Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
International Finance Discussion Papers
Number 1097, December 2013 --- Screen Reader
Version*
NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.
Abstract:
This paper documents highly persistent effects of financial crises on output, labor productivity and employment in a sample of emerging economies. To address these facts, it introduces a quantitative macroeconomic model that includes endogenous TFP growth through firm creation. Firm creators obtain funding from a financial intermediation sector which is subject to frictions. These frictions become especially severe in a financial crisis, increasing the cost of credit for firm creators and thereby lowering the growth rate of aggregate TFP. As a consequence, the model produces medium-run dynamics following crises that are in line with the data.
Keywords: Business cycles, financial crises, total factor productivity
JEL classification: E32, E44, F41, O33
A stylized fact of financial crises, consistent with the recent experience in the advanced economies, is that their aftermath tends to be characterized by a slow recovery. Numerous researchers have documented highly persistent output losses following financial crises using a variety of different approaches.3
In this paper, I first complement the existing evidence by documenting persistent effects of financial crises in a sample of emerging market economies, using a methodology similar to Cerra and Saxena (2008). I also decompose the effects on output into movements in labor productivity and employment. The analysis reveals that losses in output, labor productivity and employment during the crisis are not reversed. Moreover, I find that a substantial portion of the medium-run output decline is due to a fall in labor productivity: of the 11 percent medium-run output loss, labor productivity accounts for over 6 percent of it, with the remaining loss explained by decreases in employment.
The main goal of this paper is then to develop a quantitative model to address the empirical results on the effects of financial crises. Guided by the evidence, I introduce two key modifications to a relatively standard neoclassical economy, the backbone of modern quantitative macroeconomic frameworks. First, I explicitly model the process of firm creation as a source of endogenous medium-run productivity growth. Second, I introduce financial intermediaries (banks, for short) that obtain funds from savers and channel them to entrepreneurs, who are the agents with the ability to create new firms. Because of an agency problem between banks and their creditors, there may be frictions in the process of transferring funds from savers to entrepreneurs. These frictions become especially severe in a financial crisis.4
The model features sustained TFP growth that arises due to an endogenously expanding variety of intermediates, as in Romer (1990). There is an unbounded mass of entrepreneurs in the model economy, each with an "idea" for a new firm or variety but lacking the funds to finance the startup costs of their project. To obtain the necessary funds, entrepreneurs borrow from banks. Once an entrepreneur pays the initial entry cost, his project follows a simple life-cycle pattern whereby it can either fail or successfully become a new variety according to an exogenously given probability.
To provide funding to entrepreneurs, banks borrow from both domestic households and international creditors. I assume that banks are efficient at monitoring entrepreneurial projects, so that the relationship between banks and entrepreneurs is frictionless: entrepreneurs can offer the bank perfectly state-contingent equity in exchange for funds. On the other hand, the bank faces frictions in the process of obtaining funds from creditors. As in Gertler and Karadi (2011) and others,5 I model these frictions through a simple limited enforcement problem: after borrowing funds, the bank can renege on its debt and divert a certain fraction of resources for its own personal gain, at which point creditors can force it into bankruptcy. The limited enforcement friction effectively introduces an endogenous constraint on the bank's lending that may tighten as economic conditions worsen.
An important determinant of the degree of financial constraints is the state of banks' balance sheets, summarized by their net worth. The primary source of fluctuations in banks' net worth is the movement in the prices of the assets on their balance sheets. These assets consist of claims on fully successful firms (interpretable as mature or old firms) as well as projects that have not yet successfully turned into a new variety (interpretable as young startups or products in development). In the model, the presence of the latter type of assets introduces a source of adverse feedback between the price of the equity issued by entrepreneurs and banks' net worth, which acts as an important amplification mechanism. In particular, a decline in bank net worth forces banks to cut back on project funding. This lowers the price at which new entrepreneurs can sell equity, and at the same time lowers the franchise value of projects that have already been created but have not yet been successful.6 Since the asset side of banks' balance sheets includes the latter, a decline in their price leads to further drops in banks' net worth.
I embed these two features, endogenous growth through firm creation and frictional financial intermediation, into a conventional small open economy model that is modified to allow for variable capital utilization, habit formation in consumption and a need for working capital of intermediate goods producers. These modifications are standard in the emerging market business cycles literature. Although not critical for obtaining the main results on the persistent effects of financial crises -which arise due to the novel mechanism linking firm creation with financial frictions- these features help enhance the quantitative properties of the model at little cost of added complexity.
After describing the model, I turn to presenting a quantitative analysis of a financial crisis experiment. The analysis is designed to explore the model's ability to account for the evidence described in Section 2. The crisis is modeled as the simultaneous occurrence of two exogenous shocks: an increase in the country interest rate, to represent a sudden stop in capital inflows, and a direct disruption of domestic capital markets, to capture a corresponding loss of confidence in the domestic banking sector. The main result is that the baseline model is successful at qualitatively and quantitatively capturing the empirical behavior of output, labor productivity and employment. Endogenous TFP growth is critical for the model to generate the high persistence observed in the data: it allows a crisis shock to induce a slowdown in the growth rate of TFP, leading to lasting effects on productivity, employment and output. In addition, I show that financial factors play a crucial role in generating this persistence - in the baseline calibrated model, close to half of the medium run output decline is explained by the financial side of the model. In summary, through the mechanisms described above the model can closely replicate the medium-run movements in output, labor productivity and employment identified in the data.
The modeling approach in this paper combines elements of the literature on endogenous growth through an expanding variety of products, due to Romer (1990), with ideas from the literature on financial factors in macroeconomics, pioneered by Bernanke and Gertler (1989) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). A more recent literature has incorporated mechanisms in the spirit of Romer (1990) within quantitative macroeconomic frameworks- notably Comin and Gertler (2006), who propose a model to study medium-term cycles in the U.S.,7 or Bilbiie, Ghironi and Melitz (2012), who analyze producer entry over the business cycle. Likewise, financial market frictions were first incorporated within a macroeconomic model by Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999). The latest incarnation of this class of models, which this paper follows most closely, focuses on financial intermediaries, as in Gertler and Karadi (2011) and others. This paper puts together ideas from both literatures by studying a quantitative model where financing frictions affect the creation of new firms.
The evidence and the model presented here are related to Aguiar and Gopinath (2007), who argue that a distinctive feature of emerging market business cycles is large movements in trend TFP growth, while developed economies are better characterized by transitory fluctuations around the trend. The evidence in this paper shows that financial crises are an example of such nonstationary behavior. Further, the model in this paper provides a foundation for the type of TFP process that Aguiar and Gopinath (2007) take as exogenous, and connects it explicitly with financial market imperfections.
Finally, this paper is also related to a large and growing literature that proposes quantitative macroeconomic models for emerging market economies, including Uribe and Yue (2006), Neumeyer and Perri (2005) or Mendoza (2010). A related branch of this literature has proposed quantitative frameworks to account for aspects of emerging markets financial crises, like Gertler, Gilchrist and Natalucci (2007) or Mendoza and Yue (2012). Some of these frameworks, as well as several others,8offer explanations for the observed decline in TFP during financial crises, including declines in capacity utilization, sectoral reallocation, and disruption in trade of imported inputs. While I view the mechanism in this paper as complementary to theirs, there is a key difference based on my focus on accounting for the medium-run TFP decline and its role in generating a slow recovery.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, I present the evidence on the effects of financial crises. In Section 3 I describe the model, and present the simulation results in Section 4. Section 5 concludes.
I now turn to describing the empirical exercise. Figure 1 provides some suggestive evidence: it plots (log) output, labor productivity and employment for a group of Asian countries around the financial crisis of 1997.9 The first panel suggests a very persistent output loss following the crisis: output does not recover to the pre-crisis trend (green dashed line), but rather remains permanently below trend in the aftermath of the crisis. From the second and third panels, there is a considerable decline in labor productivity, which is also very persistent, and a more modest slowdown in employment. In particular, labor productivity falls by about 10 percent relative to the pre-crisis trend, and it never rebounds.10
To provide more formal evidence on the behavior of output, labor
productivity and employment following financial crises, I employ an
approach similar to Cerra and Saxena (2008), who estimate a
univariate autoregressive model for output growth, augmented to
include current and lagged values of dummies indicating financial
crises and other shocks. I start by decomposing (log) output as the
sum of employment and labor productivity ( and
respectively, in logs):
I then estimate the following bivariate model:
![]() |
(1) |
where
.
