Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
International Finance Discussion Papers
Number 1057, October 2012 --- Screen Reader
Version*
NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.
Abstract:
A longstanding puzzle is that the United States is a net borrower from the rest of the world, yet continues to receive income on its external position. A large difference between the yields on direct investment at home and abroad is responsible and this paper examines potential explanations for this differential. We find that most of the differential disappears after one adjusts for the U.S. taxes owed by the parent on foreign earnings, the sovereign risk and sunk costs associated with investing abroad, and the age of foreign direct investment in the U.S.. Taken together, our results suggest most of the difference in yields should remain as long as there is a difference in tax rates between the United States and the countries in which U.S. firms invest, and U.S. investments are perceived as relatively safe. This has implications for the long-run sustainability of the U.S. current account deficit which will depend, in part, on the long-run behavior of this income.
Keywords: Foreign direct investment, returns differentials, U.S. current account
JEL classification: F21, F23, F3
A longstanding puzzle is that the United States is a net borrower from the rest of the world, yet somehow manages to, on net, receive income on its external position. Net investment income receipts reported in the U.S. balance of payments (BOP), the top line in Figure 1, have continued to grow even while the net liabilities position, the bottom line, has also grown. This situation has mystified economists for almost a quarter-century:
"Clearly, if our investments abroad are yielding a positive return, their capital value must be positive not negative. Is this a defect of the figures on current flows, or is it a defect of the balance-sheet figures?..." (Milton Friedman, 1987)1
The income received on the U.S. external position plays an important role in one of the biggest issues confronting international macroeconomists--the sustainability (or lack thereof) of the U.S. current account deficit. Net income receipts, which equaled 33% of the goods and services balance in 2010, provide a significant stabilizing force for the current account. Future sustainability will depend, in part, on the persistence of these net income receipts. So an understanding of what is generating this income will help economists assess how the U.S. imbalance might evolve.
A single asset class is responsible for the puzzle. Net income receipts in the BOP owe entirely to a difference between the yields (income divided by the position) on direct investment claims and liabilities (Hung and Mascaro 2004, Bosworth et al. 2008, Bridgeman 2008, Curcuru, Dvorak and Warnock 2008). The aggregate yield on U.S. cross-border claims averaged 140 basis points per year higher than that paid on U.S. cross-border liabilities from 1990-2010, shown in the first columns of Figure 2. The next columns show that the main driver of this difference was foreign direct investment (FDI); the average yield received on U.S. FDI claims was an impressive 620 basis points per year higher than that paid on liabilities. In contrast, for portfolio equity and debt the average yields on claims and liabilities were nearly identical. The overall yield advantage was enough to move the income balance in favor of U.S. claims despite the large net liability position.2
Why is there such a large difference between the yield received on U.S. direct investment abroad (USDIA) and that paid on foreign direct investment in the United States (FDIUS)? Several studies suggest that the large difference between these yields is the result of USDIA earnings that are unusually high, FDIUS earnings that are unusually low, or a combination of the two. These conclusions are drawn from comparisons between U.S. FDI yields and yields which, at least on the surface, appear to be similar. However a closer look at the comparator yields used in these studies reveals some important differences. Some studies compare pre-tax with post-tax yields. Other studies use comparator yields that are only valid in certain situations; for example, when the affiliate borrows only from the parent firm. Our approach in this paper is to first closely examine DI earnings and position data to find the most comparable measures before constructing yields. We then identify any remaining differences between the investments and quantify how these differences might affect yields.
We identify several reasons for the large differential between USDIA and FDIUS yields. In foreign countries, U.S. multinational enterprises (MNEs) earn about the same on their USDIA as do investors from other countries, but the yield on USDIA is above that of firms operating in the US. For USDIA we focus on the return from the parent firm's perspective, and calculate the return net of all tax liabilities and estimate the amount of compensation for the risks specific to investing abroad. We find that taxes and risk account for all but about 50 basis points of the average difference between USDIA yields and those earned by U.S. firms on their domestic operations (USIUS) since 2004, and all but about 100 basis points over the entire sample. Compensation for the sunk costs of investing abroad can account for the rest. Years in which FDIUS significantly underperformed domestic investments followed significant increases in U.S. investments by foreign parents--in other words, FDIUS performed relatively poorly when it was relatively young. In recent years, however, FDIUS has performed about as well as other investments in the United States.
Taken together, compensation for taxes, risk, sunk costs, and age account for virtually all of the difference between USDIA and FDIUS yields. Favorable transfer prices associated with trade between related firms further narrows the gap. Therefore we agree with Bosworth et al (2008) that the difference between USDIA and FDIUS yields is not "an illusion of bad data" as suggested in the quotation in the opening paragraph; rather, data quirks and investment differences create a divergence between these returns, the effect of which has decreased in recent years. Looking ahead, we expect this differential will narrow further if the FDIUS capital stock continues to age or the relative perceived risk of investing abroad decreases.
This paper contributes to the literature on sustainability, returns differentials, and FDI in several ways. Work by Cavallo and Tille (2006) and Kitchen (2007) shows that the positive income yield differential limits pressure on the exchange rate in the event of a trade balance adjustment. Our results, which suggest the yield differential is likely to persist, tend to lower the probability of a rapid decline of the U.S. exchange rate predicted by these models. Several papers have noted the large yield and capital gains differential between U.S. claims and liabilities (Lane and Milesi - Ferretti 2005; Obstfeld and Rogoff 2005; Meissner and Taylor 2006; Gourinchas and Rey 2007; Forbes 2010; Habib 2010; Gourinchas et al. 2010), although some of the difference in capital gains may be overstated because of inconsistent data (Curcuru, Dvorak and Warnock 2008; Curcuru, Thomas and Warnock 2009; Lane and Milesi - Ferretti 2009). This paper is also the first paper to fully account for all the components of the DI differential. Throughout this paper we discuss implications for the yield differentials of the extensive work done by Desai, Foley and Hines on the factors influencing FDI decisions.
The paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 summarizes existing literature, Section 3 compares USDIA yields with those on direct investment liabilities reported by other countries; Section 4 compares USDIA and FDIUS yields with yields on domestic operation of U.S. firms; Section 5 summarizes what the results suggest for future differences between USDIA and FDIUS yields; and Section 6 concludes.
Existing literature suggests that USDIA yields are abnormally-high, FDIUS yields are abnormally-low, or a combination of the two. The focus of most studies has been the role of firm characteristics (firm age, industry, intangibles, productivity), transfer costs, and taxes.
Several papers link low FDIUS yields to the relative youth of FDIUS affiliates (Lupo et al. 1978, Landefeld et al. 1992, Grubert et al. 1993, Laster and McCauley 1994, Grubert 1997, Mataloni 2000, McGrattan and Prescott 2010). Many new firms have relatively high expenses associated with depreciation of newly-purchased assets or interest on debt used to finance acquisitions. Inexperience can also lead to relatively poor performance for younger firms.
The industry mix of FDIUS is dramatically different than USDIA and U.S. investment more generally, with a large share of USDIA classified as holding companies and a large share of FDIUS classified as manufacturing firms. However, Mataloni (2000), the only study examining the role of composition, finds that the return on FDIUS assets was below that of U.S. operations for most industries.
Other work suggests that differing amounts of investment in intangible capital (defined in Bridgeman (2008) as patents, trademarks, trade secrets, and organizational knowledge) is responsible for the large difference between FDIUS and USDIA yields. The value of intangible capital is excluded from the valuation method for DI that BEA features, the current-cost method, because of measurement difficulties.3 Bridgeman (2008) estimates the stocks of intangible assets and finds that including them in the USDIA and FDIUS positions reduces the gap between USDIA and FDIUS yields by three-fourths. McGrattan and Prescott (2010) finds the FDIUS yield is held down by the large amount of research and development investment these firms engage in, which is accounted for as an expense. However, they find that the USDIA yield is higher than can be explained by intangible capital and other factors in their model.4
Studies in the trade literature find that relatively more productive U.S. firms are more likely to engage in FDI, which leads to higher USDIA yields relative to domestic-only firms (Helpman et al. 2004, Fillat and Garetto 2010). These models suggest the high return of USDIA relative to USIUS is compensation for the higher sunk costs and risks associated with FDI.
Early studies find little evidence that the low FDIUS yield arises from favorable intrafirm transfer pricing. Lester and McCauley (1994) and Mataloni (2000) find no difference in the earnings of firms with a significant share of imports from the foreign parent and those with a smaller share. Similarly, Grubert (1997) finds no difference in the earnings of FDIUS affiliates which are wholly owned by the parent and those with a smaller share of foreign ownership. In more recent work Bernard et al (2006) examines detailed price and transaction data on U.S. exports and imports and finds that the prices of exports to related firms are systematically lower than exports to unrelated firms, while the prices of imports from related firms are systematically higher. These pricing anomalies should have some effect on USDIA or FDIUS yields. Although reliable estimates of the size of the effects cannot be constructed, because firm nationality is not tracked in the trade data, we provide some sense of their magnitude in Section 5..
