the frontier itself. In addition, using simple rules to capture changes in policymakers' objectives can lead to misleading results: the presence of regime switches can be wrongly rejected and indeterminacy can be wrongly detected. Altogether, our findings restrict the possible interpretations of what are the deep sources of the existing estimates of changes in policymakers' behavior and the associated normative implications.
Our paper is partially related to the literature on political economy and monetary policy (see e.g. Alesina et al. (1997)), but our goal is not to provide a partisan analysis of monetary policy. In fact, we shed light on the difficulty of the partisan empirical literature to match timely and systematically certain parties with effective changes in monetary policy - in our model a future dovish regime implies an increase in inflation even if the current regime remains hawkish.5 Our model is also related to the literature on robust control (e.g. Hansen and Sargent (2007)) and optimal monetary policy with noisy indicators (e.g. Aoki (2003)). However, our analysis focuses on the effects of evolving objectives, and assumes the structural relationships describing the economy and the exogenous shocks to be known and common knowledge.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the model. Section 3 presents the results on optimal policy. Section 4 analyzes the relationship with simple rules, and section 5 concludes. The appendix contains additional derivations.
We base our analysis on a simple monetary model. Inflation dynamics are described by a New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC). As it is well known, the NKPC is a reduced form approximation of the relationship between inflation and output in an economy with monopolistic competition and staggered price setting
(1) |
where denotes price inflation and measures the output-gap, i.e. the difference between current output and the output level that would prevail under flexible prices.6 The term constitutes an exogenous cost-push shock, introducing a trade-off between inflation and output stabilization and following the process , with being an i.i.d. disturbance.
As it is standard in the optimal monetary policy literature, we assume that the central bank controls inflation and the output-gap directly. The monetary policy authority minimizes a weighted average of deviations of inflation and output-gap from their respective targets
(2) |
The parameter measures the relative importance of output stabilization. The inflation target is normalized to zero, while represents the (exogenously given) output-gap target. The target can be interpreted as the difference between the efficient level of output and the output that would prevail under flexible prices.
We model changes in the objective function in a straightforward way that allows for analytical solutions. In any period, current objectives can persist or change with probability and , respectively. We consider the objectives of the central bank to be either dovish () or hawkish (). The term dovish regime refers to a case where the output-gap target or the relative weight to output stabilization are higher than in a hawkish regime, that is or .7
We assume that the central bank can only make credible commitments about future policy while objectives remain unchanged. If objectives do change, a new policy will be set, and previous commitments will be disregarded. This assumption can be justified on the grounds that if objectives change, the central bank will adopt the best possible policy to fulfill its new objectives, and thus will disregard the plans made when priorities were different. Details on this type of policy formulation are available in Roberds (1987), Schaumburg and Tambalotti (2007), and Debortoli and Nunes (2010a).
In this context, it can be shown that under regime policy plans solve the following problem:
(3) | ||
The objective function is given by an infinite sum discounted at the rate , summarizing the events in which objectives remain unchanged. Each term in the summation is composed by two parts. The first part, in square brackets, is the period loss function. The second part is the value function , summarizing the utility the central bank obtains if next period objectives change.
The central bank faces a sequence of constraints represented by the NKPC, where in any period inflation expectations are an average between two terms. The first term, with weight , is the inflation that would prevail under the current regime and upon which there is commitment. The second term, with weight , is the inflation that would be implemented under the alternative regime , which is taken as given by the current central bank. As stated in the equilibrium definition, such level of inflation is determined by solving a symmetric problem to the one described above.
Definition 1 A Markov Perfect Equilibrium with objective changes must satisfy the following condition. For any and , given the sequence
The first requirement imposes the optimality of the policy functions given and . The second part defines the value function as the continuation value in case the regime changes. The value function takes into account that regime may become relevant again in the future.8 The first two conditions in the definition leave the sequence and the institutional setting of regime unspecified. The third part of the definition states that regime solves a symmetric problem. We refer to Markov Perfect Equilibrium because in a reoptimization period - the initial period in which the regime changes - policy only depends on natural state variables.9
The baseline case for our analysis is one where regimes only differ in the relative weight assigned to output stabilization, and the output-gap target is set to . Arranging the first order conditions of problem (3) yields
(4) |
where is equalized to zero. Equation (4) can be interpreted as a targeting rule, as e.g. in Giannoni and Woodford (2010). Since it does not depend on the parameters of alternative regimes, it is robust to the presence unstable objectives.10
Nevertheless, objective instability changes the dynamics of the economy. Combining (1) and (4), the evolution of inflation and output is determined by:
(5) |
with , , and the term
(6) |
is increasing in and decreasing in . The persistence of output is not affected by the parameters of the alternative regime. Instead, the inflation response to cost-push shocks depends on . The more likely is the regime switch (the lower is ) and the more persistent are the cost-push shocks, the stronger are the spillovers between alternative regimes.11 The difference in the initial response then propagates over time through the state variable .
As a benchmark for our analysis, we first analyze the standard case with full-commitment and stable objectives (of type ).12 In that case, and denoting the corresponding variables with an upper bar, the dynamics are described by equation (5), where the relevant parameters are given by , , and is the value taken by equation (6) when .
With unstable objectives ( and ), and assuming regime solves a symmetric problem, it can be easily shown that is given by
(7) |
where . In equation (7), the term in parenthesis is always bigger than one, since .13 Instead, it holds that if and only if (or equivalently ).
For a hawkish regime with , being , equation (7) univocally implies . This means that instability of objectives forces the hawkish regime into a stronger inflation hike and a sharper output contraction in response to a positive cost-push shock, relative to the stable objectives counterpart. In other words, the hawkish regime faces a worse contemporaneous trade-off caused by the possibility of a future change to a dovish regime.
