The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2010-21 Screen Reader version

Structural Shocks and the Comovements
between Output and Interest Rates

Elmar Mertens*

Keywords: Interest rates, business cycles, structural VAR, bandpass filter, news shocks

Abstract:

Stylized facts on U.S. output and interest rates have so far proved hard to match with DSGE models. But model predictions hinge on the joint specification of economic structure and a set of driving processes. In a model, different shocks often induce different comovements, such that the overall pattern depends as much on the specified transmission mechanisms from shocks to outcomes, as well as on the composition of these driving processes. I estimate covariances between output, nominal and real interest rate conditional on several shocks, since such evidence has largely been lacking in previous discussions of the output-interest rate puzzle.

Conditional on shocks to neutral technology and monetary policy, the results square with simple models, like the standard RBC model or a textbook version of the New Keynesian model. In addition, news about future productivity help to explain the overall counter-cyclical behavior of the real rate.

A sub-sample analysis documents also interesting changes in these pattern. During the Great Inflation (1959-1979), permanent shocks to inflation accounted for the counter-cyclical behavior of the real rate and its inverted leading indicator property. Over the Great Moderation (1982-2006), neutral technology shocks were more dominant in explaining comovements between output and interest rates, and the real rate has been pro-cyclical.

JEL Classification: C32, E32 and E43.




I Introduction

Understanding the relationship between output and interest rates is important to macroeconomists and policymakers alike. But basic stylized facts on their comovements in U.S. data have proved difficult to match within a variety of simple DSGE models. For instance, KingWatson:1996 study three models: a real business cycle model, a sticky price model, and a portfolio adjustment cost model. They report that this battery of modern dynamic models fails to match the business cycle comovements of real and nominal interest rates with output:

While the models have diverse successes and failures, none can account for the fact that real and nominal interest rates are "inverted leading indicators" of real economic activity.1

Calling interest rates inverted leading indicators refers to their negative correlation with future output. These correlations are typically measured once the series have been passed through a business cycle filter.2 Amongst the diverse failures mentioned by KingWatson:1996, RBC models generate mostly a pro-cyclical real rate.

But in the data, the real rate is clearly counter-cyclical, it is negatively correlated with current output. As mentioned already, it is also a negative leading indicator. This commonly found pattern of correlation between bc-filtered output and short-term interest rates is depicted in Figure 1.3


Figure 1: Lead-lag Correlations for Output and Interest Rates

Figure 1: Lead-lag Correlations for Output and Interest Rates: please refer to the link below for figure data.

Note: \text{cor}(\tilde y_t, \tilde x_{t-k}) where \tilde y_t is bandpass-filtered per-capita output and \tilde x_t is bandpass-filtered nominal, respectively real rate. This ex-ante real rate is constructed from the VAR described in Section 3 as r_t=i_t-E_t\pi_{t+1}. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.U.S. data 1959-2006.

Figure 1 Data



What is the correct conclusion from a mismatch between implications from a dynamic model and stylized facts? Modern dynamic models always involve a joint specification of fundamental economic structure and driving processes. Model outcomes, such as the output-interest rate correlation, involve the compound effect of these two features. Yet, when "puzzling" findings are taken as evidence against a particular structural feature - such as sticky prices or portfolio adjustment costs - it is typically not acknowledged that the economy might alternatively be driven by different types of shocks that yield different effects within the given structure. Yet, more carefully, it is simply unclear whether dynamic models fail (or succeed) because of their transmission mechanisms or because of the nature of their driving forces.

To shed more light on this important issue, I provide empirical evidence about output-interest rate comovement conditional on various types of shocks: Neutral technology shocks, monetary shocks, investment specific shocks and news about future productivity and permanent inflation shocks. The first two of these also drive the models of KingWatson:1996. The decomposition is applied both to a continuous sample of postwar data ranging from 1959-2006 as well as as to two sub-samples, commonly associated with the Great Inflation (1959-1979) and the Great Moderation (1982-2006)4, extending the original dataset of KingWatson:1996 by more than ten years.5 There are striking results of my decomposition, which are reported in Section 4 using plots analogous to Figure 1:

Thus, for the full sample the "output-interest rate puzzle" is already defused by conditioning on two widely-studied shocks: Technology and monetary shocks, which counteract each other. Such opposing effects of shocks to "supply" and "demand" are a general theme in Keynesian models Benassy:1995. This result also carries over to the sub-sample analysis, which is motivated by growing evidence, documenting substantial changes in the behavior of macroeconomic data since the late 1970s and early 1980s.7 In particular, since the beginning of the 1980s--and at least until 2006--macroeconomic data has been characterized by a decrease in overall volatility, called the Great Moderation Bernanke:2004:GreatModeration, whereas the 1970s have been characterized by high and rising inflation rates, also known as the Great Inflation Sargent:1999:conquestbook,StockWatson:2007:inflationforecast.