A series of papers by Desai, Foley and Hines (hence DFH) shows that affiliate funding, dividend repatriations, and the location of MNE subsidiaries are heavily influenced by tax considerations. Because U.S. tax laws generally allow U.S. MNEs to defer U.S. taxes on foreign income until that income is repatriated, foreign operations in low-tax jurisdictions are disproportionately funded using reinvested earnings rather than new equity capital. In contrast, affiliates in relatively high-tax jurisdictions are funded using debt finance (Feldstein 1994 and DFH 2001, 2003, 2004)). DFH (2001) finds that USDIA affiliates in countries with 1% lower tax rates on foreign income have 1% lower dividend payout rates. Looking across affiliate countries, DFH (2004) finds that USDIA affiliates located in countries with relatively high tax rates had a higher debt-to-asset ratio in order to take advantage of the tax deductibility of interest payments, and that internal borrowing was particularly sensitive to tax rates. Complementary work by Grubert (1998) finds that interest payments to USDIA parents are higher for affiliates in countries with higher statutory tax rates. DFH (2006) finds that large U.S. MNEs with heavy research and development spending and relatively large amounts of intra-firm trade are most likely to have affiliates located in tax havens. Bosworth et al. (2008) estimates that the diversion of income to low-tax jurisdictions accounts for one-third of the difference in USDIA and USIUS yields.
Other explanations for the low FDIUS yield include a relatively low cost of capital in the home country (Grubert et al. 1993 ), price concessions to gain access to the U.S. market or scarce raw materials (Landefeld et al. 1992), and several high-profile U.S. investments by foreigners in the 1980's which had particularly poor results (Laster and McCauley 1994, Jorion 1996). Other explanations for the large gap between USDIA and FDIUS yields include compensation for the additional risk of investing in countries with low sovereign credit ratings (Hung and Mascaro 2004), the venture capitalist nature of the U.S external position which issues safe assets while investing in risky assets (Gourinchas and Rey 2007), and the "erroneous" inclusion of reinvested earnings in income which artificially boosts USDIA earnings (Gros 2006).
USDIA yields are double those earned by other cross-border claims and liabilities (Figure 2), which has led some to conclude that the data are misreported (Gros 2006, Hausmann and Sturzenegger 2006). In our first analysis we take a different approach than earlier papers which compared USDIA yields to those earned on other assets or in different locations. We focus our comparison on similar investments; at the country level we compare USDIA yields in a given country with the yield on all direct investment in that country (ACDIA). To the extent that USDIA investment in each country is similar to that undertaken by non-U.S. investors, the yields should be similar. A finding of similar yields would suggest that the seemingly-high USDIA yields are not unusual or temporary.
A close look at global direct investment earnings and positions data needed for a cross-country comparison of DI yields reveals that neither is reported on a consistent basis across countries. USDIA earnings are measured using the Current Operating Performance Concept (COPC) recommended by the IMF, which includes reinvested earnings and intercompany debt payments in income and excludes capital gains and losses. In a survey conducted by the IMF only 19 out of 61 countries (8 OECD countries) fully applied the COPC to inward DI earnings, and only 16 out of 61 (7 OECD) to outward earnings.5 These deviations from the COPC standard can have a large impact on reported DI earnings. For example, France excludes the reinvested earnings of indirectly held subsidiaries from income; a similar omission from USDIA earnings would lower yields by one-third or over 300 basis points per year.6 In addition, it is difficult to estimate the market values of private companies, particularly in countries without liquid stock markets, so the DI positions published by most countries value firms using some combination of historical cost and market values. Because of these data variations we focus on the 8 countries that fully apply the COPC method, and provide results for an expanded selection of countries in the appendix. The ACDIA yield for each country is the ratio of net income payments associated with DI liabilities to the amount of DI liabilities, from the Balance of Payments statistics published by the IMF.7
In addition to different measures of earnings, accounting methods also vary. BEA reports country-level earnings on a financial accounting (historical cost) basis, and computes current-cost adjustments needed to transform earnings to an economic accounting basis only at the aggregate level. We use historical cost earnings to compute yields because this is how earnings are reported in the U.K. and many other countries. However, including current-cost adjustments in earnings does not change our conclusions.8 Similarly, country-level positions are reported at historical cost value and the adjustments needed to transform the position to a current-cost or market-value basis are released by BEA only at the aggregate level. We adjust the country-level positions from a historical-cost to current-cost basis using the ratio of the aggregates when we compute USDIA country-level yields.9
We find that USDIA yields in most countries are similar to or below those earned by other foreign investors in those countries. For 5 out of 8 countries in Table 1 the USDIA yield is below the ACDIA yield, significantly so for 3 countries. In the U.K., where 13% of USDIA is located, U.S. investors earn 6.7% on their USDIA, while all foreign investors in the U.K. earn significantly more--8.5%, on average. In Canada, home to almost 8% of USDIA, the average yields of U.S. and foreign investors on their DI are nearly identical. The yield on USDIA investments in Ireland is surprisingly high--almost 18% per year--but not as high as that earned on all DI in Ireland, which earns almost 22% per year.10
The last line of Table 1 presents average USDIA and ACDIA yields, where the average is weighted by the USDIA position share in the sample each year. The average yield is lower for USDIA--7.5% for USDIA vs. 8.5% for ACDIA --and the difference is statistically significant at the 10% level. Figure 3 shows these yields track each other very closely over the sample period. The weighted average USDIA yield for this sample is noticeably lower than the aggregate USDIA yield because the sample excludes many tax havens which do not report the data needed to calculate ACDIA yield. For an expanded selection which includes countries that do not fully apply the COPC method, Appendix Table A1, the weighted USDIA yield averages 30 basis points per year higher than ACDIA, and the difference between the two weighted yields is not significant. At least by this measure, there is no evidence that USDIA earnings are unusual, or any indication that they should not persist. Next we examine how USDIA and FDUIS yields compare with yields on other U.S. investments.
Several studies find that USDIA yields are significantly higher than those of U.S. domestic operations (USIUS), while FDIUS yields are significantly lower (Bosworth et al 2008, MacGrattan and Prescott 2010). We begin this section with a discussion of alternative measures of USIUS yields, and then move to comparisons of USIUS yields with USDIA and FDIUS yields.
Many studies use the yield on tangible assets (YTA) for all U.S. firms as a benchmark for evaluating USDIA and FDIUS yields (Howenstine and Lawson 1991, Bosworth et al. 2008, among others). This measure excludes financial assets and liabilities and their associated interest expenses from the position and income. Compared with YTA, USDIA yields appear unusually high, while FDIUS yields appear unusually low.
Despite its frequent use, YTA is a weak benchmark for U.S. DI yields because YTA cannot be constructed from the available DI data. DI income reported in the BOP includes earnings on all assets, including net interest income associated with financial assets, and includes interest payments on intercompany debt paid to the U.S. (for USDIA) or foreign (for FDIUS) parent. BEA does not separately report net financial assets and interest expenses of the affiliates--it only reports those associated with intercompany debt--so YTA cannot be constructed for USDIA and FDIUS affiliates. YTA may differ markedly from a yield measure that includes net financial assets if affiliates have significant borrowing from entities other than the parent firm, which U.S. FDI surveys suggest is indeed the case.11
Given this weakness of YTA as a DI yield benchmark, we instead construct a yield which includes net interest payments in earnings and financial assets in the position, and is much closer in spirit to the yield that can be constructed for USDIA and FDIUS affiliates from BEA data. We label this net yield measure USIUS_min. (To maintain comparability with earlier literature we also show YTA, which we label USIUS_max.) USDIA, FDIUS, and USIUS yields are shown in Figure 4, and details on the data series used to construct these yields are given in Appendix Table A2. Consistent with earlier literature, USDIA yields are significantly higher than both FDIUS and USIUS yields, and for much of the sample FDIUS is below USIUS. We reconcile the differences between these yields in the next sections.
As we did with ACDIA, our first step is to make sure we are making an apples-to-apples comparison between USDIA and USIUS yields. We then compute the USDIA return from the parent firms' perspective, and estimate the magnitude of other systematic factors that might account for differences between the two yields including tax accounting and compensation for risk and the sunk costs of investing abroad.