The specification is motivated by the assumption that both hours
and labor productivity are integrated of order one, so that
first-differencing is necessary to achieve stationarity.11 The
regressors in (1) include a country fixed
effect, one lag of the endogenous vector, and current and lagged
values of a dummy variable indicating the
year in which a systemic banking crisis starts in country
, year
. Lag selection
procedures recommend one lag for the endogenous vector. I include
four lags for the crisis indicator since coefficients on lags above
4 are insignificant, although results are robust to the inclusion
of a larger number of lags of
.
The model in (1) is estimated on a sample of 17 emerging economies. Data for annual real output and employment are obtained from the Total Economy Database. I obtain systemic banking crisis dates from Laeven and Valencia (2012), an updated version of the dates in Caprio and Klingebiel (2003), also used by Cerra and Saxena (2008) among many others.12
Figure 2 shows the impulse responses of labor productivity and employment from estimated model (1), as well as the response of output.13 For this sample of countries, the response of output is large and highly persistent, consistent with the findings in Cerra and Saxena (2008). Four years after the crisis, the output loss reaches and remains at almost 12 percent. Decomposing output into labor productivity and employment reveals a substantial decline in productivity, which remains at about negative 6 percent after 4 years. From the panel on the right, the drop in employment is slightly more modest in magnitude, and it is also highly persistent. The impulse responses reported in Figure 2 constitute the data moments against which I will evaluate the model presented below.14
Figure 1: Total output, employment and output per employed worker (logs) for group of 6 South East Asian countries (Indonesia, Malaysia, Phillipines, Korea, Thailand and Hong Kong). Pre-crisis linear trend (green dashed line) computed for the period 1980-1996.
Figure 2: Estimated impulse responses to a banking crisis. The dashed lines indicate 90% confidence bands computed by bootstrapping. Time measured in years. All variables in logs.
Figure 3 displays time series on TFP and patent and trademark applications by residents in South Korea. As shown in the top left panel, the 1997 financial crisis involved a persistent slowdown in TFP relative to trend. From the bottom left panel, after a moderate slowdown prior to the crisis, in 1997 TFP plunges by about 6% relative to trend. Consistent with the evidence just presented, this decline is never recovered.15 The right panel shows patent and trademark applications in Korea. After rising for almost two decades practically without interruption, these variables display large declines during the crisis episode - about 25% for patents, and more than 35% in the case of trademarks.
This evidence lends support to the mechanism introduced in this paper, namely that a financial crisis such as the one suffered by South Korea in 1997 may lead to a reduction in the pace at which new firms are created, resulting in a highly persistent effect of the crisis. The mechanism is also supported by empirical studies on the effects of finance on firm creation in the case of the U.S.16 In turn, the hypothesis that difficult access to external finance hinders innovation and R&D is backed by several firm-level studies.17 Finally, a number of papers document such effects for developing economies.18
To summarize, the evidence described above confirms that the large and persistent output declines associated with financial crises in emerging countries is indeed a general phenomenon across episodes and countries. The magnitudes of the declines in productivity uncovered by the exercise are comparable to those found by other studies of emerging market crises.19 Further, these declines tend to have a very large permanent component. In the following sections I describe and analyze a quantitative model capable of generating drops in TFP, productivity and employment of size and persistence comparable to those in the data.
The core framework is a small open economy model with endogenous TFP growth through an expanding variety of intermediates, as in Romer (1990) or Comin and Gertler (2006). The difference with respect to these frameworks is that there is an imperfection in financial markets that impedes the smooth flow of resources from savers (households and international investors) to banks, who finance the introduction of new firms. I introduce three further modifications that have become common in the DSGE literature recently, and that help the model produce a more realistic behavior of macroeconomic aggregates in response to the crisis: variable capital utilization, habit formation in consumption, and a working capital requirement for intermediate goods producers.
Figure 3: TFP, Patents and Trademarks, South Korea (in logs). Trend for TFP computed for the period 1980-1996. Source: TFP from Coe, Helpman and Hoffmaister (2009). Patent and trademark applications from World Development Indicators.
There are six types of agents in the model: households, entrepreneurs, banks, final goods producers, intermediate goods producers and capital producers. Homogeneous output is produced by final output producers using an expanding variety of intermediates. The entrepreneurial sector uses funds borrowed from banks to finance the creation of new firms. In turn, banks obtain financing from domestic households and from foreign capital markets. In what follows, I discuss the behavior of each of these agents in turn, and derive the aggregate relationships that characterize the dynamic path of the economy.
Suppose there is a representative family with a unit measure of
members. Households make decisions on consumption, labor supply,
investment in physical capital and saving through a risk-free
international bond. There are two types of members within each
household: workers and bankers, with measures
and
respectively. A fraction of the workers
are specialized or "skilled" workers, and supply labor
inelastically to the entrepreneurial sector. Their role will be
clear as I discuss entrepreneurs below. Regular workers supply
labor elastically to intermediates producers. Both types of labor
return wages to the family. Banks use borrowed funds to make loans
to entrepreneurs, and also transfer any earnings from this activity
back to the household. There is perfect consumption insurance among
family members. As in Gertler and Karadi (2011) and others, this
formulation is a simple way of introducing heterogeneity in terms
of borrowers and lenders while maintaining the tractability of a
representative agent model.
There is random turnover between bankers and workers: a banker
becomes a worker with probability
. At the end of their careers,
bankers transfer their net wealth to the family. At the same time,
each period a fraction
of workers start a
career as bankers, exactly offsetting the number of bankers who
exit. As explained below, it is assumed that the family transfers a
small amount of resources to bankers who start out so they are able
to start operations. Bank exit is introduced as a device to ensure
that the financial imperfection will be relevant: otherwise banks
might reach a point where internal resources are enough to finance
all desired loans to entrepreneurs.
Letting denote consumption and
hours of work in the sector producing intermediates, a
households' utility function is
![]() |
(2) |
The preference structure follows Uribe and Yue (2006), Neumeyer
and Perri (2005) and much of the emerging market business cycle
literature. It abstracts from wealth effects on labor supply, as in
Greenwood, Hercowitz and Huffman (GHH, 1988). The term multiplying
the disutility of work,
, depends on the aggregate
technological level,
, as follows:
![]() |
(3) |
The term
, which at the low frequency grows
at the same rate as
, is introduced to ensure
the existence of a balanced growth path with stationary hours. In
the calibrated version of the model, I will set
to a very small value, so that fluctuations in
have a negligible impact on the
disutility of labor at high and medium frequencies. Under the
interpretation of GHH preferences as a reduced form for an economy
with home production (Benhabib, Rogerson and Wright (1991) ), a
small value of
can be viewed as capturing a
process of "slow diffusion" of the varieties used in the final
goods sector into the home production sector.
The households' decision problem is to choose stochastic sequences for consumption, labor supply, purchases of the international bond and purchases of following-period physical capital to solve the following problem:
subject to
Above, is the price of capital and
is its rental rate,
the wage rate and
is the interest
rate on the international bond.
denotes the
family's choice of foreign debt and
is the
choice for physical capital holdings. Finally,
denotes net transfers from firm ownership plus wages
earned by skilled workers.
The international interest rate depends
on aggregate net foreign indebtedness
and on a
random shock
as follows:
![]() |
(4) |
As is usual in the small open economy literature, the reason for
introducing a dependence of the cost of borrowing on net foreign
indebtedness is to ensure stationary dynamics. I choose a very
small value for so that this feature does not
affect the dyamics of the model. A raise in
,
interpretable as a country interest rate shock, is a simple way to
model the sudden capital outflows that have accompanied many of the
emerging market financial crises analyzed in the previous section.
The expression for marginal utility of consumption,
is the following:
![]() |
(5) |
![]() |
(6) |
Define the households' stochastic discount factor between
periods and
,
as
![]() |
(7) |
Then the household's decision on bond and capital holdings are characterized by two conventional Euler equations:
![]() |
(8) |
![]() |
(9) |
Labor supply is given by
![]() |
(10) |
In every period there is an unbounded mass of prospective entrepreneurs with the ability to introduce new varieties of intermediates, interpretable as "innovations" or new types of products or technologies which may be entirely novel to the small open economy or possibly adaptations of varieties already in use in more advanced countries.20Specifically, each entrepreneur can use resources to create a new "potential" firm, which will then become a successful new variety with a certain (exogenous) probability each period. At the same time, both successful and unsuccessful firms face the risk of an exogenous exit shock. This process is meant to capture in a simple way the life-cycle dynamics of the firm.