The results for a dovish regime are less clear cut, since in that case . The relation between and depends on the exact parameterization. If the hawkish regime assigns a sufficiently low weight to output (i.e. is close to 0), objective instability may improve the trade-off faced by the dovish regime. This feature differentiates the effects of unstable objectives from those of limited commitment and stable objectives, as in Schaumburg and Tambalotti (2007). Indeed, limited commitment per se always worsens the trade-off in the cost-push shock response.
After the initial inflation surge in response to a positive cost-push shock, inflation is reduced in subsequent periods. The possibility of regime switches impacts expectations and consequently the optimal speed at which inflation is reduced. As shown in appendix A-1.1 the (absolute) inflation change, in comparison with the stable objective case is given by
(8) |
where, for convenience, the superscripts have been suppressed since all coefficients refer to the same regime. For a hawkish regime, being , a sufficient condition for (8) to be positive is
(9) |
Under standard calibrations of the relative weight of output stabilization () the latter condition is satisfied even in the limiting case with .14 This means that the hawkish regime reduces inflation more rapidly under unstable objectives.15 The intuition for this result is the following. The possibility that the dovish regime takes place next period increases inflation expectations. Besides the optimal impact response described in equation (7), the hawkish regime promises to reduce inflation faster in the next period. This promise anchors inflation expectations, dampening the negative impact on current variables. The promise to lower inflation at a faster speed is based on a time-inconsistent promise, and constitutes a clear example of how an optimizing central bank equates the distortions across time and states of nature.
To provide a quantitative illustration of our results, we adopt a quarterly calibration that is summarized in Table (1). The structural parameters , and follow the calibration of Gali (2008). We set according to the utility-based welfare criterion implied by those parameters. The value assigned to implies that the dovish regime assigns to output stabilization half of the weight assigned to price stabilization. The persistence of policy objectives is measured by the parameter , which is in the range of recent estimates of Markov-switching New Keynesian models.16 The autocorrelation of the cost-push shock is set to . There is no widespread consensus on the value of . Values found in the literature range from the i.i.d. case considered in Rabanal and Rubio-Ramirez (2005) found in Ireland (2004). As discussed earlier, the choice of a low degree of persistence reduces the spillovers between policymakers. Finally, the standard deviation of the cost-push shock is set to .2% in line with Adam and Billi (2006), Davig and Doh (2008), and Bianchi (2010) in similar small-scale New Keynesian models.17
Second moments and welfare are reported in Table (2). The upper and lower panels are conditional on the hawkish and dovish regime, respectively.
Table 1: Calibration
Parameter | Value | Description |
---|---|---|
Structural: | 0.99 | Discount Factor |
Structural: | 0.1275 | Slope of Phillips Curve |
Structural: | 1.0 | Real rate elasticity of output |
Policymakers: | 0.0213 | Weight on Output-gap Hawkish Regime |
Policymakers: | 0.5 | Weight on Output-gap Dovish Regime |
Policymakers: | .9 | Probability of a objectives remaining constant |
Shocks: | 0.2 | Autocorrelation of cost-push shocks |
Shocks: | 0.9 | Autocorrelation of real rate shocks |
Shocks: | 0.2 | Std. dev. cost-push innovation |
Shocks: | 0.2 | Std. dev. real rate innovation |
Moving from full-commitment to unstable objectives leads to an increase in the volatility of output and inflation both for the hawkish and the dovish regime.18 However, when objectives are unstable a switch from a dovish to a hawkish regime implies lower volatility of inflation but higher volatility of output.
In this section we consider two regimes that have different output-gap targets. This difference in targets can obviously be the consequence of disparate views on what kind of distortions and events should be accounted for by the central bank,
Table 2: Second Moments and Welfare
Full Com. | Loose Com. | Unstable Objectives | |
---|---|---|---|
Hawkish: Output | 3.395 | 3.540 | 3.579 |
Hawkish: Inflation | 0.519 | 0.535 | 0.540 |
Hawkish: Av. Period Loss | 0.536 | 0.575 | 0.588 |
Dovish: Output | 0.558 | 0.656 | 0.649 |
Dovish: Inflation | 1.028 | 1.072 | 1.061 |
Dovish: Av. Period Loss | 1.265 | 1.424 | 1.393 |
Note: The table reports the standard deviations of our variables (in relative terms of the std. dev. of the cost-push shock), as well as the implied welfare loss, conditional on being under the hawkish regime (upper panel) or the dovish regime (lower panel).
as has been quite evident in the recent crisis.19 In addition, another likely source of disagreement on the output-gap target lies in the measurement of the output level prevailing if prices would be flexible. Even if a consensus would exist that the output-gap target should be zero, as long as the flexible price output level is not perfectly observed and is subject to mismeasurement, substantial disagreement on the operative output-gap target can emerge. This issue is not a mere theoretical curiosity and is actually quite likely to occur in practice. Orphanides (2001, 2002) and several related papers showed that structural breaks in productivity can be hard to detect and do lead to dramatic different concepts regarding the output-gap target and the conduct of monetary policy. Chari et al. (2009) also discuss that the interpretation of shocks is not always straightforward which can lead to different views on the flexible price output level.20
We consider the dovish and hawkish regime to be characterized as and . For brevity of exposition we do not consider the cost-push shock since such analysis was already carried previously. The dynamics are characterized by the system
(10) |
where and .21 The dynamics coincides with those described in section 3.1, for the particular case of cost-push shocks with a unitary root (). The coefficient on the lagged output-gap to target difference remains unchanged. In addition, the coefficient is equivalent to , as given by equation (7), after imposing holding in the present case, and setting . That coefficient now multiplies a constant term which is increasing on the output-gap targets of both regimes. Under the plausible assumption of positive output-gap targets, that term is always positive.