USDIA earnings reported in the BOP and USIUS earnings reported in the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA) have different tax treatments. USDIA earnings in the BOP are net of foreign taxes, but the U.S. taxes paid by U.S. parents on those earnings are not deducted. This is because U.S. taxes due on USDIA earnings are paid by the U.S. parent firm, so they are not cross-border transactions. While U.S. parents receive a credit for foreign income taxes paid against their U.S. tax liability, because the U.S. tax rate is generally higher most U.S. parents still owe some U.S tax on repatriated earnings even after this credit (Hines 1996). So, as implied in Bridgeman (2008), the USDIA yield computed using unadjusted BOP data generally overstates the after-tax earnings of the U.S. parent firm. In contrast, USIUS and FDIUS earnings are already net of all taxes.12
We estimate the U.S. taxes owed on USDIA earnings in two steps. First, we construct an estimate of the USDIA yield net of U.S. taxes associated with earnings repatriated to the U.S. parent firm. We estimate the yearly tax liability on repatriated income using the U.S. tax rates from KPMG (2010), less a credit for foreign taxes paid if the U.S. tax rate is higher than the foreign tax rate.13 If the foreign tax rate is higher than the U.S. tax rate there is no additional U.S. tax liability. Deducting estimated U.S. tax payments from affiliate earnings reduces the USDIA yield by about 80 basis points, in Table 2, from an average of 9.1% to 8.3% per year. We view this as a lower-bound for the compensation required by U.S. parent firms for the U.S. tax liability associated with USDIA earnings.
In the second step, we adjust the yield for all taxes that will eventually be paid, including taxes on reinvested earnings which are not immediately due. U.S. parents pay U.S. taxes on foreign affiliate earnings only when those earnings are repatriated, which allows firms to defer a portion of their U.S. tax liability by reinvesting earnings in a foreign affiliate. U.S. MNEs use intricate corporate structures to aggressively funnel earnings to low income-tax jurisdictions and defer U.S. taxes on those earnings by reinvesting them abroad.
Although U.S. taxes on reinvested earnings are not paid immediately, the potential U.S. tax liability associated with those earnings is likely an important factor when firms decide whether the earnings potential of a DI investment offers a high enough return. This is because the firm might not be certain, ex ante, of how much they will need to repatriate to support domestic operations. While U.S. firms might obviously prefer to never repatriate affiliate earnings in order to forever delay the additional U.S. tax liability, there is evidence that many firms choose repatriation strategies that are not optimal from a tax perspective.14 So as an upper bound for the tax-related compensation required by U.S. parent firms we calculate and subtract from earnings U.S. taxes that would be due had the affiliate repatriated all of its earnings.15 This reduces the USDIA yield by an additional 100 basis points per year to 7.3 percent (Table 2), bringing the average adjustment for U.S. taxes to 180 basis points per year. The tax-adjusted yields, plotted in Figure 5, are much closer to the USIUS yields, particularly during the last decade.
The remaining difference between USDIA and USIUS yields--150-260 basis points depending on the USIUS measure--is greater than can be explained solely by earnings volatility. Table 2 also reports that the Sharpe (1966) ratio of the after-tax USDIA yield is significantly higher than that of even our upper-bound estimate for USIUS.16 Some of this remaining difference could be compensation for other risks associated with investing abroad, discussed next.
Some of the risks faced by MNEs beyond those faced by domestic-only firms include foreign regulations, foreign tax policy, fluctuations in foreign demand, U.S. tax policy for foreign investments, and dependence on the foreign labor and goods markets. So the relatively high yields earned by MNEs likely represent compensation for these additional risks relative to domestic-only firms. Otherwise, as pointed out in Fillat and Garetto (2010), investors would not bother holding the equities of domestic-only firms in equilibrium.
To estimate how much might be required to compensate investors for the additional risks associated with investing abroad we use credit-default swaps (CDS) spreads on sovereign debt when they are available, and corporate debt spreads in earlier years. CDS are a form of insurance that compensates the holder when the issuer of the underlying bond defaults (i.e., fails to make an interest or principal payment), and are commonly used as a proxy for the amount of compensation required for investors to invest in a country. We calculate the average difference between foreign country and U.S. CDS spreads on sovereign debt, weighted by the share of the USDIA position in each country each year. Because of the extensive use of intermediate firms in low-income-tax and low-sovereign risk jurisdictions--about 36% of USDIA in 2010-- recent USDIA positions have been shown to be a poor representation of where the activity of foreign affiliates actually occurs (Borga and Mataloni 2001). So we construct weights based on the positions in 1999 when the use of intermediate holding companies was more limited (about 7% of USDIA).
The average difference between U.S. and foreign sovereign CDS spreads, our proxy for compensation for sovereign risk, averaged 70.4 basis points per year between 2004 and 2010 (Table 3).17 For earlier years when U.S. and other CDS spreads are unavailable we follow Hung and Mascaro (2004) and use the spread between the yields on AAA and Baa-rated corporate debt published Moody's as a proxy for risk compensation.18 For these earlier years the weighted risk adjustment averages 98 basis points. Putting the two risk adjustments together, the estimated compensation for risk over the entire sample averages 91 basis points per year.
After adjustments for taxes and risk, the estimated yield on USDIA falls to 6.4% per year (Table 2). The total compensation for taxes and risk averages 270 basis points per year, which is the bulk of the 330-440 basis point difference per year between unadjusted USDIA and USIUS yields. The remaining difference might represent compensation for the sunk costs of investing abroad, discussed next.
The remaining difference between USDIA (after-tax) and USUIS yields averages between 60 and 170 basis points per year over the entire sample (Table 2), and all but 50 basis points of the difference since 2004. Other literature suggests that foreign investments should also include compensation for sunk costs specific to investing in a foreign country. For example, in the models of Helpman et al. (2004) and Fillat and Garretto (2010) FDI investments are subject to sunk costs beyond those encountered domestically. Fillat and Garetto (2010) estimate that compensation for these sunk costs adds 25% to MNE yields relative to the yields of domestic-only exporters. This translates to 120-145 basis points based on our USIUS estimates, roughly equal to the difference that remains between USDIA and USIUS yields after we adjust for taxes and risk. In sum, we estimate that compensation for taxes, risk, and sunk costs accounts for around 400 basis points of the 9.1% yield on USDIA. Now that we have reconciled the difference between USDIA and USIUS yields, we turn to FDIUS yields.
Existing literature reports that the yield on FDIUS has been low relative to YTA (USIUS_max in Figure 4), and for much of the sample FDIUS also underperformed the net U.S. yield (USIUS_min). This underperformance was striking in the early 1990s and 2000s--totaling almost 600 basis points in 1991 and averaging over 300 basis points per year between 1988 and 2002. However, Figure 4 shows that since 2002 the gap has closed considerably, suggesting a permanent change has affected the relative profitability of FDIUS.
One potential explanation for the comparatively low yield earned by FDIUS affiliates is their age. Several studies suggest that the relative youth of FDIUS affiliates has played a role in their low profitability relative to other U.S. firms (Lupo et al. 1978, Landefeld et al. 1992, Grubert et al. 1993, Laster and McCauley 1994, Grubert 1997, Mataloni 2000). Younger firms may underperform more experienced firms because of inexperience, startup costs, or interest expenses on debt used to fund acquisitions.
To see how age effects FDIUS yields we construct several proxies for affiliate age using the equation:
where AGE represents the "newness" of the FDIUS investment; specifically, the share of FDIUS that has occurred in the last T years. We use several types of investment in AGEVAR, including outlays to acquire or establish new FDIUS, increases in U.S. affiliates' intercompany debt payables, and increases in parent equity. We also construct a measure of the relative age of FDIUS and USIUS using the differential between the growth rates of the respective positions. The weight variable w ( = 1) represents effects such as learning which decay the importance of new investment over time. We sum weighted investment over T prior years and scale by the FDIUS position. Estimates for AGE, shown in Figure 6, suggest that there have been three waves of new FDIUS investment during the last 30 years; 1987-1990, 1998-2001, and to a lesser extent 2008-2010. Glancing back at Figure 4, it is apparent that FDIUS underperformed USIUS during these three investment waves, suggesting that affiliate age does depress the FDIUS yield.
To more precisely measure the relationship between AGE and FDIUS yields we regress FDIUS yields on USIUS yields and AGE from equation (1):
A significant and negative b will confirm results from earlier studies that the underperformance is linked to firm age. The regressions results, presented in Table 4, suggest that FDIUS performance is indeed related to new investment by foreign parents as b is negative and significant in every specification. The adjusted-R2 values are quite high, ranging between 41% and 74%. New intercompany debt has the most explanatory power, suggesting that debt service costs play a large role, likely in the form of higher outside borrowing costs. The age effect subtracts 150 basis points on average from FDIUS (based on the first specification in Table 4), and in the absence of age effects the FDIUS yield increases to 5%--higher than USIUS_min, which averages 4.7% (Table 2). An FDIUS estimate where the effects of age have been removed, plotted in Figure 7, closely tracks USIUS_min, even during new investment waves.