Entrepreneurs need to obtain funding from banks to finance entry. Here the idea is that banks are "specialists" with skills in evaluating and monitoring entrepreneurs. Contracts between banks are entrepreneurs are assumed to be frictionless: in exchange for funding, each entrepreneur can offer the bank a security which is perfectly contingent on the success of his or her project. On the other hand, as explained in detail in the following section, banks do face frictions in obtaining funds.
To be more specific, each entrepreneur can produce new potential firms by employing materials and skilled workers as inputs, according to the following production function:
![]() |
(11) |
Above, is the amount of materials used (in
units of final output) and
is the number
of skilled workers hired.
denotes the
aggregate technological level of the economy, which as explained
below is equal to the total number of firm varieties in operation.
As in Romer (1990), (11) incorporates an
externality of the aggregate level of knowledge on the efficiency
of skilled labor in introducing new types of firms. This assumption
is key to generate endogenous growth.
Given constant returns to scale of (11), the
entrepreneurial sector can be formulated as consisting of a
representative entrepreneur or potential entrant who decides how
many new firms to introduce, subject to production function
(11). An alternative, perhaps more plausible,
interpretation is that there is an unbounded mass of entrepreneurs,
each with an "idea" for a project, which can be put into practice
by paying a sunk cost given by the marginal
cost associated with (11). Denoting the skilled
labor wage by
, the expression for this marginal
cost is the following:21
![]() |
(12) |
The entrepreneur has no funds to finance the sunk cost
. To obtain funds, he or she issues
equity to banks. Let
be the price of a unit
of entrepreneur equity. There are no commitment or enforcement
frictions between entrepreneurs and banks, so the entrepreneur can
commit to pay all the contingent proceeds from the project to the
equity holding bank. At the same time, given free entry of
entrepreneurs, the price of equity issued by entrepreneurs must
equal the sunk cost of introducing a new project:
![]() |
(13) |
Once the entrepreneur has paid the sunk cost, the dynamics of
the firm are as follows. A firm that has just entered is still not
a successful new business. The firm becomes successful with an
exogenous probability . Here the idea is that
an entering entrepreneur cannot grow into a successful business
immediately, but rather it takes time to turn his or her idea into
a marketable new product. Once the entrepreneur's idea becomes
successful, it generates profits
per period
(determined below when discussing the problem of intermediates
producers). At the same time, both successful and
still-unsuccessful businesses face the risk of receiving an
exogenous exit shock: the corresponding survival probabilities are
denoted
and
respectively. I assume that
, to capture the fact
that small, young firms have higher exit rates than firms that are
large and mature.22
Finally, as explained earlier, the supply of skilled labor is
assumed to be inelastic and fixed at
. One can then combine
(12), (13) and the first-order
condition for
to obtain the following relation
between the price of entrepreneur equity
and
the number of new entrants
:
![]() |
(14) |
Equation (14) can be interpreted as an
aggregate supply curve of new entrant firms, as a function of the
price of a unit of entrepreneur equity .
Banks lend funds obtained in capital markets to entrepreneurs. As in Gertler and Kiyotaki (2011), banks are interpreted as specialists who assist in channeling funds from savers to entrepreneurs. They purchase securities issued by entrepreneurs that are perfectly state-contingent. These claims offer to pay the full value of the entrepreneur's project in the contingency that the project is successful. In addition, banks engage in maturity transformation: they hold long-term assets (claims on entrepreneurial projects) and fund these assets with short-term liabilities (beyond their own equity capital).
The agency friction in financial markets takes the form of a
limited enforcement problem between the bank and its creditors: at
the end of the period, after borrowing funds, a bank can default on
his or her debt and divert an exogenous fraction
of resources, with creditors only
being able to recover the remaining part
. This imposes a limit on how
much debt the bank is able to take on ex-ante, as lenders recognize
that excessive debt will lead to default.
I allow the fraction divertable
to be time-varying. An increase in
is interpretable as a reduction in
the efficiency of financial markets, as lenders expect to be able
to recover a smaller amount from defaulting borrowers.23
Given these considerations, the bank's sequence problem is the following:
![]() |
(15) |
subject to
![]() |
(16) |
![]() |
(17) |
Examining first the budget constraint, equation (16), the bank's use of funds (left hand side) includes
the purchase of an amount of claims on
entrepreneurs, which costs
, as well as debt repayments,
. The sources of funds are the
revenues obtained from previous loans (the first term on the right
hand side) as well as new debt issued,
. Projects
financed the previous period,
, have a
survival probability
. If the project
survives, it is successful with probability
,
in which case the bank receives its full value, denoted
. If the project is unsuccessful this period, then given
the simple Poisson process for the evolution of projects it is
exactly equivalent to a security issued by a new entrant
entrepreneur, so that its value is
.
A successful project generates a stream of profits
obtained from manufacturing and selling the new variety of
intermediate. Therefore, the value of a successful project is given
by the expected discounted value of the profit stream, accounting
for the survival rate
of successful
firms:24
![]() |
(18) |
As indicated by (15), if a bank alive at
exits in period
(which happens with probability
) it the accumulated
wealth back to the household. The resources accumulated until
period
are given by the term in curly brackets
in (15). The bank thus values payoffs in the
period and state at which it exits with the household's stochastic
discount factor,
.
Equation (17) is the bank's incentive
constraint. At the end of period , after
having borrowed in capital markets, the bank may choose to default
on its creditors and divert fraction
of available funds, which it then
transfers back to its household. Creditors can then force the bank
into bankruptcy and recover the remaining fraction
of resources, but it is too
costly for them to recover the fraction
of funds that the bank diverted.
Accordingly, for creditors to be willing to supply funds to the
bank, equation (17) must hold: the bank's value
if he honors the contract with his creditors must be greater than
the value of diverting resources in the amount
and being shut
down.
To simplify the bank's problem, define first the rate of return
to one dollar invested in entrepreneurial projects, :
depends only on the aggregate state,
through prices
and
.
Times of low realizations of the value of a new intermediate,
and of the value of entrepreneur
equity,
, will be times of low returns
. Noting that bank's individual state
variables at the beginning of period
are
and
, the
entrepreneur's problem can be expressed recursively as follows:
![]() |
(19) |
subject to
![]() |
(20) |
![]() |
(21) |
Above, the time index on the value function reflects aggregate
uncertainty. The problem can be simplified further by realizing
that the key individual state variable is the bank's net worth
, defined as the difference between the
value of assets and debt:
![]() |
(22) |
From the budget constraint (20) at equality, the evolution of net worth is
![]() |
(23) |
Net worth at is given by the gross return to
the bank's investments financed during
, net of
repayments to creditors. Equation (23) shows
that net worth at
depends on the individual
state at
together with the
realization of the aggregate state at
, through the
rate of return
. This suggests making the
following guess for the bank's value function:
![]() |
(24) |
Above, the undetermined coefficient
is conjectured to
depend only on the aggregate state, and dependence of
on
through (22) and (23) is understood.
Define also the following variables:
![]() |
(25) |
![]() |
(26) |
![]() |
(27) |
Variable
is interpretable as the
prospective value of a unit of net worth, before the bank finds out
whether he will have to exit at the end of the period. From
equation (26),
is
interpretable to the return for the bank of investing in excess of
the cost of funds. Finally,
represents
the value of an extra unit of net worth today.
Given the definitions above, the problem of the bank reduces to the following:
![]() |
(28) |
subject to
![]() |
(29) |
Here reflects the value to the bank of
funding an additional project (increasing
)
while holding net worth constant. On the other hand,
is the value of an additional unit of net worth,
holding constant
. With frictionless financial
markets banks would be unconstrained, with the implication that
. The agency problem introduces a
friction that makes banks potentially constrained, and that may
therefore place limits on arbitrage.