Hence, as illustrated in Figure (1), the possibility of a dovish regime induces the hawk to increase inflation and reduce output on impact, and then reduce inflation faster in case objectives remain hawkish. For the dovish regime the effects of unstable objectives counteract the effects of limited commitment. For instance, limited commitment makes the output-gap to be lower. However, when objectives are unstable (and commitment is also limited) the presence of the hawk improves the response for the dovish regime.
These considerations show that our results of section 3.1 do not depend on the presence of cost-push shocks, since changes in output-gap targets affect the equations in a similar way.
Figure 1: Output-Gap Target Instability
Note: The upper and lower panel plot the impulse response functions for the hawkish and dovish regime, respectively. The values reported are percentages and inflation is annualized.
In this regard, this model can be seen as endogenously incorporating shocks that create a wedge between inflation and the output-gap.22 However, there are three important differences between the effects we identify and the traditional cost-push shocks. First, the reduction in output and increase in inflation occurs in response to the anticipation of future dovish objectives, and not in response to a current change in objectives or a current shock.23 Second, the anticipation of objective changes creates permanent effects instead of transitory ones. Third, the magnitude of the shock is endogenous and can be influenced by the monetary authority. Indeed, as long as the Phillips curve is not purely forward looking, the current central bank can set inflation and strategically influence future decisions and distortions.
It may not be entirely plausible to assume that a regime change can occur in every period. In practice, objectives can only be changed with some delay due to institutional aspects and policy implementation lags. We investigate whether incorporating these features alters or introduces additional interactions among policy regimes. We assume that objectives remain unchanged with certainty for periods. Only after periods, current objectives can eventually change. In this setting, the problem of the central bank can be written as:
(11) |
(12) | ||
(13) | ||
where indexes the sequence of regimes each lasting for periods. In order to solve problem (11), we first write its recursive formulation. To do so we apply the technique of Marcet and Marimon (1998) and write the problem as a saddle point functional equation that generalizes the usual Bellman equation. The proof of that result requires considering each tenure as one fictional big period, and then applying the results of Debortoli and Nunes (2010a) to address the probabilistic switch at the end of each tenure. Proposition (1) in the appendix proves this result in detail. As stated in Proposition (2) in the appendix, the solution can be characterized as tenure invariant functions of the Lagrange multipliers associated with constraints (12) and (13).24
Figure (2) plots the optimal policy functions with unstable objectives (continuous line). The upper and lower panel correspond to the hawkish and dovish regime with output-gap targets of 0.01 and 0.1, respectively.25 Each regime implements the policy functions shown in each period until the regime is changed. We calibrate the model such that regimes can only change with probability every periods (signaled with continuous vertical lines). For comparison, Figure (2) also plots the policy functions that occur in a limited commitment setting without regime changes (dashed line).
The hawkish regime implements a low inflation level immediately after knowing that the dovish regime has dissipated and objectives will not change in the following four periods (periods 5, 9, 13 in the graph).26 Differently from the model where regime changes can occur in every period, the strengths of the accommodation and anchoring effects are not constant over time. These two effects explain why the hawk starts with low inflation and then increases it.
This model puts in evidence the interactions between the two regimes and the potential difficulties in identifying them trough simple processes - it is difficult to distinguish whether the accommodation effect is making a hawk to increase inflation, or if in fact the regime already became dovish. Our findings are qualitatively robust to two alternative specifications. First, we have solved the model with a hybrid Phillips curve. Second, we assumed that objectives may change but the central bank never reoptimizes and, therefore, makes state contingent promises regarding the objectives.27
Figure 2: Delayed Regime Changes
Note: This figure refers to the model where objectives can not change immediately. The upper two panels plot the policy functions (inflation and output-gap) of a hawkish regime, and the lower two panels refer to a dovish regime. Changes in objectives can only occur every four periods - periods marked with continuous vertical lines. The case with objective changes and limited commitment is plotted with a continuous line. The case of no objective changes and limited commitment is plotted with a dashed line. In all panels the horizontal axis refers to the number of periods elapsed after the last regime change or reoptimization. Values are in percentages and inflation is annualized. The policy functions are truncated at period 16 in the figure but not in the solution method.
The most common approach followed in the monetary policy literature is to model regime switches as exogenous changes in the parameters of an interest rate rule. Some empirical studies support the view that interest rate rule parameters have changed over time.28 Such changes are typically interpreted as a signal of switches between "good" and "bad" policies.
The goal of this section is to understand if there is a relationship between changes in the parameters of an interest rate rule (the common approach in the literature) and the changes in policy preferences modeled in the previous sections. We proceed in two different directions. First, we compare some qualitative implications of the two approaches. Second, we perform a Monte Carlo experiment, where we check if changes in policy objectives would be detected by estimating an interest rate rule with Markov-switching coefficients.
Consider the interest rate rule
(14) |
where the parameters and measure the response of the interest rate to changes in inflation and output-gap, respectively.29 In order to show how this policy rule affects the behavior of inflation and output, we need to supplement the NKPC (1) with an IS equation describing the demand-side of the economy
(15) |
where the term represents a real interest rate shock, which may result either from demand or supply shocks, and is assumed to follow an AR(1) process . The calibration of the real rate shock follows standard values described in Table (1). For simplicity and without loss of generality, we assume the innovation to the real rate shock, , and the innovation to the cost-push shock, , to be uncorrelated.30
The solution of the three-equation system (1), (14) and (15) is given by
16) |
where and .