This evidence confirms the results of previous studies which concluded that age was an important factor in the comparatively poor performance of FDIUS. However, since 2002 FDIUS affiliates have matured and there is little underperformance. So far have we accounted for most of the difference between FDIUS and USIUS, in addition to accounting for most of the difference between USDIA and USIUS. We end this section with a discussion of the difference between USDIA and FDIUS.
To recap, we estimate that compensation for taxes, risk, and sunk costs can account for as much as 400 basis points of the 9.1% average USDIA yield (Table 2), and that age subtracts 150 basis points from the FDIUS yield, which averages 3.5% (Tables 2 and 4). Taken together, these adjustments account for just about all of the 560 basis point difference between USDIA and FDIUS.
Although evidence on the existence of transfer pricing effects is mixed, the results of one paper suggest transfer pricing might add further to the wedge between USDIA and FDIUS yields. Bernard et al. (2006) finds that the prices of U.S. exports to related firms in 2004 were systematically lower than those to unrelated firms, while the prices of U.S. imports from related firms were systematically higher. This mispricing will have a downward effect on the earnings of firms located in the U.S. and an upward effect on the earnings of related firms located abroad. Unfortunately firm nationality is not reported in the customs data used in that study so a direct link to USDIA or FDIUS earnings cannot be made. However, if half the $15.7 billion mispricing identified by the authors is attributed to USDIA and the other half to FDIUS, that would account for 80 basis points of the 480 basis point difference between USDIA and FDIUS yields in 2004.19 So while transfer pricing effects play a role in the DI yield differential, their effect is less than that of taxes or sunk costs.
Looking ahead, we can say a few things about how much of the difference between USDIA and FDIUS we expect to persist. The performance of FDIUS affiliates has caught up to other U.S. firms in recent years, probably because the capital stock has reached a comparable maturity level. So we suspect that FDIUS affiliates will continue to earn about the same yields as USIUS firms, or even outperform because of the tendency of only the most productive firms to engage in FDI. Further, we do not have a reason to expect the yield of USDIA affiliates to decline--absent a change in U.S. tax laws or the perception of the relative risk of investing in the U.S. versus abroad. Taken together, this suggests that the difference between USDIA and FDIUS yields might remain near or slightly below the 2010 difference of 400 basis points. How this yield difference will translate into net income will depend on the relative amount of capital flows into USDIA and FDIUS affiliates and other changes in the values of the positions.
In this paper we showed that compensation for taxes, risk, sunk costs and age account for just about all of the difference between USDIA and FDIUS yields, which is behind the puzzling behavior of the U.S. net income. Unless there is a change in the underlying factors driving the difference--the perception of investment in the U.S. as relatively safe and the relatively high U.S. tax rate--we expect the difference to remain near or slightly below the 400 basis points recorded in 2010. Therefore the U.S. will continue to, on net, earn income on the net liability position, which, in turn, will continue to provide a stabilizing force for the U.S. current account deficit.
Our results provide evidence against misreporting of USDIA earnings (Gros 2006), or that the U.S. is earning abnormally high returns because of the role of the dollar as an international reserve currency (Gourinchas and Rey 2007). In sum, we agree with Bosworth et al. (2008) that the large difference between USDIA and FDIUS yields is not "an illusion of bad data.
This study suggests several areas of future research. One obvious extension is to verify all of our results using the firm-level data available on-site at BEA, as the existence of significant heterogeneity in the underlying firm data might result in different conclusions. Our results have implications for the sustainability of the U.S. current account deficit, so it would be interesting to see how they change the predictions of sustainability models such as those presented in Kitchen (2007) or Gourinchas and Rey (2007). Finally, our results can also inform policy discussions on the potential effect of changes in taxation of MNEs.
Bernard, Andrew B., J. Bradford Jensen and Peter K. Schott, 2006. Transfer Pricing by U.S.-Based Multinational Firms. NBER Working Paper No. 12493.
Borga, Maria and Raymond J. Mataloni, Jr., 2001. Direct Investment Positions for 2000: Country and Industry Detail. Survey of Current Business 81, 16-25.
Bosworth, Barry, Susan M. Collins and Gabriel Chodorow-Reich, 2008. Returns on FDI: Does the U.S. Really Do Better? Brookings Trade Forum 2007: Foreign Direct Investment, Susan M. Collins editor, Brookings Institution Press, Washington, D.C., 177-210
Bridgeman, Benjamin, 2008. Do Intangible Assets Explain High U.S. Foreign Direct Investment Returns? Bureau of Economic Analysis Working Paper 2008-06.
Buiter, Willem, 2006.Dark Matter or Cold Fusion? Global Economics Paper no. 136, London: Goldman Sachs.
Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2006. Foreign Direct Investment in the United States: 2002 Benchmark Survey, Final Results, http://www.bea.gov/international/exe/fdius02bmrkpdf.exe.
Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2008. U.S. Direct Investment Abroad: 2004 Final Benchmark Data, http://www.bea.gov/international/usdia2004f.html.
Cavallo, Michele, and Cedric Tille, 2006. Could Capital Gains Smooth a Current Account Rebalancing?. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports No. 237.
Curcuru, Stephanie E., Tomas Dvorak, and Francis E. Warnock, 2008. Cross-Border Returns Differentials. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, 1495-1530.
Curcuru, Stephanie E., Charles P. Thomas, and Francis E. Warnock, 2009. Current Account Sustainability and Relative Reliability. in J. Frankel and C. Pissarides, ed. NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics 2008. University of Chicago Press, 67-109.
Curcuru, Stephanie E., Charles P. Thomas, and Francis E. Warnock, 2011. Returns Differentials and the Income and Position Puzzles. Working paper.
Desai, Mihir A., C. Fritz Foley, and James R. Hines Jr., 2001. Repatriation Taxes and Dividend Distortions. National Tax Journal 54, no. 4: 829-851.
________, 2003) Chains of Ownership, Regional Tax Competition, and Foreign Direct Investment in Foreign Direct Investment in the Real and Financial Sector of Industrial Countries, edited by Heinz Herrmann and Robert Lindsay, 61-98, Heidelberg: Springer Verlag, 2003.
________, 2004. A Multinational Perspective on Capital Structure Choice and Internal Capital Markets. Journal of Finance 59(6): 2451-2488.
________, 2006. The Demand for Tax Haven Operations. Journal of Public Economics, 90, no. 3: 513-531.
________, 2007. Dividend Policy inside the Multinational Firm. Financial Management, 36(1): 5-26.
Feldstein, Martin, 1994. Taxes, Leverage and the National Return on Outbound Foreign Direct Investment. NBER Working Paper No. 4689.
Fillat, Jose L. and Stefania Garetto, 2010. Risk, Returns and Multinational Production. working paper, Boston University.
Forbes, Kristin, 2010. Why do Foreigners Invest in the United States? Journal of International Economics 80(1): 3-21.
Gohrband, Christopher A.and Kristy L. Howell, 2010. U.S. International Financial Flows and the U.S. Net Investment Position: New Perspectives Arising from New International Standards. Paper presented at NBER-CRIW Conference on Wealth, Financial Intermediation and the Real Economy.
Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, and Helene Rey, 2007. From World Banker to World Venture Capitalist: The U.S. External Adjustment and the Exorbitant Privilege. in R. Clarida, ed. G7 Current Account Imbalances: Sustainability and Adjustment, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 11-55.
Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, Hélène Rey, and Nicolas Govillot, 2010. Exorbitant Privilege and Exorbitant Duty. Bank of Japan IMES Discussion Paper No. 2010-E-20.
Gros, Daniel, 2006. Foreign Investment in the US, II: Being Taken to the Cleaners? CEPS Working Document No. 243, Centre for European Policy Studies, Brussels, April.
Grubert, Harry, 1997. Another Look at the Low Taxable Income of Foreign-Controlled Companies in the United States. U.S. Treasury Department, Office of Tax Analysis Paper 74.
Grubert, Harry, 1998. Taxes and the division of foreign operating income among royalties, interest, dividends and retained earnings. Journal of Public Economics 68(2): 269-290.
Grubert, Harry, Timothy Goodspeed, and Deborah Swenson, 1993) Explaining the Low Taxable Income of Foreign-Controlled Companies in the United States. Studies in International Taxation, edited by Alberto Giovannini, Glenn Hubbard, and Joel Slemrod, 237-275. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Habib, Maurizio M., 2010. Excess returns on net foreign assets - the exorbitant privilege from a global perspective. European Central Bank Working Paper Series 1158.