Figure 2: Cyclical Behavior of Output and Interest Rates

Figure 2: Cyclical Behavior of Output and Interest Rates: please refer to the link below for figure data.

Note: Time series of bandpass-filtered output, nominal and real interest rates. The real rate is constructed from the VAR described in Section 3 as r_t=i_t-E_t\pi_{t+1}.

Figure 2 Data


To foreshadow some of the sub-sample results, consider the time series of bandpass-filtered output and interest rates shown in Figure 2. As can be seen from the figure's upper panel, the counter-cyclicality of the real rate is most prevalent over the Great Inflation, while it displays mostly positive comovements with output over the later part of the sample. The nominal rate behaves consistently pro-cyclical throughout the entire postwar period. What remains to be seen from the sub-sample decompositions presented in Section 4 is how these changes can mostly be attributed to changes in the relative importance of shocks, rather than substantial changes in the conditional comovements. This result is consistent with the study of SimsZha:2006:regimeswitching, who attribute changes in macroeconomic dynamics over the postwar period mostly to changes in the amplitudes of shocks rather than changes in their transmission mechanism.

The backbone of my calculations is a VAR for the joint process of (unfiltered) output, nominal and real interest rate. The VAR serves both as a platform for identifying the structural shocks and to model the bc-filtered covariances and correlations. The identified shocks are shocks to the unfiltered data. For instance, both technology shocks have permanent effects on output but they might also have important effects on economic fluctuations. The point of bc-filtered statistics is to judge models solely on those cyclical properties, not on their implications for growth Prescott:1986. In this vein, the VAR is used to trace out the effects of shocks to the bc-filtered components of output and interest rates. This is done analytically using a frequency domain representation for the VAR and the bc-filters. Rotemberg:1996, Gali:1999 and denHaan:2000:comovements stress the importance of looking at conditional comovements in the context of the comovements of output with either prices or hours. In applying this general idea to output and interest rates, my specific approach is motivated by the fact that the "puzzle" in this area is typically expressed in terms of bc-filtered data.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: Related literature is briefly discussed in Section 2. Section 3 lays out my VAR framework for the identification of shocks as well as for decomposing the filtered covariances. Results are presented in Sections 4. Concluding comments are given in Section 5.


III Empirical Methodology

The variables of interest for this paper are the logs of per-capita output11, the nominal as well as the real interest rate: Y_t = \begin{bmatrix}y_t & i_t & r_t \end{bmatrix}'. Let us call their bc-filtered component \tilde Y_t. The goal is to model and estimate how structural shocks induce comovements between the elements of \tilde Y_t.

The backbone of the calculations in this paper is a VAR. Since the real interest rate, Y_t is not fully observable, the VAR cannot be run directly over Y_t but rather over a vector of observables X_t. To sufficiently capture a wide-ranging set of structural shocks, the logs of the following eleven variables are included in X_t: the change in the relative price of investments, the growth rate in labor productivity, inflation, the ratios of consumption and investment to output, hours worked, wage markups, capacity utilization, the nominal interest rate, the velocity of money and the spread between nominal long- and short-term interest rates:
\begin{align} X_t &= \begin{bmatrix} \Delta p^I_t & \Delta a_t & \pi_t & c_t-y_t & x_t-y_t & l_t & \mu_t & u_t & i_t & v_t & i^L_t-i_t \end{bmatrix} \end{align}
where a_t = y_t-l_t. Apart from adding the long-term bond spread to the list of observables, this specification corresponds to the VAR used by ACEL. Details of the data construction are described in Section 4. The dynamics of X_t are captured by a p-th order VAR:12

\begin{displaymath} A(L) X_t = e_t = Q \, \varepsilon_t \end{displaymath} (1)

where A(L) = \sum_{k=0}^p A_k L^k , A_0 = I and E_{t-1} \varepsilon_t = 0, E_{t-1} \varepsilon_t \varepsilon_t' = I. The coefficients A_k and forecast errors e_t can be estimated using OLS. Identification of the structural shocks \varepsilon_t will be concerned with pinning down Q. Since fewer shocks are identified than the VAR has equations, there remains an unidentified component without structural interpretation.