As opposed to optimal policy, here inflation and output also respond to the real rate shock . The intensity of the response to depends on the magnitude of and through the parameter . In particular, since and , an increase in the policy parameters or lead to a simultaneous reduction in the volatility of both inflation and output, conditional on the shock . Unconditional volatilities may follow a similar pattern, as long as the volatility of the real rate shocks is sufficiently higher than the volatility of cost-push shocks, as it seems more plausible from an empirical viewpoint.31 The appendix shows that a change in the policy parameters and drive the volatilities of inflation and output-gap in the same direction, as long as
(17) |
This inequality is easily satisfied. According to our calibration, for the above condition to be violated the volatility of the innovations to cost-push shocks should be more than 10 times than that of real shocks.
We can then conclude that changes in simple rule parameters cannot always be interpreted as changes in policy objectives. Changes in simple rules may drive the volatility of output-gap and inflation in the same direction, while changes in policy objectives always drive those volatilities in opposite directions. This result is more general and applies to a broader set of models and policy rules. Intuitively, when the central bank behaves optimally, it stabilizes different objectives according to certain weights. A change in those weights is restricted to be a movement along a policy frontier. Such restrictions are not necessarily satisfied by changes in the parameters of a simple rule.32
For example, empirical studies have typically found that both the volatility of inflation and output were reduced after the Volcker disinflation period. This constitutes a shift of the policy frontier itself and cannot be interpreted as a reduction in the relative weight assigned to output stabilization. Instead, as shown in Table (2) a movement of the policy frontier can be associated with a change in the probability of regime switching (e.g. moving from the third to the first column), or a change in the perception of the alternative regime objectives. Both the explanations are not related to the preferences of the regime in power nor to factors fully under its control. It is then unclear to what extent changes in simple rule parameters can be interpreted as "good" or "bad" policies for which the current central bank is responsible.
Another implication concerns the central bank vulnerability to objective instability. Using a regime switching model with interest rate rules, Liu et al. (2009) find that "active'' regimes are more insulated from the spillovers generated by regime switches. Our findings show that this result does not hold when policymakers' differ in their relative preference for output stabilization and set policy optimally. If a regime is more insulated in terms of inflation volatility, it would necessarily suffer a higher exposure in terms of output volatility.
In this section we examine whether changes in policy objectives could be identified in the data as changes in interest rate rule coefficients. We try to address this issue through a Monte Carlo exercise. We simulate our baseline model of section 3.1 for different realizations of the cost-push shock, the real rate shock, and the regime switching shock. We then use the resulting series to estimate the following (standard) Taylor-type interest rate rule
(18) |
where is an unobservable residual, assumed to be uncorrelated with the regressors.33 Equation (18) includes a lagged interest rate term because of empirical plausibility and the endogenous persistence in the data generating process. Following Hamilton (1989) and Kim and Nelson (1999), we estimate equation (18) by maximum likelihood allowing for , , , and to follow a two state Markov-switching process.34
Table (3) shows that, according to the Markov-switching criterion developed by Smith et al. (2006), the two-regime model is preferred to a single regime specification only in 13% of the cases. In addition, the algorithm identifies correctly the regime in place in a certain period only in 60% of the cases, a relatively small improvement over the 50% probability of being right without any information.
The mean estimates seem plausible. The coefficient on the lagged interest rate is in accordance with empirical studies. The coefficients and are also plausible for the hawk.35 The two regimes differ in an important dimension. While the policy rule followed by the hawkish regime implies a determinate equilibrium (when combined with the other equations of the model), the dovish regime implies an indeterminate one. This result is consistent with many empirical studies arguing that monetary policy became more hawkish leading to equilibrium determinacy. But our results are due to a misinterpretation of the source of regime switches rather than the determinacy characteristics. Indeterminacy is not a feature of the data generating process - both regimes follow an optimal policy delivering a determinate solution.36
The results in Table (3) show the risks associated with estimating simple policy rules to draw conclusions about the underlying objectives of the central bank. The presence of regime switches may be wrongly rejected, the specific regime in power may be hard to identify, and the determinacy properties that each regime would imply may be erroneous.
We performed many alternative exercises to check the robustness of our results, as reported in the last two columns of Table (3). In these exercises we constrained to be constant across regimes, which simplifies the algorithm task to identify switches in the interest rate response to inflation and output-gap. Also, we increased the cost-push volatility to the level of the real rate volatility, which we see as an upper bound. As discussed in section 4.1, such calibration allows the simple interest rate rule to better capture the optimal policy data generating process. The performance of the estimation algorithm improves, but the main conclusions reached with the baseline calibration are still valid.
Finally, we checked the dependence of the results on the presence of a strategic interaction between regimes. To do so, we simulated the model imposing , thus shutting down the spillovers between the regimes.37
Table 3a: Markov-Switching Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Simple Interest Rate Rule
Baseline | |||
---|---|---|---|
% MSC(2) MSC(1) | .13 | .36 | .43 |
% Right Regime | .60 | .72 | .77 |
Table 3b: Markov-Switching Maximum Likelihood Estimation of a Simple Interest Rate Rule - Means of Parameters Estimates
Hawk | Dove | Hawk | Dove | Hawk | Dove | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
.8577 (.0185) | .8452 (.0319) | .7526 (.0238) | .7526 (.0238) | .8417 (.0299) | .8417 (.0299) | |
.2270 (.0635) | .1469 (.0792) | .7200 (.1066) | -.1124 (.0547) | 2.3285 (.2294) | -.2578 (.1232) | |
-.1954 (.0154) | -.1780 (.0288) | -.1525 (.0193) | -.1703 (.0426) | -.0775 (.0428) | -.3482 (.1159) | |
() | .1396 (.040) | .1470 (.049) | .2007 (.1030) | .1980 (.0843) | .1664 (.0686) | .1841 (.0762) |
.6191 (.0692) | .6525 (.0711) | .7685 (.1097) | .7287 (.0881) | .8413 (.0913) | .8400 (.0795) | |
Determinacy | Yes | No | Yes | No | Yes | No |
Notes: The Markov-switching criterion was computed for the 2-state model (MSC(2)) and the alternative specification with constant parameter across regimes (MSC(1)). The second row displays the average fraction of periods the estimation correctly identifies the regime in power. For each parameter, the table presents the mean estimate over 1000 simulations, each of 200 observations. Standard errors are reported in parenthesis. The convergence to global maxima was checked using alternative initial conditions
The performance of the estimation algorithm improves significantly, since it detects the presence of regime switches in 43% of the cases, and the correct regime is identified in 77% of the periods. This result, however, does not undermine the main conclusions obtained above, but rather highlights why explicitly modeling the strategic interactions is important. Strategic interactions between different policy regimes would be present in any economy with endogenous state variables, like private capital or public debt. In those cases, estimating simple policy rules that ignores such interactions may lead to erroneous conclusions about the underlying monetary policy decision process.