Hausmann, Ricardo and Federico Sturzenegger, 2006. Global Imbalances or Bad Accounting? The Missing Dark Matter in the Wealth of Nations. Harvard University, Center for International Development Working Paper 124.
Helpman, Elhanan, Marc J. Melitz, and Stephen R. Yeaple, 2004. Exports Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms. The American Economic Review 94(1): 300-316.
Hines Jr., James R., 1996. Dividends and Profits: Some Unsubtle Foreign Influences. Journal of Finance 51(2): 661-89.
________, 1999. Lessons from Behavioral Responses to International Taxation. National Tax Journal 52(2): 305-322.
Hines Jr., James R. and R. Glenn Hubbard, 1990.Coming Home To America: Dividend Repatriations By U.S. Multinationals. in Taxation in the Global Economy A. Razin and J. Slemrod, eds. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 161-200.
Howenstine, Ned G. and Ann M. Lawson, 1991. Alternative Measures of the Rate of Return on Direct Investment. Survey of Current Business 71(8): 44-45.
Hung, Juann H., and Angelo Mascaro,, 2004) Return on Cross-Border Investment: Why Does U.S. Investment Abroad Do Better? Technical Paper no. 2004-17, Washington, D.C. Congressional Budget Office, December).
Ibarra-Caton, Marilyn, 2010. Direct Investment Positions for 2009: Country and Industry Detail. Survey of Current Business 90(7):20-35.
Jorion, Philippe, 1996. Returns to Japanese investors from US investments. Japan and the World Economy 8, 229-241.
Kitchen, John, 2007. Sharecroppers or Shrewd Capitalists? Projections of the US Current Account, International Income Flows, and Net International Debt. Review of International Economics 15(5): 1036-1061.
KPMG, 2010. KPMG's Corporate and Indirect Tax Rate Survey 2010. http://www.kpmg.com/Global/en/IssuesAndInsights/ArticlesPublications/Documents/Corp-and-Indirect-Tax-Oct12-2010.pdf.
Landefeld, J. Steven, Ann M. Lawson, and Douglas B. Weinberg, 1992. Rates of Return on Direct Investement. Survey of Current Business 72, 79-86.
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2005. A Global Perspective on External Positions. NBER Working Paper No. 11589.
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 2009. Where Did All the Borrowing Go? A Forensic Analysis of the U.S. External Position. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 23(2):177-199.
Laster, David S. and Robert N. McCauley, 1994. Making sense of the Profits of Foreign Firms in the United States. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review, Summer-Fall. 44-75.
Lupo, L.A., Arnold Gilbert, and Michael Liliestedt, 1978. The Relationship Between Age and Rate of Return of Foreign Manufacturing Affiliates of U.S. Manufacturing Parent Companies. Survey of Current Business 58, August, 60-66.
Mataloni Jr., Raymond, 2000. An Examination of the Low Rates of Return of Foreign-Owned U.S. Companies. Survey of Current Business 80, March, 55-73.
McGrattan, Ellen R. and Edward C. Prescott, 2010. Technology Capital and the US Current Account. American Economic Review 100: 1493-1522.
Meissner, Christopher M., and Alan M. Taylor, 2006. Losing Our Marbles in the New Century? The Great Rebalancing in Historical Perspective. NBER Working Paper No. 12580.
Newey, W. K., and K. D. West, 1987. A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55, 703-708.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2005. Global Current Account Imbalances and Exchange Rate Adjustments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 67-123.
Sharpe, William F., 1966. Mutual Fund Performance. Journal of Business 39, 119-138.
Table 1: U.S. Direct Investment Abroad (USDIA) and All Countries Direct Investment Abroad (ACDIA) Yields for Selected Countries
All values are average percentages over the sample period; share is of 2010 USDIA position. Sample includes countries which fully apply the current operating performance concept (COPC) to direct investment income reporting. The USDIA yield in each country is computed using BEA income and position data. BEA country-level positions are only available at historical-cost; we use the ratio of the aggregate position at current cost to the aggregate position at historical cost for each year to adjust the position to a current-cost basis. ACDIA is the ratio of DI income payments reported in the IMF Balance of Payments for each country to the DI liabilities position for that country. The last line of the table presents yields weighted by the historical cost share of USDIA investment in each country each year. ** and * indicate statistical significance at the 5% and 10% levels, respectively.
Country | USDIA | ACDIA | Difference | Share of Position | Data Available |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
United Kingdom | 6.7 | 8.5 | -1.9** | 13.0 | 1983-2010 |
Canada | 7.5 | 7.6 | -0.1 | 7.6 | 1983-2010 |
Ireland | 17.6 | 21.6 | -4.0** | 4.9 | 2002-2010 |
Australia | 7.7 | 7.5 | 0.2 | 3.4 | 1987-2010 |
Hong Kong | 12.4 | 8.8 | 3.7** | 1.4 | 1998-2010 |
Sweden | 6.4 | 8.3 | -1.9 | 0.8 | 1983-2010 |
New Zealand | 6.3 | 8.4 | -2.1** | 0.2 | 1990-2010 |
Finland | 13.6 | 10.7 | 2.9** | 0.1 | 1983-2010 |
Weighted Average Yields for 8 Countries: | 7.5 | 8.5 | -1.1* | 31.3 |
Table 2: Summary Statistics for Yields, 1983-2010
Details of how the yield series were constructed are in Table A2. Direct investment income does not include current-cost adjustments and positions are valued at current-cost. The Sharpe ratio is the ratio of average excess returns to Standard deviation. The last column is chi-squared test statistic for the null hypothesis that the Sharpe ratio is equal to the USIUS Sharpe ratio indicated by the column heading; probability that the null is rejected is shown. Asymptotic p-values computed from Newey and West (1987) standard errors are in brackets. ** and * indicate test for equal Sharp ratios rejected at 5% level and 10% levels, respectively.
Mean | Standard Deviation | Sharpe Ratio | Chi-squared test: Equal Sharpe Ratios: USIUS_max | Chi-squared test: Equal Sharpe Ratios: USIUS_min | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
USDIA, before U.S. taxes | 9.1% | 1.2% | 3.3 | 26.9** [0.00] | 34.2** [0.00] |
USDIA, after U.S. taxes on repatriated earnings | 8.3% | 1.2% | 2.8 | 31.5** [0.00] | 34.0** [0.00] |
USDIA, after U.S. taxes on all earnings | 7.3% | 1.1% | 2.7 | 22.4** [0.00] | 24.0** [0.00] |
USDIA, after U.S. taxes on all earnings and risk | 6.4% | 1.3% | 1.9 | 5.6** [0.02] | 13.3** [0.00] |
USIUS_max | 5.8% | 1.1% | 1.4 | --- | --- |
USIUS_min | 4.7% | 1.3% | 0.8 | --- | --- |
FDIUS | 3.5% | 1.9% | 0.2 | 19.0** [0.00] | 9.3** [0.00] |
Table 3: Sovereign CDS Spreads
Each values is the average difference between the CDS spreads on 5-year sovereign debt and the CDS spread on 5-year U.S. Treasuries in basis points from 2004-2010. CDS spreads are from Markit. Share is of 1999 USDIA position calculated from BEA data.
Country | Average Sovereign CDS Spread over U.S. | Share of USDIA Position |
---|---|---|
United Kingdom | 12.1 | 17.8 |
Netherlands | 2.8 | 10.0 |
Canada | 5.3 | 9.8 |
Japan | 9.2 | 4.5 |
Germany | -0.7 | 4.4 |
France | 4.7 | 3.5 |
Brazil | 216.5 | 3.1 |
Mexico | 104.2 | 3.1 |
Australia | 7.8 | 2.9 |
Panama | 162.6 | 2.8 |
Ireland | 65.1 | 2.1 |
Hong Kong | 17.7 | 1.9 |
Belgium | 15.9 | 1.8 |
Singapore | 4.7 | 1.7 |
Spain | 35.9 | 1.6 |
Other | 288.4 | 13.4 |
Total: | 84.4 |
Weighted Avg. of 49 Countries: 70.4
Table 4: FDIUS Age Regressions
This table shows coefficient estimates from the regression:
where:
The USIUS variable is either USIUS_max or USIUS_min from Table A2. AGEVAR is either new outlays (http://www.bea.gov/international/xls/io_ind_0508.xls), gross debt flows (BOP Table 7a line 96 or 7b line 61), equity flows (BOP Table 7a line 92 or 7b line 57), or the difference between the annual growth rate of the FDIUS and USIUS_min positions (Table A2). RelAge is not scaled by the FDIUS position when AGEt is constructed. Newey West (1987) standard errors are in parentheses.