The real rate is computed from the Fisher equation r_t = i_i - E_t\pi_{t+1} where inflation expectations are given by the VAR. So Y_t can be constructed from X_t by applying a linear filter:
\begin{align*} Y_t &= \begin{bmatrix}y_t \\ i_t \\ r_t \end{bmatrix} = H(L) X_t & \text{where} \quad H(L) &= \begin{bmatrix}(1-L)^{-1} h_{a} + h_l \\ h_i \\ h_i - h_\pi \left(\sum_{k=1}^p A_k L^{k-1} \right) \end{bmatrix}\end{align*}
and where h_{a}, h_{i} and h_{\pi} are selection vectors such that \Delta a_t=h_{a}X_t and so on.

The remainder of this section describes the following: First, how the structural shocks are identified (Section 3.1). This gives us Q and the conditional dynamics of the unfiltered variables can be computed from Y_t = H(L) A(L)^{-1} Q\, \varepsilon_t. Second, how to apply a bc-filter to the structural components of Y_t to obtain the decomposition of their auto-covariances (Section 3.2).


III.1 Identification of Structural Shocks

In order to identify a variety of structural shocks, which are commonly investigated by theoretical and empirical studies,13 this paper applies long-, medium- and short-run restrictions to the estimated VAR model. For the benchmark VAR, whose eleven variables are specified in (1), four structural shocks are identified: Investment-specific and neutral technology shocks, monetary policy shocks and news shocks about future productivity. When studying the sub-sample of the data associated with the Great Inflation (1959-1979), the VAR is respecified to allow for a common trend in inflation and nominal interest rates. For this model, innovations to this nominal trend are estimated as a fifth structural shock. Since all VAR models estimated here have more observables than identified shocks, there remains also an unidentified component, which is orthogonal to the identified shocks. These identification schemes are described below.

III.1.1 Investment-Specific and Neutral Technology Shocks

Two types of technology shocks are identified from long-run restrictions as it has been done before by Fisher:2006:invtech, ACEL, GaliGambetti:2008:aej. Investment-specific shocks are identified as the sole source of variations in the permanent component of the relative price of investments, p^I_t. Neutral technology shocks are identified as driving the permanent component of labor-productivity (output per hour) beyond what is explained by the investment-specific technology shocks.14 Since hours are assumed to be stationary, the identification scheme used here is actually equivalent to identifying (neutral) technology shocks from the permanent component of output as in ShapiroWatson:1988.15

The identifying restriction for both technology shocks imposes zero restrictions on A(1)^{-1}Q:16
\begin{align} A(1)^{-1}Q &= \begin{bmatrix}a_{11} & 0 & \ldots & \ldots & 0 \\ a_{21} & a_{22} & 0 & \ldots & 0 \\ \cdot &\cdot &\cdot &\cdot &\cdot \\ \vdots & & & & \vdots \\ \cdot &\cdot &\cdot &\cdot &\cdot \end{bmatrix} \end{align}
The shocks are signed by imposing a_{11} < 0 and a_{22} > 0; a_{21} is unrestricted.17 Together with the orthogonality of the structural shocks, this identifies the first two column of Q, which is then computed as in BlanchardQuah:1989.18 The standardized shocks to investment specific and neutral technology will be denoted \varepsilon_t^I and \varepsilon_t^a, respectively.


III.1.2 Monetary Policy Shocks

Shocks to monetary policy are defined as unexpected deviations from endogenous policy. As in CEE:HandbookMacro or RotembergWoodford:1997, the short-term interest rate is assumed to follow a linear policy rule

\begin{displaymath}i_t = \gamma_Z\, Z_t + \gamma_a \varepsilon_t^a + \gamma_I \varepsilon_t^I + \theta(L)\, X_{t-1} + \sigma_m \varepsilon^m_t\end{displaymath}

where Z_t is a vector of containing all observable variables X_t, which appear before i_t in (1),19 The standardized policy shock \varepsilon^m_t is assumed to be uncorrelated with the other variables in the policy rule. \varepsilon_t^m corresponds to the projection of the VAR's forecast error in the interest rate equation off the innovations of Z_t and off the two technology shocks. The velocity of money, v_t, and the interest rate spread, i^L_t-i_t, have been included in the VAR specification (1) to ensure that this nullspace has (at least) a rank of one.20 A previous working paper version of this paper Mertens:szg:montblanc used the shock series constructed by RomerRomer:2004 for each FOMC meeting from 1966-1996 and found results similar to those reported here.