Regime shifts in macroeconomic relationships in general and central bank behavior in particular have been identified in the data. We study the effects of unstable objectives as a potential source of regime changes, and characterize policy choices in a variety of models and specifications. The central bank is allowed to react to the possibility of future changes, a central feature of modern economics that simple interest rules can not easily capture in a regime shifting framework.
The paper illustrates some perils of using switches in simple rules for positive and normative analyses, and identifies the conditions under which such analyses are less prone to error. We show that changes in simple rules cannot be interpreted solely as changes in policy objectives, but are potentially related to factors not under the central bank's control. Similarly, it may be difficult to detect unstable objectives, the regime in place, and the determinacy conditions through changes in simple rules.
It can be argued that central banks do not behave optimally, and that changes in simple rules reflect the central banks' ability to approach optimal policy. Our intuitions do not require an optimal behavior, but the weaker requirements of the presence of spillovers among alternative regimes and that central banks recognize a trade-off between inflation and output stabilization.
Finally, it is not our claim that unstable objectives are the main source of regime switches. Other factors not considered in the paper may also play a role, like structural factors or the information available to central banks. In this respect, incorporating the monetary monetary decision process into more complete regime switching models would constitute a crucial step towards the identification and the interpretation of the sources of monetary regime switches.
Adam, K., Billi, R., 2006. Optimal monetary policy under commitment with a zero bound on nominal interest rates. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38 (7), 1877-1905.
Alesina, A., Roubini, N., Cohen, G., 1997. Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy. The MIT Press.
Aoki, K., 2003. On the optimal monetary policy response to noisy indicators. Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 501-523.
Ball, L., Mankiw, N. G., 2002. The nairu in theory and practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (4), 115-136.
Barro, R. J., Gordon, D. B., 1983. Rules, discretion and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (1), 101-121.
Beaudry, P., Portier, F., September 2006. Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations. American Economic Review 96, 1293-1307.
Bianchi, F., 2010. Regime switches, agents' beliefs, and post-world war ii u.s. macroeconomic dynamics. Duke University. Manuscript.
Blanchard, O., Dell'Ariccia, G., Mauro, P., 2010. Rethinking macroeconomic policy. International Monetary Fund Staff Position Note.
Canova, F., Gambetti, L., 2009. Structural changes in the us economy: Is there a role for monetary policy? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33 (2), 477-490.
Carboni, G., Ellison, M., 2009. The great inflation and the greenbook. Journal of Monetary Economics 56 (6), 831-841.
Chari, V., Kehoe, P., McGrattan, E., 2009. New keynesian models: Not yet useful for policy analysis. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (1), 242-266.
Clarida, R., Gali, J., Gertler, M., 2000. Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (1), 147-180.
Cogley, T., Sargent, T. J., 02 2002. Evolving post-world war ii u.s. inflation dynamics. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001, Volume 16. NBER Chapters. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, pp. 331-388.
Davig, T., Doh, T., 2008. Monetary policy regime shifts and inflation persistence. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Research Working Paper.
Davig, T., Leeper, E., 2007. Generalizing the taylor principle. American Economic Review 97 (3), 607-635.
Debortoli, D., Nunes, R., 2010a. Fiscal policy under loose commitment. Journal of Economic Theory 145-3, 1005-1032.
Debortoli, D., Nunes, R., 2010b. The macroeconomic effect of external pressures on monetary policy. International Finance Discussion Papers N.944.
Dennis, R., 2004. Inferring policy objectives from economic outcomes. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 66 (1), 735-764.
Dennis, R., 2006. The policy preferences of the us federal reserve. Journal of Applied Econometrics 21 (1), 55-77.
Farmer, R. E., Waggoner, D. F., Zha, T., 2009. Understanding markov-switching rational expectations models. Journal of Economic Theory 144 (5), 1849-1867.
Faust, J., Irons, J., 1999. Money, politics and the post-war busines cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (1), 61-89.
Gali, J., 2008. Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework. Princeton University Press.
Gali, J., Gertler, M., Lopez-Salido, D., 2007. Markups, gaps and the welfare costs of business fluctuations. Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (1), 44-59.
Giannoni, M., Woodford, M., 2010. Optimal target criteria for stabilization policy. NBER Working Paper 15757.
Greenspan, A., 1994. Statement to the u.s. house committee on the budget, june 22, 1994. Federal Reserve Bulletin 80 (8), 714-719.
Hamilton, J. D., 1989. A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 57 (2), 357-84.
Hansen, L., Sargent, T., 2007. Robustness. Princeton University Press. Ireland, P. N., 2004. Technology shocks in the new keynesian model. The Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (4), 923-936.
Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G., 2008. Potential and natural output. Manuscript. Kim, C.-J., Nelson, C. R., 1999. State-Space Models with Regime-Switching: Classical and Gibbs-Sampling Approaches with Applications. The MIT Press, Cambridge Massachusets.
Liu, Z., Waggoner, D., Zha, T., 2009. Asymmetric expectation effects of regime shifts in monetary policy. Review of Economic Dynamics 12 (2), 284-303.
Lubik, T. A., Schorfheide, F., 2004. Testing for indeterminacy: An application to u.s. monetary policy. American Economic Review 94 (1), 190-217.
Lucas, R. J., 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1 (1), 19-46.
Marcet, A., Marimon, R., 1998. Recursive contracts. Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Working Paper.
Orphanides, A., 2001. Monetary policy rules based on real-time data. The American Economic Review 91 (4), 964-985.
Orphanides, A., 2002. Monetary-policy rules and the great inflation. The American Economic Review 92 (2), 115-120.
Orphanides, A., 2006. The road to price stability. The American Economic Review 96 (2), 178-181.
Owyang, M. T., Ramey, G., 2004. Regime switching and monetary policy measurement. Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (8), 1577-1597.
Rabanal, P., Rubio-Ramirez, J. F., 2005. Comparing new keynesian models of the business cycle: A bayesian approach. Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (6), 1151-1166.
Roberds, W., 1987. Models of policy under stochastic replanning. International Economic Review 28 (3), 731-755.
Schaumburg, E., Tambalotti, A., 2007. An investigation of the gains from commitment in monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (2), 302-324.
Sims, C. A., Zha, T., 2006. Were there regime switches in u.s. monetary policy? American Economic Review 96 (1), 54-81.
Smets, F., Wouters, R., 2003. An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (5), 1123-1175.
Smith, A., Naik, P. A., Tsai, C.-L., 2006. Markov-switching model selection using markov-switching model selection using kullback-leibler divergence. Journal of Econometrics 134, 553-577.
Stock, J., Watson, M., 2002. Has the Business Cycle Changed and Why? NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 159-218.
Woodford, M., 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton University Press.
Yun, T., 1996. Nominal price rigidity, money supply endogeneity and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 37 (2), 345-370.
Zampolli, F., 2006. Optimal monetary policy in a regime-switching economy: The response to abrupt shifts in exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 30 (9-10), 1527-1567.
Here we consider a particular case of problem (3), where , and .38 The first-order conditions of the problem are given by
(A-1) | ||
(A-2) | ||
(A-3) |
where is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the NKPC and .39 Since the model is linear-quadratic, we guess that expected inflation prevailing when objectives change is given by a linear rule
where is a coefficient to be determined. Rearranging equations (A-1) - (A-3) the following second-order difference equation is obtained:
(A-4) |
whose solution is given by
(A-5) |
where
(A-6) | ||
(A-7) |
Note that and and . 40 Moreover,
(A-8) |
and . The unique stable solution to (A-5) is given by the expression
(A-9) |
where and . Combining (A-9) with (A-1), using (A-2) to eliminate the Lagrange multiplier, and imposing the initial condition , equation (5) in the main text is obtained.
In the limiting case where , equations (A-2) and (A-3) remains unaltered, while (A-1) takes the form . Solving for the equilibrium, it holds
(A-10) |
The resulting law of motion is similar to (A-9). Indeed, the coefficient multiplying is the same as in (A-9) after imposing the condition . However, none of the variables depend on (or equivalently on ).
Given the above law of motion, it follows that in response to a cost-push shock
(A-11) |
Following a positive cost-push shock, the (absolute) initial change in inflation is therefore given by:
(A-12) |
An identical expression holds for the (standard) full-commitment and stable objectives case, whose corresponding variables are indicated with an upper bar. In comparison with that case, the slope of the impulse response function is then given by
which coincides with (8), and where the second equality is obtained using equation (7) and the definition of and . For that expression to be positive, and setting - the lowest possible value taken by that parameter for a hawkish regime - it must be that
or equivalently,
The right hand side of (A-13) only depends on the parameters , and on the ratio . Fixing and to the values described in Table (1), Figure (A-1) shows that condition (A-13) is always satisfied as long as and - a value well above the available estimates.
Consider that , , and for simplicity that the cost push-shock is not present then the FOCs of regime are:
(A-14) | |
(A-15) | |
(A-16) |
Figure A-1
Note: For any value of , the regions above the corresponding contour line indicate the values of and satisfying condition (A-13). The dot on the top-left corner indicates our baseline calibration for those parameters. The parameters and are set to the values described in Table (1).
Substituting (A14) and (A-15) into (A-16), and solving the resulting second-order difference equation, the following expression is obtained
(A-17) |
where is defined as in equation (A-6). For convenience, define , and notice that . Assuming regime is solving a symmetric problem, equations (A-17) and (A-14), together with the initial condition implies
(A-18) |
Substituting the last expression into (A-17), and using the fact that the law of motion of the Lagrange multiplier is given by
(A-19) |
Substituting this expression into (A-14) and (A-15), and imposing the initial condition (or equivalently ), the law of motion in equation (10) in the text is obtained. Notice that in the law of motion of the endogenous variables and the coefficients coincide with the case of the previous section in the limiting case where , but are responding to different variables. Indeed the previous term is now replaced by a regime weighted output-gap measure.