Estimation period is 1983-2009 for regressions that include the outlay variable; 1983-2010 for all other regressions. ** and * indicate significance at 5% and 10% levels, respectively.
USIUS | AGEVAR | T | Adj. R2 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
USIUS_min | Outlay | 1.0 | 3 | 2.61** (0.88) | -6.47** (2.76) | 0.52** (0.18) | 0.41 |
USIUS_min | Debt | 1.0 | 3 | 4.69** (1.23) | -30.73** (7.13) | 0.27 (0.21) | 0.54 |
USIUS_min | Equity | 1.0 | 3 | 2.33** (1.15) | -8.71* (4.83) | 0.64** (0.19) | 0.43 |
USIUS_max | Debt | 1.0 | 3 | 1.18 (1.75) | -23.37** (6.08) | 0.72** (0.22) | 0.62 |
USIUS_min | Debt | 1.0 | 5 | 7.27** (1.37) | -34.84** (6.14) | 0.09 (0.16) | 0.74 |
USIUS_min | Debt | 0.7 | 5 | 5.75** (1.55) | -44.98** (11.57) | 0.20 (0.21) | 0.61 |
USIUS_min | RelAge | 1.0 | 3 | 2.07** (0.98) | -5.73** (2.48) | 0.52** (0.19) | 0.44 |
Figure 1: U.S. Cross-Border Investment Income and Position
Net investment income is from the U.S. balance of payments and the net investment position from the U.S. international investment position, both published by BEA.
Data for Figure 1
Year | Net Investment Income | Net Investment Position |
---|---|---|
1990 | 28.55 | -230.375 |
1991 | 24.13 | -291.754 |
1992 | 24.234 | -411.021 |
1993 | 25.316 | -284.46 |
1994 | 17.146 | -298.458 |
1995 | 20.891 | -430.194 |
1996 | 22.318 | -463.338 |
1997 | 12.609 | -786.174 |
1998 | 4.265 | -858.363 |
1999 | 11.931 | -731.068 |
2000 | 19.178 | -1337.01 |
2001 | 29.728 | -1875.03 |
2002 | 25.175 | -2044.63 |
2003 | 43.691 | -2093.79 |
2004 | 65.081 | -2253.03 |
2005 | 68.591 | -1932.15 |
2006 | 44.182 | -2191.65 |
2007 | 101.485 | -1796.01 |
2008 | 147.089 | -3260.16 |
2009 | 128.001 | -2396.43 |
2010 | 165.224 | -2470.99 |
Figure 2: Income Yields and Capital Gains on U.S. Cross-Border Positions
Income and capital gains are from Gohrband and Howell (2010) for 1990-2009 and from the U.S. balance of payments and international investment position published by BEA for 2010. Yields are computed by scaling income and capital gains with positions. Direct investment positions valued at current-cost.
Data for Figure 2
Total U.S. Claims | Total U.S. Liabilities | Direct Investment U.S. Claims | Direct Investment U.S. Liabilities | Portfolio Equity U.S. Claims | Portfolio Equity U.S. Liabilities | Debt and Other Assets U.S. Claims | Debt and Other Assets U.S. Liabilities | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Income | 0.054649 | 0.040219 | 0.102 | 0.040105 | 0.02552 | 0.021289 | 0.044302 | 0.045932 |
Capital Gains | 0.018114 | 0.01189 | 0.003963 | 0.005053 | 0.056029 | 0.064405 | 0.004622 | 0.001461 |
Figure 3: U.S. Direct Investment Abroad (USDIA) and All Countries Direct Investment Abroad (ACDIA) Yields
The USIDA and ACDIA series are those shown in the last line of Table 1; see notes to Table 1 for a description.
Data for Figure 3
Year | USDIA | ACDIA |
---|---|---|
1983 | 0.072591 | 0.109241 |
1984 | 0.08816 | 0.124111 |
1985 | 0.079768 | 0.127909 |
1986 | 0.071738 | 0.09416 |
1987 | 0.07994 | 0.111015 |
1988 | 0.098878 | 0.111977 |
1989 | 0.081388 | 0.093202 |
1990 | 0.068636 | 0.060302 |
1991 | 0.041209 | 0.03027 |
1992 | 0.041776 | 0.034506 |
1993 | 0.064897 | 0.069968 |
1994 | 0.065826 | 0.073583 |
1995 | 0.088315 | 0.096294 |
1996 | 0.083583 | 0.094641 |
1997 | 0.086024 | 0.093096 |
1998 | 0.062005 | 0.060609 |
1999 | 0.077094 | 0.079157 |
2000 | 0.089818 | 0.089573 |
2001 | 0.053378 | 0.065149 |
2002 | 0.058732 | 0.067003 |
2003 | 0.067882 | 0.075521 |
2004 | 0.081386 | 0.085517 |
2005 | 0.083567 | 0.098543 |
2006 | 0.087388 | 0.108462 |
2007 | 0.076106 | 0.107591 |
2008 | 0.088329 | 0.073135 |
2009 | 0.068101 | 0.077357 |
2010 | 0.079807 | 0.081845 |
Figure 4: Yields on U.S. Direct Investment Abroad (USDIA), Foreign Direct Investment in the United States (FDIUS), and U.S. Investment in the United States (USIUS)
The USDIA series is the ratio of aggregate DI income receipts to the USDIA position reported by BEA. The FDIUS series is the ratio of aggregate DI income payments to the FDIUS position reported by BEA. The USIUS_max yield is the return (excluding interest payments) on tangible U.S. non-financial corporate assets excluding USDIA and FDIUS with tangible assets valued at replacement cost. The USIUS_min yield is the return on all U.S. non-financial corporate assets excluding USDIA and FDIUS with assets valued at replacement cost. The data series used to construct these yields are listed in Appendix Table A2. Direct investment income does not include current-cost adjustments and positions are valued at current-cost.
Data for Figure 4
Year | USDIA | USIUS_MAX | USIUS_MIN | FDIUS |
---|---|---|---|---|
1983 | 0.074715 | 0.047783 | 0.037267 | 0.027309 |
1984 | 0.087348 | 0.053172 | 0.041032 | 0.045235 |
1985 | 0.080008 | 0.047077 | 0.033431 | 0.032067 |
1986 | 0.080018 | 0.040536 | 0.022869 | 0.027948 |
1987 | 0.090676 | 0.048708 | 0.036622 | 0.027966 |
1988 | 0.104974 | 0.057422 | 0.046463 | 0.034697 |
1989 | 0.101099 | 0.055897 | 0.040685 | 0.017228 |
1990 | 0.099173 | 0.055465 | 0.041502 | 0.006034 |
1991 | 0.082677 | 0.051835 | 0.040269 | -0.0055 |
1992 | 0.077364 | 0.050921 | 0.045127 | 0.00261 |
1993 | 0.085603 | 0.05296 | 0.051171 | 0.012475 |
1994 | 0.091369 | 0.05998 | 0.05921 | 0.034475 |
1995 | 0.104478 | 0.063929 | 0.060149 | 0.047658 |
1996 | 0.099818 | 0.064933 | 0.061548 | 0.042656 |
1997 | 0.101847 | 0.067583 | 0.060771 | 0.050892 |
1998 | 0.080099 | 0.061147 | 0.0502 | 0.037156 |
1999 | 0.08761 | 0.059851 | 0.044262 | 0.045885 |
2000 | 0.091823 | 0.055428 | 0.03489 | 0.039357 |
2001 | 0.068959 | 0.046499 | 0.029745 | 0.003554 |
2002 | 0.070826 | 0.045642 | 0.030882 | 0.022084 |
2003 | 0.084767 | 0.047871 | 0.033154 | 0.040992 |
2004 | 0.10072 | 0.062811 | 0.049819 | 0.053924 |
2005 | 0.106276 | 0.079397 | 0.065743 | 0.062196 |
2006 | 0.108614 | 0.085815 | 0.070744 | 0.071307 |
2007 | 0.107744 | 0.081096 | 0.063643 | 0.05376 |
2008 | 0.107635 | 0.067566 | 0.052117 | 0.05301 |
2009 | 0.085794 | 0.059288 | 0.047094 | 0.036509 |
2010 | 0.096401 | 0.065205 | 0.05953 | 0.056222 |
Figure 5: Tax-Adjusted USDIA Yields
The USDIA series is the ratio of aggregate DI income receipts to the USDIA position reported by BEA. The top boundary of the range of after-tax USDIA yields subtracts from income estimated U.S. taxes on repatriated income (reported in the second line of Table 2), the bottom boundary subtracts from income U.S. taxes on all income (reported in the third line of Table 2). Direct investment income does not include current-cost adjustments and positions are valued at current-cost. USIUS yields are from Figure 4.