Equation (29) is the incentive
constraint. Note that as long as
, it is profitable for the bank
to borrow and fund an additional project. Thus, in this instance,
and given
, the constraint binds:
![]() |
(30) |
Equation (30) shows that the amount the
bank can spend on funding projects,
, is constrained by his net worth
, through a limit on the amount the
bank is allowed to borrow in capital markets.25
Define the banks maximum leverage ratio
as
![]() |
(31) |
so that when the credit constraint binds,
![]() |
(32) |
Then with a binding constraint, solving the undetermined coefficient from (28)-(29) we have that
![]() |
(33) |
The value of a unit of net worth today (
) derives from its
value holding assets constant (
) plus the
capacity that it generates to fund additional projects (
) multiplied by the value to the bank of those
additional projects (
).
Aggregation accross banks is simple given the linearity of
(32). The aggregate amount of projects
funded, , is constrained by aggregate net worth
of the financial intermediation sector:
![]() |
(34) |
At the same time, aggregate net worth at is
given by the sum of net worth of surviving banks, which evolves
individually according to (23), and the
transfer that newborn ones obtain from their family. For simplicity
I assume that the transfer is a small fraction
of the total value of the projects funded the previous
period. Accordingly, the law of motion of aggregate net worth is
given by
![]() |
(35) |
Note that the source of fluctuations in aggregate net worth of
the financial intermediation sector are movements in return
, which as discussed earlier arise
from movements in the prices
and
.
In what follows I describe the evolution of the aggregate stock
of projects for new varieties. At the beginning of period
, a total number of potential firms
exist in the economy. Each point in
represents a project for a
different intermediate. The points between 0 and
correspond to already successful new intermediates,
with
. In period
,
the entrepreneurial sector introduces a measure
of new potential firms. At the same time, a fraction
of unsuccessful firms exit each
period. Thus, the aggregate number of potential firms
evolves as follows:
![]() |
(36) |
In period the points between
and
correspond to projects "in
process", i.e. projects that the entrepreneurial sector is
currently attempting to turn into successful firms. Fraction
of these projects will become
successful during period
. Also, only fraction
of firms operating in period
survive into
.
Therefore, the total number of varieties of intermediates,
, evolves as follows:
![]() |
(37) |
where the term in brackets is the measure of potential firms
that have not yet been successful, accounting for the fact that
only fraction of potential firms survive each
period.
Recall that refers to the aggregate number
of projects financed by banks. In equilibrium, we must have
![]() |
(38) |
That is, the total number of projects financed by the financial intermediation sector must be equal to the total number of projects that entrepreneurs are currently holding and trying to develop.
These considerations clarify how financial factors may affect
the evolution of TFP. When net worth is low, through equation
(34) the aggregate number of projects that
the intermediation sector can finance, , is
reduced. This makes demand for new entrants
lower, as equation (38) suggests. With a smaller
number of products being attempted, the growth rate of TFP will
decline, as equation (37) indicates.
As emphasized earlier, with frictionless markets there is
perfect arbitrage, so that excess returns
must be equal to zero. It follows from (25)-(27) and (33) that
, or
![]() |
(39) |
The value of entrepreneur equity, , is
given by the option value of obtaining a successful new
intermediate the following period, valued
-
this happens with probability
. With
financial frictions and constrained banks, we will have
![]() |
(40) |
The gap between the left and right hand side of (40) widens whenever banks' financial constraints are tighter, which happens in times in which the net worth of the intermediation sector is low. This implies that the rate of new firm creation falls below its frictionless level. The imperfection in financial markets also implies that the growth rate of TFP, and therefore of output, along the balanced growth path is below its value in a model without financial frictions.26
The final good is produced in a competitive sector which
aggregates a continuum of measure of
intermediates:
![]() |
(41) |
Given the aggregator above, demand for each intermediate
by the final good sector is
![]() |
(42) |
where the price level is defined as
![]() |
(43) |
Equation (42) gives the demand facing each intermediate good producer . Intermediates are produced using a standard Cobb-Douglas
technology with capital services
and labor
as inputs:
![]() |
(44) |
Intermediate goods firms face a working capital requirement
which forces them to hold an amount of non-interest-bearing assets
that is no smaller than a multiple
of the quarterly wage bill:
where
denotes the amount of working
capital held by firm
in period
.
As shown in Uribe and Yue (2006) and Mendoza and Yue (2012), this
formulation implies that the effective cost of labor becomes
, and therefore an increase in the interest rate reduces the demand
of labor by intermediates firms.
The objective of intermediates producers is to maximize profits, including the value of the remaining part of capital they rent from households. Firms face a replacement price of depreciated capital equal to unity.27Thus, their objective is to solve
Subject to (42) and (44). Solving the firm's problem yields the following equations:
![]() |
(45) |
![]() |
(46) |
![]() |
(47) |
Each intermediates producer sets its price to a constant markup
over marginal cost - the ratio of price to marginal cost equals
. Per period
profits of intermediates producers,
, can
then be shown to be equal to
![]() |
(48) |
Finally, one can combine (41) with the first-order conditions for intermediates producers and with equilibrium in factor markets to obtain an expression for final output:
![]() |
(49) |
At the end of period , capital producing firms
repair depreciated capital and produce new capital. For simplicity
I assume that no financial frictions apply to the production and
purchase of capital goods, in order to focus on the role of
frictions on the creation of new firms. However, it would be
straightforward to extend the model to allow for frictions in
investment of existing firms as well, along the lines of Gertler
and Karadi (2011) and others.28
As in and Gertler et. al. (2007), repair of old capital is not
subject to adjustment costs, but there are stock adjustment costs
associated with the production of new capital. Let be net investment, the amount of investment used
for construction of new capital goods:
![]() |
(50) |
To produce new capital, capital producers combine final output
with existing capital via the constant returns to scale technology
, where
is increasing and concave and
satisfies
and
, where
is the net investment to capital ratio along the
balanced growth path.
The economy-wide capital stock evolves according to29
![]() |
(51) |
As in Gertler et. al. (2007), I assume that capital producing firms make production plans one period in advance, with the objective of capturing the delayed response of investment observed in the data. Accordingly, the optimality condition for capital producers is
![]() |
(52) |
The economy uses output and international borrowing to finance consumption, investment in physical capital, and investment in new technology. The resulting market clearing condition is
![]() |
(53) |
is economywide foreign indebtedness,
equal to the sum of aggregate family and entrepreneurial debt (
). Equation (53) can be derived by combining family and
entrepreneur budget constraints with equilibrium conditions.
This completes the description of the model.
This section presents numerical results from a dynamic simulation of the model, meant to capture in a rough way the type of crises analyzed empirically in Section 2. The goal is to illustrate how the novel mechanism introduced in the paper, namely financially constrained firm creation, is crucial for the model to be able to produce persistent declines in output, productivity and employment that are quantitatively close to those identified in the data.30
Table 1: Parameter Values
Symbol | Value | Description |
---|---|---|
Conventional: ![]() | 0.99 | Discount factor |
Conventional: ![]() | 1 | Risk aversion |
Conventional: ![]() | 1 | Inverse Frisch elasticity |
Conventional: ![]() | 0.25 | Habits Uribe adn Yue (2006) |
Conventional: ![]() | 0.01 | Parameter on labor disutility term |
Conventional: ![]() | 0.025 | Capital depreciation |
Conventional: ![]() | 1/3 | Capital share |
Conventional: ![]() | 0.15 | Elasticity of depreciation to utilization Comin et. al. (2009) |
Conventional: ![]() | 2.5 | Demand elasticity for intermediates Comin and Gertler (2006) |
Conventional: Φ"(In/K) | 0.2 | Elasticity of Pk to In/K Gertler et. al. (2007) |
Conventional: θW | 0.35 | Working capital requirement |
Conventional: τ | 0.00001 | Elasticity of interest rate to foreign debt |
Conventional: B/Y | 0.2 | Foreign debt to output |
Entrepreneurs: λ | 0.125 | Adoption prob. 2 years success lag - Pakes and Schankerman (1984) |
Entrepreneurs: 1-φA | 0.025 | Exit rate old Bilbiie et. al (2012) |
Entrepreneurs: 1-φZ | 0.05 | Exit rate young Haltiwanger et. al (2012) |
Entrepreneurs: η | 0.125 | Final output in entrepreneurs' prod. fun. 10% o foutput used by entrepreneurs along BGP |
Entrepreneurs: ![]() | 0.033 | Skilled labor supply 2% TFP growth rate - Young (1995) |
Banks: σ | 0.98 | Survival rate 12 years horizon |
Banks: θ | 0.45 | Fraction divertable 1% annual spread |
Banks: ξ | 0.0075 | Transfer rate leverage = 4 |
Table 1 lists the choice of parameter values. Overall there are
twenty-two parameters, fourteen of which relate to preferences and
technology. Of the remaining eight, five relate to the
entrepreneurial sector: the success probability (), the exit rates (
,
), the weight of materials in
entrepreneurs' production function (
) and the
aggregate supply of skilled labor (
). The remaining three parameters
relate to financial intermediaries. They include the survival rate
of banks (
), the steady state divertable
fraction of assets (
), and the transfer rate
to new bankers (
).