For notational convenience only, we consider a purely forward looking Phillips curve and we abstract from the presence of uncertainty other than the one regarding the policy objective changes. Results in the presence of a hybrid Phillips curve are available in the working paper version (). The problem is
(A-20) |
(A-21) | ||
(A-22) | ||
Proposition 1 Being the vector of lagrange multipliers associated with the constraints (A-21) and (A-22), problem (A-20) can be written as a saddle point functional equation (SPFE) as follows:
where
Proof. of Proposition 1. Define the real valued function as follows:
Moreover, and are defined as in the second part of the proposition. Problem (A-20) is therefore equivalent to:
This formulation fits the definition of Program 1 in Marcet and Marimon (1998). We can therefore write the problem as a saddle point functional equation in the sense that there exists a unique function satisfying:
where
or in a more intuitive formulation define
and the saddle point functional equation is:
Proposition 2 For any type of policy objectives the solution of problem (A-20) is a tenure invariant function , such that:
Proof. of Proposition 2. Using Proposition 1, this proof follows directly from the results of Marcet and Marimon (1998).
Consider a simple New-Keynesian economy characterized by a dynamic IS equation (15), a NKPC (1) and where monetary policy is conducted according to the simple interest rate rule (14). The solution of this model is given by
(A-23) |
where and , corresponding to equation (16) in the main text.41 We are assuming a standard calibration with stationary shocks , positive interest rate rule coefficients , and a unique rational expectations stationary equilibrium .
It is now possible to analyze how the responses of our variables to the different shocks, and the implied conditional volatilities, are affected by changes in policy parameters. It can be noticed that
(A-24) | ||
(A-25) |
The following properties are then satisfied:
The composite effects on the unconditional volatilities of our variables thus depend on the volatilities of the shocks , as well as on their correlation .
The (unconditional) volatility of inflation and output are given by
(A-26) | ||
(A-27) |
where , and are, respectively, the variances of the shocks , and their contemporaneous correlation.
Taking the derivatives of (A-26) and (A-27), and assuming that the two shocks are uncorrelated ( ), the following hold:
(A-28) | ||
(A-29) |
In other words, regardless of the relative volatility of the underlying shocks, the unconditional volatility of inflation is decreasing in and the unconditional volatility of output is decreasing in .42 Moreover,
(A-30) | ||
(A-31) |
and
(A-32) | ||
(A-33) |
We can then conclude that, as long as condition (17) holds, a change in policy parameters leads to the volatility of both inflation and output to move in the same direction.
If objectives are stable and the central bank is behaving optimally the implied paths of inflation and output are described by the equations (5) and (6) for the case where . The (unconditional) variances of inflation and output are given by:
(A-34) | ||
(A-35) |
with and .
In this case a change in policy parameters is given by a change in the relative weight of output stabilization (). Noticing that , it follows that
where the last inequality follows from noticing that the term in the round brackets is increasing in and taking its limit as . This clarifies that a change in , as opposed to changes in simple rule parameters, always drives the volatility of inflation and output in opposite directions.
1. See for instance Cogley and Sargent (2002), Stock and Watson (2002), Sims and Zha (2006), Canova and Gambetti (2009) and the literature reviewed therein. Return to text
2. Dennis (2004, 2006) are two exceptions considering that monetary policy is set optimally in the estimation exercise. Return to text
3. For a recent paper on the importance of the policymaker's expectations see Carboni and Ellison (2009). Return to text
4. While there is some agreement that the output target should be the output level with flexible prices, there is much less agreement on how to measure such concept and which shocks affect it. The inflation target itself is also subject to debate, see for instance Blanchard et al. (2010). Return to text
5. Theoretical models in this literature did not contemplate this possibility. On the empirical side, Alesina et al. (1997) point out several empirical successes of political cycle models, whereas Faust and Irons (1999) conclude that partisan effects in US macroeconomic data are fragile, and that there is little evidence that the partisan effects on the economy operate through changes in monetary policy. Return to text
6. The theoretical framework underlying such relationship is described in Yun (1996), Woodford (2003) and Galí (2008). This specification of the NKPC holds in a neighborhood of a zero inflation steady state. Throughout our analysis, we abstract from the changes that may derive from having a different steady state level of inflation. Return to text
7. It is also plausible that different views coexist in central bank boards, in which case the current regime would correspond to the one holding decision power at a certain point in time. Orphanides (2006) states that "members of the FOMC hold diverse views, and consequently the views of the chairman do not necessarily reflect the consensus of the Committee". The appointment of a new Board member could therefore introduce a regime change. Return to text
8. and are value functions in the presence of disagreement between successive policymakers, therefore unlike Debortoli and Nunes (2010a) one can not use an envelope result. We have also examined the results with a hybrid NKPC, in which case the value function derivative enters the first order conditions. Return to text
9. We are therefore not considering trigger strategies as in Barro and Gordon (1983). When a reoptimization does not occur, policies depend both on the natural state variables and past promises as in Marcet and Marimon (1998). Return to text
10. This holds conditionally on being in a certain regime . When objectives switch to type , a new plan is made and the term on lagged output is discarded. Return to text
11. Zampolli (2006) analyzes exchange rate regime switches and optimal policy in a model with backward looking expectations where these type of interactions are not present. In our forward-looking model such spillovers would be absent only in the very particular case of i.i.d. cost-push shocks and no endogenous state variables. Section 3.2 considers an alternative type of objective instability that turns out to be similar to a unit root in the cost-push shock process. Return to text
12. See for instance the examples in Woodford (2003, ch. 4) and Galí (2008, ch. 5). Return to text
13. This follows from the definition of together with the fact that is increasing in . Return to text
14. Section A-1.1 in the appendix explores more extreme calibrations. As long as the hawkish regime weights inflation more than output (), it suffices that , a value well above available estimates. Return to text
15. Using a similar argument as above, the sign of (8) depends on the parametrization and cannot be univocally determined for the dovish regime. Return to text