Data for Figure 5
Year | USDIA | USDIA AFter Repatriated Taxes | USDIA After All Taxes | USIUS_MAX | USIUS_MIN |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1983 | 0.074715 | 0.06513 | 0.055806 | 0.047783 | 0.037267 |
1984 | 0.087348 | 0.077293 | 0.067048 | 0.053172 | 0.041032 |
1985 | 0.080008 | 0.069059 | 0.060756 | 0.047077 | 0.033431 |
1986 | 0.080018 | 0.072978 | 0.068112 | 0.040536 | 0.022869 |
1987 | 0.090676 | 0.083805 | 0.078085 | 0.048708 | 0.036622 |
1988 | 0.104974 | 0.09422 | 0.091447 | 0.057422 | 0.046463 |
1989 | 0.101099 | 0.089288 | 0.087422 | 0.055897 | 0.040685 |
1990 | 0.099173 | 0.091353 | 0.085218 | 0.055465 | 0.041502 |
1991 | 0.082677 | 0.075274 | 0.070797 | 0.051835 | 0.040269 |
1992 | 0.077364 | 0.070893 | 0.065509 | 0.050921 | 0.045127 |
1993 | 0.085603 | 0.079673 | 0.071714 | 0.05296 | 0.051171 |
1994 | 0.091369 | 0.082227 | 0.075426 | 0.05998 | 0.05921 |
1995 | 0.104478 | 0.097372 | 0.087483 | 0.063929 | 0.060149 |
1996 | 0.099818 | 0.092456 | 0.083169 | 0.064933 | 0.061548 |
1997 | 0.101847 | 0.093113 | 0.083904 | 0.067583 | 0.060771 |
1998 | 0.080099 | 0.071119 | 0.064414 | 0.061147 | 0.0502 |
1999 | 0.08761 | 0.079283 | 0.069757 | 0.059851 | 0.044262 |
2000 | 0.091823 | 0.083617 | 0.072626 | 0.055428 | 0.03489 |
2001 | 0.068959 | 0.060576 | 0.052795 | 0.046499 | 0.029745 |
2002 | 0.070826 | 0.063263 | 0.053737 | 0.045642 | 0.030882 |
2003 | 0.084767 | 0.07845 | 0.068592 | 0.047871 | 0.033154 |
2004 | 0.10072 | 0.092899 | 0.080283 | 0.062811 | 0.049819 |
2005 | 0.106276 | 0.0994 | 0.088565 | 0.079397 | 0.065743 |
2006 | 0.108614 | 0.099189 | 0.080321 | 0.085815 | 0.070744 |
2007 | 0.107744 | 0.096589 | 0.078451 | 0.081096 | 0.063643 |
2008 | 0.107635 | 0.095121 | 0.077886 | 0.067566 | 0.052117 |
2009 | 0.085794 | 0.077834 | 0.060928 | 0.059288 | 0.047094 |
2010 | 0.096401 | 0.089673 | 0.068345 | 0.065205 | 0.05953 |
Figure 6: Age of FDIUS Affiliates
The chart shows several alternative proxies for the age of FDIUS given by:
for w = 1.0, T=3; AGEVAR is new outlays (http://www.bea.gov/international/xls/io_ind_0508.xls), gross debt flows (BOP Table 7a line 96 or 7b line 61), equity flows (BOP Table 7a line 92 or 7b line 57), or relative age (the difference between the annual growth rate of the FDIUS and USIUS_min positions; see Table A2 for definitions). RelAge is not scaled by the FDIUS position when AGEt is constructed.
Data for Figure 6
Year | Equity | Debt | RelAge | New Outlays |
---|---|---|---|---|
1983 | 0.173173 | 0.084731 | 0.528672 | 0.238545 |
1984 | 0.148597 | 0.082474 | 0.240567 | 0.188456 |
1985 | 0.135368 | 0.081493 | 0.150033 | 0.137952 |
1986 | 0.136838 | 0.080161 | 0.167541 | 0.162957 |
1987 | 0.16543 | 0.092697 | 0.296164 | 0.231593 |
1988 | 0.18573 | 0.132714 | 0.352422 | 0.255355 |
1989 | 0.22324 | 0.132844 | 0.39494 | 0.325248 |
1990 | 0.259507 | 0.148138 | 0.395073 | 0.364433 |
1991 | 0.286951 | 0.120734 | 0.308061 | 0.393299 |
1992 | 0.284721 | 0.096455 | 0.210934 | 0.301022 |
1993 | 0.22532 | 0.062438 | 0.087818 | 0.180011 |
1994 | 0.173338 | 0.065199 | 0.057371 | 0.108579 |
1995 | 0.144868 | 0.057197 | -0.00535 | 0.128205 |
1996 | 0.153933 | 0.040922 | 0.008329 | 0.173078 |
1997 | 0.180595 | 0.033818 | 0.012701 | 0.221747 |
1998 | 0.185994 | 0.065718 | 0.068586 | 0.224807 |
1999 | 0.245368 | 0.092368 | 0.090873 | 0.331206 |
2000 | 0.3013 | 0.103529 | 0.171031 | 0.394028 |
2001 | 0.413767 | 0.127903 | 0.290273 | 0.543863 |
2002 | 0.414749 | 0.135273 | 0.306938 | 0.505145 |
2003 | 0.319979 | 0.079671 | 0.175801 | 0.339822 |
2004 | 0.194905 | 0.012153 | 0.034346 | 0.152187 |
2005 | 0.153028 | -0.00154 | -0.01163 | 0.107204 |
2006 | 0.119333 | 0.010394 | 0.002167 | 0.111974 |
2007 | 0.118784 | 0.051337 | 0.049615 | 0.144567 |
2008 | 0.136817 | 0.084072 | 0.107983 | 0.210578 |
2009 | 0.210101 | 0.091154 | 0.201243 | 0.27596 |
2010 | 0.200189 | 0.059621 | 0.148785 |
Figure 7: U.S. Domestic Yields (USIUS) and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States (FDIUS) Adjusted for Age-Effects
The dashed line is the FDIUS yield predicted by the regression in the first line of Table 4, with the contribution of age removed. USIUS_min yield is the return on all U.S. non-financial corporate assets excluding USDIA and FDIUS with assets valued at replacement cost.
Data for Figure 7
Year | USIUS_MIN | Adjusted FDIUS |
---|---|---|
1983 | 0.037267 | 0.045479 |
1984 | 0.041032 | 0.047437 |
1985 | 0.033431 | 0.043484 |
1986 | 0.022869 | 0.037992 |
1987 | 0.036622 | 0.045143 |
1988 | 0.046463 | 0.050261 |
1989 | 0.040685 | 0.047256 |
1990 | 0.041502 | 0.047681 |
1991 | 0.040269 | 0.04704 |
1992 | 0.045127 | 0.049566 |
1993 | 0.051171 | 0.052709 |
1994 | 0.05921 | 0.056889 |
1995 | 0.060149 | 0.057378 |
1996 | 0.061548 | 0.058105 |
1997 | 0.060771 | 0.057701 |
1998 | 0.0502 | 0.052204 |
1999 | 0.044262 | 0.049116 |
2000 | 0.03489 | 0.044243 |
2001 | 0.029745 | 0.041567 |
2002 | 0.030882 | 0.042159 |
2003 | 0.033154 | 0.04334 |
2004 | 0.049819 | 0.052006 |
2005 | 0.065743 | 0.060287 |
2006 | 0.070744 | 0.062887 |
2007 | 0.063643 | 0.059194 |
2008 | 0.052117 | 0.053201 |
2009 | 0.047094 | 0.050589 |
In Table A1 we extend our comparison of USDIA and ACDIA yields to include countries that do not fully apply the COPC to earnings. These countries either include capital gains and losses in direct investment income, which could either overstate or understate the ACDIA yield, or exclude some reinvested earnings or interest on intercompany debt, which would tend to understate the ACDIA yield. The USDIA yield for these countries averages 8.3% per year, lower than the 9.1% per year reported in Table 2. This is because yields in countries for which IMF BOP data are not available, such as Bermuda or the Cayman Islands, have a higher yield than the reported countries.
For this less comparable sample the USDIA yield averages only 0.3 higher per year than the ACDIA yield and is not statistically significant. Therefore our conclusion remains unchanged --U.S. investors earn about the same yields on their USDIA as investors from other countries earn on their FDI.