I choose relatively conventional values for the preference and
technology parameters. The discount factor is set at 0.99, and risk
aversion is set at unity. I set the inverse Frisch elasticity of
labor supply, , equal to one. I set the habits
parameter
at 0.25, similar to the value estimated
by Uribe and Yue (2006). The parameter
governing the impact of the total number of varieties
on the labor disutility term
is set at 0.01, implying that
aggregate technology affects the disutility of work only over the
very long run. Turning to technology parameters, I set the capital
share
to 1/3, and the
quarterly depreciation rate of physical capital,
, to 2.5
. Capital utilization along
the balanced growth path is normalized to 1, and the elasticity of
marginal depreciation with respect to the utilization rate (
), is
set at 0.15, as in Jaimovich and Rebelo (2009) and Comin, Gertler
and Santacreu (2009). I set the elasticity of the price of capital
with respect to the investment-capital ratio at 0.2, as in Gertler
et. al. (2007) and Bernanke et. al. (1999). I choose the parameter
on the intermediate goods aggregator,
, so
that output is proportional to TFP along the balanced growth path,
which by examining equation (49) amounts to
imposing
. This restriction
makes profits per period,
, a stationary
variable, and simplifies somewhat the characterization of the
balanced growth path. Given
, the resulting value for the
markup is
, close to the
value of 1.6 chosen by Comin and Gertler (2006).
Regarding the working capital constraint, I set
, implying that firms need
to pay less than a month's worth of the wage bill in
advance.31 The debt to GDP ratio along the
balanced growth path is set at 0.2, and the elasticity of the
interest rate with respect to the debt-output ratio equals 0.00001
- the latter ensures that the dynamics of the model are virtually
unaffected by the debt-elastic interest rate at high and medium
frequencies, while still making the foreign asset position revert
to trend over the long run.
Turning to the parameters relating to the entrepreneurial
sector, I set the probability of successfully obtaining a new
variety, , to 0.125, implying an average
success lag (
) of 8 quarters or 2 years.
This is based on evidence on mean R&D gestation lags reported
by Pakes and Schankerman (1984), defined as the average time
between the initial outlay of resources and the beginning of the
associated revenue stream. The exit rate for mature firms (
) is set to 10 percent annually,
following Bilbiie et. al. (2012), and the corresponding number for
young firms (
) is set to twice that number,
consistent with the evidence in Haltiwanger et. al. (2012) of
substantially higher firm exit by younger firms. The weight of
final output in entrepreneurs' production function,
, is set to 0.125, implying that along the balanced
growth path 10 percent of output is used by the entrepreneurial
sector. This number represents a rough estimate of expenditures on
firm creation as a fraction of GDP.32 Finally, the inelastic
supply of skilled labor,
, is set to deliver a growth
rate of TFP along the balanced growth path of 2 percent, similar to
the numbers reported by Young (1995).
The choice of the financial sector parameters is meant to be
suggestive. Similar to Gertler and Kiyotaki (2010), I set the
entrepreneur survival rate
, implying an expected horizon of
bankers of about twelve years. To calibrate the fraction of
resources that bankers can divert in steady state,
, and the transfer to newborn bankers,
, I target two features of the balanced growth path of the
model economy: a bank leverage ratio (assets to net worth) of four,
and an excess return
equal to one hundred
basis points annually. The target for the leverage ratio reflects a
relatively conservative attempt to capture an average leverage
ratio of the financial intermediation sector. For example, most
housing finance is typically intermediated by financial
institutions with leverage ratios of at least 10 on average in the
case of commercial banks, and substantially higher for investment
banks.33 On the other hand, leverage ratios are
clearly smaller in other sectors of the economy. The target for the
spread along the balanced growth path is based on evidence on BBB
industrial corporate spreads in the US and Europe prior to the
crisis. These targets imply setting the divertible fraction
to 0.45, and the transfer rate
to 0.0075.
I now turn to the crisis experiment. The initiating disturbance
is the combined impact of two shocks: an increase in the country
interest rate , and an increase in the variable
governing the agency friction,
.
I consider a 500 basis point increase in the interest rate that
persists as a first-order autoregressive process with a 0.88
coefficient. These magnitudes are close to the evidence for the
crisis in South Korea in 1997, as shown by Gertler et. al.
(2007).34 At the same time,
rises by fifty percent, and the
increase persists as a first order autoregressive process with
coefficient 0.95 (the time paths for
and
are shown in Figure 5). The idea
is to capture a situation in which not only there is a capital
outflow, as captured by an increase in
, but also
a disruption in domestic financial markets, corresponding in the
model to the increase in
. It is best to think of the shock
as a rare event.
Figure 4 shows the main result of the paper, by plotting a
dynamic simulation for the model economy along with its empirical
counterpart. It shows the behavior of output, labor productivity
and employment following the shocks to and to
the agency parameter
, relative to the balanced growth
path of the economy. In the baseline model (blue solid line), there
is a large permanent component to the decline in output, whose
magnitude is close to the data. As an example, six years after the
shock output is depressed by about 11 percent relative to the
unshocked path of the economy, very close to the empirical value.
This is the case even though the exogenous driving forces,
and
, have almost completely returned
to their steady state values. As made clear in the following
section, behind this result is the behavior of firm creation
following the crisis, which implies that the financial crisis shock
has a permanent effect on aggregate TFP. This is the main driving
force behind the behavior of labor productivity displayed in the
figure. At the same time, as shown in the last panel of Figure 4,
the permanent decline in productivity leads to a decline in labor
demand by producers of intermediates. As a result, employment also
falls persistently relative to the balanced growth path of the
economy. Thus, the model is also able to account for the evidence
provided in Section 2 that employment remains persistently
depressed following financial crises. Overall, the bottomline from
Figure 4 is that the mechanisms introduced in the model have
potential for quantitatively accounting for the medium-run behavior
of output, labor productivity and employment following financial
crises.35
Figure 4: Crisis experiment: Responses of output, labor productivity and employment. Time measured in years. All vairables in log deviations from the balanced growth path.
Figure 5: Shock paths for interest rate R (log deviation) and fraction divertable θ (level) in crisis experiment. Time measured in years.
The financial intermediation sector plays an important role in
accounting for the model's behavior. Without financial market
frictions (green dashed line), the responses of all three variables
differ significantly from their empirical counterparts: for
example, the decline in output six years after the shock hits is
approximately 6 percent in the case without financial frictions,
compared to the 11 percent in the baseline case and in the data.
The difference is driven to a large extent by the endogenous
amplification implied the interaction between the financial
intermediation sector and the process of firm creation (described
in detail in the following section). This can be seen by comparing
the case without financial frictions and the case with financial
frictions but without the shock to
(light blue dash-dotted line). The
increase in
then contributes an extra decline
in all three variables - in the case of output its contribution is
about 2 percentage points in the medium run.
Finally, Figure 4 also reports the response in a model in which the endogenous growth channel is inactive (grey dotted line) - what is then left is a relatively standard RBC model of a small open economy, subjected to an interest rate shock. As made clear by the figure, the behavior of the model in this case is very far from the data, due to the absence of endogenous movements in TFP.
How does the model's transmission mechanism operate? Figure 6
documents the behavior of the financial and entrepreneurial side of
the model following the crisis shock. The disturbance induces a
large decline in the value of a new variety, , and in the price of entrepreneur equity,
(top panels), as the stream of future profits per new
intermediate good is discounted more heavily. This has the effect
of generating a large drop in the net worth of the intermediation
sector, as equation (35) indicates.