16. See e.g. Davig and Doh (2008) and Bianchi (2010). Results are amplified when considering more frequent switches or a central bank with a dual mandate (). Return to text
17. The available estimates of medium and large scale DSGE models (e.g. Smets and Wouters (2003)) with multiple sources of fluctuations are not directly comparable with our reduced form shocks. The chosen values for the standard deviations of the shocks are only relevant for the Monte Carlo exercise of section 4 where we also consider alternative calibrations. Return to text
18. This result is due in part to a loss in credibility, as can be seen in the table comparing the volatilities with full and limited commitment. However, unstable objectives in comparison with limited commitment increase the volatilities for the hawk but reduce them for the dove. Accordingly, the hawk induces a positive welfare externality, whereas the dove introduces a negative externality with respect to the limited commitment case. Return to text
19. It is not clear that central banks have the credibility to disregard distortions that impair ignificantly economic activity. The Federal Reserve and ECB actions in the 2008-2010 crisis constitute examples where such issues are at the very least debatable. Return to text
20. Policymakers themselves seem to be aware of such issues; answering a question on "the so-called 'natural rate' of unemployment" Alan Greenspan on June 22, 1994 said "[w]hile the idea of a national 'threshold' at which short-term inflation rises or falls is statistically appealing, it is very difficult in practice to arrive at useful estimates that would identify such a natural rate." (see Greenspan (1994)). For a discussion see Ball and Mankiw (2002) and for recent attempts to estimate the efficient level of output see for example Gali et al. (2007) and Justiniano an Primiceri (2008). Return to text
21. The system is initialized at . Return to text
22. Since the micro-foundations of cost-push shocks are not well understood, we regard this result as a contribution in itself. Cost-push shocks have been modeled, for example, as exogenous variations in price and wage markups (see e.g. Woodford (2003) and Galí (2008)). Return to text
23. When objectives change and become dovish, both inflation and output expand. Therefore, it is the anticipation and not the realization of the shock that resembles the traditional (positive) cost-push shock. In this respect, our argument is similar to the important distinction between current shocks and news about future shocks (see e.g. Beaudry and Portier (2006)). Return to text
24. We are not claiming that the policy functions are time-invariant, as they change in different periods within a tenure. In order to solve our problem we have to find the policy functions satisfying the equilibrium conditions ( policy functions per regime). As shown in equation (13), the policies of each regime interact and therefore we have to solve a fixed point problem in such policy functions. In addition, the implied value functions and also enter the problem and need to be solved for endogenously. We also have to take into account the possibility of default on past promises, an event that occurs whenever there is a change in objectives. Return to text
25. Schaumburg and Tambalotti (2007) also consider an output-gap target of 0.1. Return to text
26. The first period of the hawkish regime (period 1) is fundamentally different from any initial period after being reconfirmed (periods 5, 9, 13 in the graph). Periods 5, 9, and 13 are characterized by low inflation that was promised in the previous period. Past promises are not binding in period 1 because each regime reoptimizes. Return to text
27. The corresponding derivations are omitted for brevity and available in the working paper version Debortoli and Nunes (2010b). Return to text
28. For instance Clarida et al. (2000) and Lubik and Schorfheide (2004) find regime switches whereas Sims and Zha (2006) do not. Return to text
29. We have explored numerically that the results obtained are robust to many alternative interest rate rules displaying forward and backward looking terms in inflation, output-gap and interest rate. Return to text
30. This assumption greatly simplifies our algebra without affecting qualitatively the results. A non-zero correlation between and arises when the flexible price equilibrium is not attainable. For example, in a model with sticky prices and sticky wages the term would be an endogenous variable, which is a linear function of the shock . Return to text
31. See for instance Rabanal and Rubio-Ramirez (2005) and Adam and Billi (2006). Return to text
32. Our analysis focuses mainly on simple interest rate rules because these are usually employed in empirical studies. Giannoni and Woodford (2010) discuss targeting rules implementing the optimal policy with similar form to simple interest rate rules. In some cases, those rules can be invariant to objective instability. However, the targeting rule parameters depend on the preferences. If the implied cross restrictions on the parameters are ignored, similar issues arise. Return to text
33. The Monte Carlo exercise uses 1000 histories of 200 periods each, which is comparable to the number of quarters available using the actual data from 1960-2010. The exercise also assumes that the econometrician knows all the parameters except those of the simple rule. Removing that assumption gives less information to the econometrician and may imply that the misspecification problem biases the estimation of the other structural parameters. Examining such bias is interesting but goes beyond the scope of this paper. Return to text
34. We chose maximum likelihood estimation over Bayesian estimation methods because we need to estimate the model many times. Using Bayesian methods would increase the computation time dramatically and could bias the results of the Monte Carlo experiment by imposing restrictive priors. Return to text
35. The estimates in some studies should be changed to for direct comparability. Return to text
36. In the work of Davig and Leeper (2007), considering the dove in isolation would deliver an indeterminate solution, but the presence of the hawk renders the solution determinate. Here the problem is of a different nature. Indeterminacy is detected even though the hawk and the dove always deliver a determinate equilibrium both in isolation and jointly. The calculation of determinacy conditions with regime switches and specially when the dynamic system has lagged variables is not clear and is subject to debate (see Davig and Leeper (2007) and Farmer et al. (2009) among others). Due to this reason, we have calculated the determinacy conditions ignoring the possibility of regime changes. Return to text
37. We are also not allowing for switches on the output-gap target, which would introduce a strategic interaction as shown in section 3.2. Return to text
38. For notational convenience, we suppress the superscript , and indicate with the superscript the variables related to the alternative regime. Return to text
39. See Marcet and Marimon (1998). Return to text
40. The solution is always a real number since
41. The associated derivations are standard, and available upon request. Return to text
42. This holds also in the more general cases with a positive correlation between and . Return to text
This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text