Table A1a: U.S. Direct Investment Abroad (USDIA) and All Countries Direct Investment Abroad (ACDIA) Yields for Selected Countries: Panel A: ACDIA Income Includes Capital Gains and Losses
Country | USDIA | ACDIA | Difference | Share of Position | Data Available |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Austria | 11.7 | 8.4 | 3.3** | 0.4 | 1983-2010 |
Belgium | 5.3 | 4.5 | 0.8 | 1.9 | 2002-2010 |
Chile | 11.6 | 12.4 | -0.8 | 0.7 | 1998-2010 |
Norway | 26.0 | 12.7 | 13.3** | 0.9 | 1999-2009 |
Russia | 12.6 | 10.8 | 1.8 | 0.3 | 2000-2010 |
Switzerland | 11.2 | 5.8 | 5.4** | 3.7 | 1984-2010 |
Weighted Average Yields for 20 Countries in Tables 1 and Panels A and B Above: | 8.3 | 7.9 | 0.3 | 64.1 |
Table A1b: U.S. Direct Investment Abroad (USDIA) and All Countries Direct Investment Abroad (ACDIA) Yields for Selected Countries: Panel B: ACDIA is Missing Intercompany Debt Payments and/or Reinvested Earnings
Country | USDIA | ACDIA | Difference | Share of Position | Data Available |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
France | 5.7 | 5.0 | 0.8 | 2.4 | 2000-2009 |
Germany | 7.3 | 7.1 | 0.1 | 2.7 | 1983-2010 |
Japan | 8.1 | 9.2 | -1.1 | 2.9 | 1991-2010 |
Mexico | 9.3 | 3.6 | 5.7** | 2.3 | 2002-2010 |
Netherlands | 12.0 | 8.0 | 4.0** | 13.3 | 1983-2010 |
Spain | 9.7 | 5.2 | 4.5** | 1.5 | 1983-2010 |
Weighted Average Yields for 20 Countries in Tables 1 and Panels A and B Above: | 8.3 | 7.9 | 0.3 | 64.1 |
All values are average percentages over the sample period; share is of 2010 USDIA position. Sample includes countries which do not fully apply the current operating performance concept to direct investment income reporting. See notes to Table 1 for a description of the USDIA yields. The ACDIA yield is the ratio of total direct investment income payments reported by the IMF's BOP statistics to the liabilities position with two exceptions: DeNederlandsche Bank data that includes special financial institutions are used for the Netherlands starting in 2000, and returns for France are from Banque de France report (http://www.banque-france.fr/gb/stat_conjoncture/telechar/bdp/FDI-overview-1999-2009.pdf). The last line of the table presents returns weighted by the historical cost share of USDIA investment in each country each year. ** and * indicate statistical significance at the 5% and 10% levels, respectively.
Table A2: Yield Definitions
Variable Name | Description | Source | |
---|---|---|---|
1 | USDIA | Yield on U.S. Direct Investment Abroad | [BOP Table 7a, 7b line 10] / [IIP Table line 18] |
2 | FDIUS | Yield on Foreign Direct Investment in the U.S. | - [BOP Table 7a line 75 or 7b line 51] / [IIP Table line 35] |
3 | USIUS_max | Yield on Tangible Assets | [NIPA 1.14 line 38 + NIPA 1.14 line 25 - (FOF F.7 line 14 - FOF F.7 line 19)] / [FOF B.102 line 2 - FOF B.102 line 3 + FOF B.102 line 33 + FOF B.102 line 34] |
4 | USIUS_min | Yield on Net Assets | [NIPA 1.14 line 38 + (BOP Table 7a line 80 - BOP Table 7a line 83) - FOF F.7 line 14 - FOF F.7 line 19)] / [FOF B.102 line 32 - FOF B.102 line 3 + FOF B.102 line 33 + FOF B.102 line 34 - FOF L.102 line 17 ] |
FOF: Flow of funds
BOP: Balance of Payments
NIPA: National Income and Product Accounts
1. Personal correspondence with Charles Thomas, June 1987. Return to text
2. Although there is a difference between the asset compositions of DI claims and liabilities, it contributes very little to the yield differential. Return to text
3. Investments in intangible capital are generally excluded from the U.S. national accounts because of difficulties in measuring its production and depreciation. BEA plans to start including some intangible assets related to research and development in the accounts in 2013. Return to text
4. In related work Hausmann and Sturznegger (2006) infers from the large net income receipts that USDIA intangible investment is much larger than FDIUS intangible investment, although Buiter (2006) challenges their methodology. Return to text
5. See http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fdis/2003/fdistat.pdf for a description of the COPC and the survey results. Return to text
6. In 2009 reinvested earnings in USDIA holding company affiliates totaled $110 billion or one-third of total earnings. Most of this income was generated by indirectly held affiliates. Excluding these reinvested earnings lowers aggregate USDIA earnings in 2009 from 9.7% to 6.4%. Return to text
7. We also estimated the yield earned by only non-U.S. investors in each country by subtracting the USDIA earnings and position in each country from IMF DI liabilities. The resulting yields for the 8 countries in the main sample were similar to those reported, but these estimates could not be constructed for the expanded sample for several countries because inconsistent reporting resulted in U.S. income receipts or positions reported by BEA which were larger than total DI payments or liabilities reported by that country. Return to text
8. Current-cost adjustments increase USDIA earnings and lower FDIUS earnings and the differential between USDIA and FDIUS yields widens to 650 basis points. Return to text
9. The aggregate USDIA yield falls to 6.6%, and the aggregate differential drops to 125 basis points per year when yields are computed using the market value estimate of the position. We use aggregate income and positions to compute yields, which may mask significant heterogeneity in the underlying data. Unfortunately, those data are maintained by BEA and access to them by individuals from other government agencies, including the authors of this paper, is prohibited. Return to text
10. The yield on all DI liabilities in Ireland calculated from IMF data slightly overstates the yield on those liabilities because recorded DI income payments are not net of interest income associated with lending from Irish affiliates to foreign parents. Return to text
11. BEA (2006) Table III.C.1 reports that current liabilities and long-term debt owed by majority-owned nonbank FDIUS affiliates totaled $2.7 trillion in 2002, of which $719 billion (or 27%) was owed to the foreign parent. In contrast, BEA (2008) Table III.C.1 reports that current liabilities and long-term debt owed by majority-owned nonbank USDIA affiliates totaled $4.2 trillion in 2004, of which $523 billion (or 12%) was owed to the U.S. parent. Return to text
12. The United States has a "worldwide taxation" policy which taxes income generated by U.S. MNEs regardless of where it is earned. In contrast, most other countries have a policy of "territorial taxation" and only tax income generated by domestic activities. See the section "International Taxation for Beginners" in Hines (1999) for an overview of tax issues. Return to text
13. Foreign tax rates are inferred from 2004 benchmark survey (BEA 2008) and earlier surveys. An increasing number of multinational corporations include holding companies as intermediate firms between the parent company and foreign subsidiaries because several jurisdictions offer attractive tax treatment (DFH 2003, chart A in Ibarra-Caton 2010). See Figure 1 in DFH (2003) for common ownership structures used by firms located in tax havens. The aggregate foreign tax rate is a relatively low 14% because of the large share of intermediate holding companies that almost entirely avoid foreign taxes. In practice, the foreign tax credit may be smaller than our estimate because credits against U.S. taxes are given for only certain types of tax payments (DFH 2004). Return to text
14. For example, Hines and Hubbard (1990) find that many firms repatriate earnings during the same period in which they inject equity, and that some firms with excess tax credits reinvest earnings. Similarly, DFH (2007) finds that the amount firms repatriate depends on domestic funds available to meet dividend payments to external shareholders and domestic investment needs. Return to text
15. U.S. MNEs reinvest a substantial fraction of USDIA earnings--60% on average from 1999-2009--most of which is reinvested by holding company affiliates (Ibarra-Caton 2010). While 60% is the average, Hines and Hubbard (1990) find significant heterogeneity between firms. The 60% average excludes reinvested earnings in 2005 because reinvested earnings were large and negative in that year because firms took advantage of temporary reduction in the U.S. tax liability on repatriated earnings contained in the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004. Return to text
16. Hung and Mascaro (2004) report a similar result using the USDIA (pre-tax) and FDIUS yields. Return to text
17. The weighted spread is about 45 basis points using weights 2003 or 2009 weights. Return to text
18. Hung and Mascaro (2004) estimated that 11% of USIDA was invested in AAA-rated Canada, 17% in BB-rated Latin American countries, 50% in AA-rated European countries, and the weighted-average rating estimate for all countries was BBB, using Standard & Poor's ratings and the 2003 positions. We follow Hung and Mascaro and use the difference between AAA and BBB corporate debt yields as an estimate of the additional risk of USDIA. Return to text
19. Bernard et al. (2006) estimate that U.S. exports to related parties in 2004 were under-reported by $1.9 billion, while U.S. imports to related parties were over-reported by $13.8 billion, for a total of $15.7 billion. Return to text
This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text