Notice that the interest rate shock leads the price of entrepreneur
equity,
, to fall substantially more in the
baseline model with frictions (light blue dash-dotted line) than in
the model without financial frictions (green dashed) - about sixty
percent more on impact. This is at the core of the amplification
mechanism in the model: as banks' constraints tighten (as reflected
in the increase in the multiplier on the incentive constraint),
they are forced to cut back on project funding to a larger extent
than what would happen with frictionless financial markets. Along
the way, there is an "adverse feedback" effect between bank net
worth and the value of entrepreneur equity
: as
the former falls, bank' constraints tighten, forcing a decline in
the credit available for projects in development. The decrease in
demand for new projects leads to further reductions in value
, starting a new round of declines in
bank net worth. The end result is a large decline in the aggregate
number of new projects started,
, as made
clear by the last panel.
Figure 6: Crisis experiment: responses of growth and financial intermediation variables. Time measured in years. All variables in log deviations from the balanced growth path except net worth, expressed in level deviation as fraction of value in the balanced growth path.
The tightening of financial constraints is also reflected in the
rise in excess returns
, which
reflects that profitable opportunities in the entrepreneurial
sector go unexploited due to an intensification of financial market
frictions. The rise in the spread represents a widening of the
departure from perfect arbitrage, as exemplified by equation
(40). It is
accompanied by a substantial reduction in the flow of credit to
banks, as indicated by the right panel in the third row.
The blue solid line shows the effects of the and
shocks combined. Relative to the
case with the interest rate shock only, the increase in
further restricts the flow of
credit to banks (right panel in the third row), as they are able to
borrow less per unit of net worth. This initiates another round of
cuts in project funding, again amplified by the adverse feedback
channel described above.
The decline in the number of projects funded by the entrepreneurial sector directly translates into a decline in the rate of newly successful firms. As shown in Figure 7, it follows that there is a substantial slowdown in the growth rate of TFP, leading to a permanent drop in the level of this variable relative to the balanced growth path. Further, the magnitude of the medium-run decline is substantially larger due to financial factors - in the baseline model, the level of TFP after six years falls more than 6 percent with both shocks and almost 5 percent with only the interest rate shock, compared to only 3.5 percent in the model without financial frictions. Thus, the financial friction plays a quantitatively significant role in helping the model generate a persistent decline in TFP following a crisis. Such movements in TFP are a salient feature of financial crises, as illustrated for example in the case of South Korea reviewed earlier, in which TFP remained persistently depressed relative to trend by about 6%. In a standard RBC economy, of course, TFP growth would be unaffected by the crisis shock.
Figure 7: Crisis experiment: responses of growth rate and level of TFP. Time measured in years. Variables in log deviations from the balanced growth path.
Finally, Figure 8 plots the response of a set of standard macroeconomic variables. Overall, the model does a relatively good job of capturing quantitatively the macroeconomic effects of the typical emerging market financial crisis. In particular, the responses of the variables displayed in Figure 8 are reasonably close to the evidence for the Korean 1997 crisis, as documented for example in Gertler et. al. (2007). The mechanisms introduced in this paper contribute to explaining the persistence of the decline in output and other variables following these episodes. A final point to highlight from Figure 8 is the substantial amplification due to the financial friction of aggregate consumption, a variable which is well known to display higher volatility relative to GDP in emerging markets when compared to more developed economies, and also of the ratio of net exports to GDP.
Figure 8: Crisis experiment: Responses of macroeconomic variables. Time measured in years. All variables in log deviations from the balanced growth path.
This paper has sought to explain the highly persistent effects of financial crises. It has argued that the phenomenon of slow recoveries from financial crises can be a natural consequence of an adverse shock in an environment in which productivity growth is endogenous through the creation of new firms. Further, it has shown how domestic financial market disruptions can work to amplify these declines. Thanks to these mechanisms, the model developed here is able to quantitatively reproduce the persistent declines in output, labor productivity and employment following financial crises identified from the data.
The evidence presented in this paper has been based on the experience of emerging market economies, as have been some of the modeling choices made (for example, the interest rate shock used to motivate a crisis, or the small open economy assumption). The reason is that it is in these countries where most financial crises have occurred over the past decades. The recent wave of financial crises in advanced economies, however, also appears to display a substantial degree of persistence, and many have suggested a slowdown in the underlying rate of productivity growth as a possible explanation.36 With minor adaptation, the mechanisms introduced in this paper could be used to address the case of advanced economies as well.
A potentially interesting application of the framework presented in this paper would be an evaluation of the welfare gains of government intervention in mitigating a financial crisis. Gertler and Karadi (2011) and Gertler, Kiyotaki and Queralto (2012), for example, analyze different government financial policies in the context of the recent financial crisis in the US, finding important benefits of government intervention. The endogenous productivity growth mechanism introduced in this paper would likely affect what is at stake when considering intervention during a financial meltdown, and therefore it could have a substantial impact on the welfare gains of government policies directed at ameliorating the impact of a crisis.
Aoki, K., G. Benigno and N. Kiyotaki (2007). "Capital Flows and Asset Prices," NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics 2007
Aguiar, M. and G. Gopinath (2007). "Emerging Market Business Cycles: The Cycle Is the Trend," Journal of Political Economy 115(1), 69-102
Ayyagari, M., A. Demirgüç-Kunt and V. Maksimovic (2007) "Firm Innovation in Emerging Markets: The Roles of Governance and Finance," World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4157
Bank of England (2012). Inflation Report, November 2012
Benhabib, J. and M. Spiegel (1994). "The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data," Journal of Monetary Economics 34(2), 143-173
Benjamin, D. and F. Meza (2009). "Total Factor Productivity and Labor Reallocation: The Case of the Korean 1997 Crisis,"The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics: Vol. 9: Iss.1 (Advances), Article 31
Benhabib, J., R. Rogerson and R. Wright (1991). "Homework in Macroeconomics: Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations," Journal of Political Economy 99(6), 1166-1187
Bernanke, B. (2012). "The Economic Recovery and Economic Policy," Speech at the Economic Club of New York, November 2012
Bernanke, B. and M. Gertler (1989). "Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations," American Economic Review 79(1), 14-31
Bernanke, B., M. Gertler and S. Gilchrist (1999). "The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework," Handbook of Macroeconomics, North Holland
Bilbiie, F., F. Ghironi and M. Melitz (2012). "Endogenous Entry, Product Variety, and Business Cycles," Journal of Political Economy, 120(2), 304-345
Calvo, G. (1998). "Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: The Simple Economics of Sudden Stops," Journal of Applied Economics, I(1), 35-54
Caprio, G. and D. Klingebiel (2003). "Episodes of Systemic and Borderline Financial Crises," mimeo
Cerra, V. and S. C. Saxena (2008). "Growth Dynamics: The Myth of Economic Recovery," American Economic Review 98(1), 439-457
Chari, V. V., Kehoe, P. and E. McGrattan (2008). "Business Cycle Accounting," Econometrica 75(3), 781-836
Coe, D., E. Helpman and A. Hoffmaister (2009). "International R&D Spillovers and Institutions," European Economic Review 53(7), 723-741
Comin, D. and M. Gertler (2006). "Medium-Term Business Cycles," American Economic Review 96(3), 523-551
Comin, D., M. Gertler and A. Santacreu (2009). "Technology Innovation and Diffusion as Sources of Output and Asset Price Fluctuations," mimeo
Comin, D., N. Loayza, F. Pasha and L. Serven (2009). `` Medium-Term Cycles in Developing Countries," mimeo
Del Negro, M., G. Eggertsson, A. Ferrero and N. Kiyotaki (2010)"The Great Escape? A Quantitative Evaluation of the Fed's Non-Standard Policies," mimeo
Galí, J., M. Gertler and D. López-Salido (2007), "Markups, Gaps, and the Welfare Costs of Business Fluctuations," Review of Economics and Statistics 89(1), 44-59
Gertler, M., S. Gilchrist and F. Natalucci (2007). "External Constraints on Monetary Policy and the Financial Accelerator," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39(2-3), 295-330
Gertler, M. and P. Karadi (2011). "A Model of ``Unconventional" Monetary Policy," Journal of Monetary Economics 58, 17-34
Gertler, M. and N. Kiyotaki (2010). "Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis," Handbook of Monetary Economics Vol.3, 547-599
Gertler, M., N. Kiyotaki and A. Queralto (2012). "Financial Crises, Bank Risk Exposure and Government Financial Policy," Journal of Monetary Economics 59, S17-S34
Gopinath, G. and B. Neiman (2011). "Trade Adjustment and Productivity in Large Crises," American Economic Review, forthcoming
Gorodnichenko, Y. and M. Schnitzer (2010). "Financial Constraints and Innovation: Why Poor Countries Don't Catch Up," Journal of the European Economic Association, forthcoming
Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz and G. W. Huffman (1988). `` Investment, Capacity Utilization and the Real Business Cycle," American Economic Review 78, 402-417
Griliches, Z. (1990). "Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A Survey," Journal of Economic Literature XXVIII (December 1990), 1661-1707
Hall, R. (1997). "Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the Allocation of Time," Journal of Labor Economics 15(1), S223-50
Hall, B. (2002). "The Financing of Research and Development," Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 18(1): 35-51
Hall, B. and J. Lerner (2009). "The Financing of RD and Innovation," NBER Working Paper No. 15325
Howard, G., R. Martin and B. A. Wilson (2011). "Are Recoveries from Banking and Financial Crises Really So Different?," International Finance Discussion Paper Number 1037
International Monetary Fund (2009). World Economic Outlook, October 2009 Edition
Jaimovich, N. and S. Rebelo (2009)."Can News about the Future Drive the Business Cycle?," American Economic Review 99(4), 1097-1118
Jaffe, A. B. and M. Trajtenberg (2002)."Patents, Citations and Innovations: A Window on the Knowledge Economy," Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
Jermann, U. and V. Quadrini (2012)."Macroeconomic Effects of Financial Shocks," American Economic Review 102(1), 238-271(34)
Kalemli-Ozcan, S., B. Sorensen and S. Yesiltas (2012). `` Leverage across firms, banks, and countries" Journal of International Economics 88, 284-289
Kehoe, T. and K. Ruhl (2009)."Sudden stops, sectoral reallocations, and the real exchange rate," Journal of Development Economics 89(2), 235-249
Kerr, W. and R. Nanda (2009). "Democratizing entry: Banking deregulations, financing constraints, and entrepreneurship" Journal of Financial Economics 94, 124-149
Kiyotaki, N. and J. Moore (1997). "Credit Cycles," Journal of Political Economy 105(2), 211-248
Kiyotaki, N. and J. Moore (2012). "Liquidity, Business Cycles and Monetary Policy," mimeo
Kortum, S. and J. Lerner (2000). "Assessing the contribution of venture capital to innovation," RAND Journal of Economics 31(4), 674-692
Krueger, A. and J. Yoo (2001). ``Chaebol Capitalism and the Currency-Financial Crisis in Korea," NBER Conference on Currency Crises Prevention
Laeven, L. and F. Valencia (2012). "Systemic Banking Crises Database: An Update," IMF Working Paper
Levine, R. (1997). "Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda," Journal of Economic Literature 35(2), 688-726
Levine, R. (2005). "Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence," in P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, eds: Handbook of Economic Growth (North-Holland Elsevier Publishers, Amsterdam)
Mansfield, E., M. Schwartz and S. Wagner (1981). "Imitation Costs and Patents: An Empirical Study," The Economic Journal 91, 907-918
McGrattan, E. and E. Prescott (2010). "Technology Capital and the US Current Account," American Economic Review 100(4): 1493-1522
Mendoza, E. (2010). "Sudden Stops, Financial Crises, and Leverage" American Economic Review 100(5): 1941-1966
Mendoza, E. and V. Z. Yue (2012). "A General Equilibrium Model of Sovereign Default and Business Cycles," Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(2): 889-946
Meza, F. and E. Quintin (2007). "Factor Utilization and the Real Impact of Financial Crises," The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics : Vol. 7: Iss.1 (Advances), Article 33
Neumeyer, P. A. and F. Perri (2005). "Business Cycles in Emerging Economies: The Role of Interest Rates," Journal of Monetary Economics 52, 345-380
Pakes, A. and M. Schankerman (1984). "The Rate of
Obsolescence of Knowledge, Research Gestation Lags, and the Private
Rate of Return to Research Resources," pp. 73-88 in Z. Griliches
(Ed.),Patents, RD and Productivity,
The University of Chicago Press
Pratap, S. and C. Urrutia (2010). "Financial Frictions and Total Factor Productivity: Accounting for the Real Effects of Financial Crises," Review of Economic Dynamics, 15(3) 336-358
Reinhart, C. M. and V. R. Reinhart (2010) "After the Fall," NBER Working Paper 16334
Reinhart, C. M. and K. S. Rogoff (2009) "This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly," Princeton University Press
Romer, P. (1990). "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political Economy 98(5), 71-102
Uribe, M. and V. Z. Yue (2006). "Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom?," Journal of International Economics 69, 6-36
Young, A. (1995). "The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian Growth Experience," Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3): 641-680
Data on real output and employment (in number of persons) are obtained from the Total Economy Database.37 The data on employment used is broadly consistent with the employment dataset in Neumeyer and Perri (2005) for the set of countries used in that analysis. Systemic banking crisis episode dates are from Laeven and Valencia (2012).
The list of countries and episodes used in the analysis is the following (episode starting date in parenthesis): Indonesia (1997), Malaysia (1997), Korea (1997), Thailand (1983, 1997), Philippines (1983, 1997), Argentina (1980, 1989, 1995, 2001), Brazil (1990, 1994), Chile (1976, 1981), Colombia (1982, 1998), Mexico (1981, 1994), Peru (1983), Israel (1977), Poland (1990), Turkey (1982, 2000), Hungary (1991, 2008), Czech Republic (1996), Slovak Republic (1998).
![]() |
(B.1) |
![]() |
(B.2) |
![]() |
(B.3) |
![]() |
(B.4) |
![]() |
(B.5) |
![]() |
(B.6) |
![]() |
(B.7) |
![]() |
(B.8) |
![]() |
(B.9) |
![]() |
(B.10) |
![]() |
(B.11) |
![]() |
(B.12) |
![]() |
(B.13) |
![]() |
(B.14) |
![]() |
(B.15) |
![]() |
(B.16) |
![]() |
(B.17) |
![]() |
(B.18) |
![]() |
(B.19) |
![]() |
(B.20) |
![]() |
(B.21) |
![]() |
(B.22) |
![]() |
(B.23) |
![]() |
(B.24) |
![]() |
(B.25) |
![]() |
(B.26) |
In the frictionless benchmark, equations (B.17)-(B.21) become irrelevant, and instead perfect arbitrage holds:
![]() |
(B.27) |
The model is solved by first appropriately detrending the variables that exhibit long-run growth, in order to obtain a stationary system. The steady state of that system characterizes the balanced growth path of the economy. Dynamics are obtained by computing a loglinear approximation around the balanced growth path.
Here I analyze the behavior of the model economy following two types of non-financial shocks that have been highlighted in the literature as important sources of business cycle fluctuations: an exogenous TFP shock, and a wage markup shock. To introduce the former, I modify the production function of intermediate goods firms as follows:
![]() |
(C.1) |
Above,
is an exogenous aggregate
TFP shock. To introduce the wage markup shock, the labor supply
equation is modified according to the following:
![]() |
(C.2) |
is a markup of the wage over the
household's marginal disutility of work. Several authors have
argued that countercyclical movements in the wage markup are an
important source of business fluctuations,38 possibly by
capturing in a reduced-form way the effects of nominal price and
wage rigidities or labor market frictions.
Figures 9 and 10 report the effects of a 5% decline in exogenous
TFP and a 5% increase in the wage markup, respectively. Both shocks
persist as an AR(1) with a 0.95 coefficient. The key point to note
is that both shocks induce only modest declines in the endogenous
component of TFP, and that the degree of amplification through the
credit market imperfection is also relatively small. The reason is
that unlike financial shocks, these two types of shocks induce
modest movements in the asset prices and
. As a consequence, both the
frictionless effect on firm creation is small (since the movement
in
is relatively small) and also the
degree of amplification due to financial frictions is small, since
the relatively modest movements in asset prices lead to only mild
fluctuations in banks' net worth. Further, in the case of wage
markup shocks, labor productivity does not decline - in fact it
slightly increases initially due to the sharp drop in employment.
As the figures illustrate, these types of disturbances are followed
by a recovery, which is driven by the unwinding of the shock. Thus,
the bottomline from Figures 9 and 10 is that the model is also
consistent with the evidence that especially deep and persistent
output losses are a phenomenon especially associated with
recessions involving financial crises, as Reinhart and Rogoff
(2009) and others have noted.
Figure 9: Responses to exogenous TFP shock. Time measured in years. All variables in log deviations from the balanced growth path.
Figure 10: Responses to wage markup shock. Time measured in years. All variables in log deviations from the balanced growth path.
1. I thank Ozge Akinci, Dario Caldara, Diego Comin, Jordi Galí, Matteo Iacoviello, Leyla Karakas, Robert Kollmann, John Leahy, Virgiliu Midrigan, Vivian Yue and seminar participants at various venues for very useful comments and discussions. I am especially indebted to Mark Gertler for his advice and guidance on this project. Financial support from Fundación Rafael del Pino is gratefully acknowledged. The views expressed in this paper are those of the author, and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. Return to text
2. Division of International Finance, Federal Reserve Board. E-mail: albert.queralto@frb.gov Return to text
3. Cerra and Saxena (2008) document little evidence of output recovery from financial crises in a large cross-section of countries. See also Reinhart and Reinhart (2010), Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) or Chapter 4 in International Monetary Fund (2009) and references therein. Return to text
4. At the end of section 2, I present some evidence suggesting a decline in firm creation during financial crises, by examining the behavior of time series data on patent and trademark applications during the 1997 crisis in South Korea. Return to text
5. See also Gertler and Kiyotaki (2010) or Gertler, Kiyotaki and Queralto (2012). Return to text
6. Since projects become successful through a simple time-invariant Poisson process, at any given date the value of a unit of the equity issued by an entrant entrepreneur must equal the franchise value of an entrepreneur that entered in the past but that has so far not been successful. Return to text
7. See also Comin, Gertler and Santacreu (2009), who estimate a version of the model in Comin and Gertler (2006), or Comin, Loayza, Pasha and Serven (2009) who propose a related framework for developing countries. Return to text
8. For instance, Gopinath and Neiman (2011), Benjamin and Meza (2009), Meza and Quintin (2007), Kehoe and Ruhl (2009), Pratap and Urrutia (2010) or Aoki, Benigno and Kiyotaki (2007). Return to text
9. The countries included are Indonesia, Malaysia, Phillipines, Korea, Thailand and Hong Kong, labelled "SEA-6". Area totals are computed by adding constant dollar, PPP-adjusted GDP for each of the countries. Labor productivity is defined as output per employed worker. See Appendix 1 for details on the data. Return to text
10. This is robust to different choices for the period used to compute the pre-crisis trend. Annualized growth of labor productivity for the period 1980-1996 is 4.06%, which is close to that for the entire pre-crisis sample (1960-1996), equal to 3.69%. Annual productivity growth for the post-crisis period of 1998-2007 is 3.61%, close to the figure for the pre-crisis sample. Return to text
11. That assumption is motivated by the outcome of standard augmented Dickey-Fuller tests, which for virtually all countries do not reject the null of a unit root in the levels of ouput, employment and productivity, but do reject the same null when applied to the first differences (at the 1-percent significance level). Return to text
12. See Appendix 1 for details on the data and the complete list of crises dates. Return to text
13. The latter is obtained by estimating a univariate model for the first difference of log output analogous to (1). This approach is more efficient than computing output as the sum of labor productivity and employment from (1) as it requires estimating a smaller number of parameters. Return to text
14. The results documented here contrast to some extent to those in Howard, Martin and Wilson (2011), who find that the recoveries from recessions associated with banking or financial crises are not unusually weak. The discrepancy is partly because they focus on growth following the recession trough, while the analysis above studies the impulse response to a banking crisis shock. Both sets of findings can be partly reconciled by the observation in Howard, Martin and Wilson (2011) that since banking and financial crises tend to be deep and long, and post-trough growth is about average, the output declines in these episodes are not made up quickly. Return to text
15. See Chapter 4 of International Monetary Fund (2009) for further evidence on persistent declines in TFP following financial crises. Return to text
16. Kortum and Lerner (2000) establish a positive effect on innovation of the availability of venture capital funding, and Kerr and Nanda (2009) show that US financial reforms enhanced the process of small firm entry. Return to text
17. See Hall (2002) and Hall and Lerner (2009) for surveys of work using data from OECD countries. Return to text
18. See Ayyagari et. al. (2007), and particularly Gorodnichenko and Schnitzer (2010), for studies using firm-level survey data from developing economies. Return to text
19. For example Meza and Quintin (2005) or Kehoe and Ruhl (2009). Return to text
20. In the latter case, the assumption is that it is still costly to introduce an innovation that is already in use in a more developed economy. See Mansfield, Schwartz and Wagner (1981) for evidence suggesting that "imitation" costs can indeed be substantial. Return to text
21. The expression for can be obtained by solving the cost minimization
problem of an entrepreneur
:
The marginal cost is then equal to the
multiplier associated with the constraint of the problem
above. Return to text
22. See Haltiwanger, Jarmin and Miranda (2012). Return to text
23. Kiyotaki and Moore (2012), Del Negro, Eggertsson, Ferrero and Kiyotaki (2010) and Jermann and Quadrini (2012) use a mechanism in this spirit to motivate a disruption in financial markets. Return to text
24. Here the underlying assumption is
that the entrepreneur, when successful, sells the idea to a
monopolist producer of intermediates, who then obtains the stream
of profits
from manufacturing and selling the new variety and therefore is
willing to pay
for the project. Return to text
25. Note that for the incentive
constraint to bind we must also have
: otherwise, the
value of an extra project is greater than the gain from diverting
the additional funds, so there is never an incentive to default. In
the equilibrium constructed below, for reasonable parameterizations
the constraint always binds along the balanced growth
path. Return to text
26. See Levine (1997, 2005) for surveys of evidence suggesting that financial development has a positive impact on long-run TFP and output growth. Return to text
27. As made clear below, adjustment costs are on net rather than gross investment, so that replacing worn-out capital does not involve adjustment costs. This formulation makes the capital utilization decision independent of the price of capital. Return to text
28. To elaborate on this, one could follow Gertler and Karadi (2011) and assume that firms need to obtain loans from banks to finance their purchases of physical capital. In this generalized model, banks would then make two types of loans: loans to existing firms to invest, and loans to entrepreneurs to create new firms. One could postulate different intensities of the financial friction for each type of activity, which could be captured by assuming that the fractions divertable are different for each of the two types of banks' assets. Return to text
29. Given the assumptions on
, to a first order the evolution
of capital along the balanced growth path is the usual
.
Return to text
30. Appendix C contains some additional model results regarding the effects of non-financial shocks. Return to text
31. While higher values of this parameter are frequently used in the literature, Mendoza and Yue (2012) argue that it is desirable to set this parameter at a relatively low value, since empirical estimates suggest that working capital is a small fraction of GDP. A working capital requirement of 0.35, together with a wage bill of two thirds of GDP, implies a ratio of working capital to GDP of around 23%. Return to text
32. MacGrattan and Prescott (2010), for example, estimate investment in technology capital at about 6 percent of GNP in the US. This is likely a lower bound on total entry costs, as not all firm creation is captured by R&D data. Return to text
33. See Kalemli-Ozcan, Sorensen and Yesiltas (2012) for cross-country evidence on bank leverage ratios. Return to text
34. Unanticipated increases in country interest rates, reflecting sudden stops in capital inflows, are considered an important force behind recent financial crises, and behind emerging market business cycles more generally - see for example Calvo (1998), Neumeyer and Perri (2005) or Uribe and Yue (2006). Return to text
35. As Figure 4 shows, the model understates the short-run declines following the crisis. These are likely related to phenomena like nominal price or wage rigidities which for simplicity have been ignored in the model, focusing instead on the novel aspects regarding persistence. It would be straightforward to extend the model along these dimensions. Return to text
36. See Bernanke (2012) or Section 3 of Bank of England (2012). Return to text
37. http://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/ Return to text
38. See Hall (1997), Galí, Gertler and López-Salido (2007) and Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan (2007). Return to text
This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text