III.1.3 News Shocks about Future Productivity

News shocks have lately attracted considerable interest in theoretical and empirical work, with at least parts of the literature suggesting that they might play an important role in business cycle fluctuations BeaudryPortier:2006:news:aer,SchmittGroheUribe:news:nber,JaimovichRebelo:2009:news:aer. BarskySims:News and Sims:News identify news shock as "the shock orthogonal to technology innovations that best explains future variation in technology". While they use direct data on total factor productivity, their definition is applied here to labor productivity, as measured by the second element in the vector of VAR observables defined in (1). In addition to requiring that news have no contemporaneous impact on labor productivity, news shocks are assumed to be orthogonal to the other shocks identified in this study. Computational details of the identification strategy are described in Appendix B

III.1.4 Nominal Trend Shocks

When estimating the VAR over the "Great Inflation" sample (1959-1979), nominal trend shocks are identified as well. As described in Section 4.3 below, for this sub-sample the VAR is adapted to allow for a common trend in inflation and nominal rates by replacing  \pi_t in (1) with \Delta\pi_t and i_t by i_t-\pi_t. The nominal trend shocks are then identified as the third element in the Blanchard-Quah factorization of the spectral density at frequency zero shown in (3).21 Such a trend could capture slow-moving fluctuations in policymakers' preferences for inflation--be these variations in their actual inflation target as in Ireland:2007:jmcb:InflationTarget or self-fullfiling market perceptions as in AlbanesiChariChristiano:2003 or Sargent:1999:conquestbook.


III.2 Decomposition of BC-Filtered Covariances

Summarizing the previous discussion, the impulse responses of the unfiltered variables in Y_t are given by H(L)A(L)^{-1}Q. These do not only trace out the business cycle responses of Y_t to the structural shocks \varepsilon_t, but also how the shocks induce growth as well as high-frequency variations. The motivation for bc-filtering is to focus only on the business cycle effects.22 Formally, it remains to apply a bc-filter and to decompose the filtered lead-lag covariances into the contributions of the structural shocks. The computations are straightforward to perform in the frequency domain and a brief overview is given in A.

Since the bc-filtered variables in \tilde Y_t are covariance-stationary, their lead-lag covariances exist and so does their spectrum. They can be computed from the VAR parameters and the filters H(L) and B(L). To ease notation, the impulse responses of Y after applying the bc-filter are written as \begin{equation*} \tilde C(L) \equiv B(L) H(L)\, A(L)^{-1} \, Q \end{equation*} so that the bc-filtered spectrum can be expressed as S_{\tilde Y}(\omega) = \tilde{C}(e^{-i\omega}) \, \tilde{C}(e^{-i\omega})'. For each frequency \omega, this is simply a product of complex-numbered matrices. The lead-lag covariance matrices of \tilde Y_t can be recovered from the spectrum in what is known as an inverse Fourier transformation
\begin{align} \Gamma_{\tilde Y}^k &\equiv E \tilde Y_t \tilde Y_{t-k} = \frac{1}{2\pi} \int_{-\pi}^\pi S_{\tilde Y}(\omega) \, e^{i\omega k} d\omega \end{align}

Since the structural shocks are orthogonal to each other, the decomposition of the covariances \Gamma_{\tilde Y}^k is straightforward. First, the spectrum is computed conditional on each shock. Then, the conditional lead-lag covariances follow from an inverse Fourier transformation, analogously to equation (4). To fix notation, the shocks are indexed by s and J_s is a square matrix, full of zeros except for a unit entry in its s'th diagonal element. The spectrum conditioned on shock s is  S_{\tilde Y \vert s}(\omega) = \tilde C(e^{-i\omega}) \; J_s \; \tilde C(e^{-i\omega})'. Since \sum_s J_s = I the conditional spectra add up to S_{\tilde Y }(\omega). This carries over to the coefficients \Gamma_{\tilde Y \vert s}^k \equiv E( \tilde Y_t \tilde Y_{t-k} \vert s) from the inverse Fourier transformation of S_{\tilde Y \vert s}(\omega) such that \sum_s \Gamma_{\tilde Y \vert s}^k = \Gamma_{\tilde Y}^k.



IV Decomposition Results

This section presents the results for the VAR described in the previous section. The VAR is estimated using quarterly data for the United States from 1959 to 2006. The construction of the data is described in C. The lag-length of each VAR used in this paper has been selected based on a comparison of information criteria, bootstrapped Portmanteau tests and the ability of the VAR to replicate bc-correlation computed from applying the Bandpass filter of BaxterKing:1999 directly to the data. Details can be found in the web-appendix for this paper, which has been attached at the end of this document.

To assess the statistical significance of the results, bootstrapped confidence intervals are computed for each shock. As discussed by SimsZha:1999:errorbands these are best interpreted as the posterior distributions from a Bayesian estimation with flat prior. The small sample adjustment of Kilian:1998 is used to handle the strong persistence of the VAR23. In a first round, the small sample bias of the VAR coefficients is estimated from 1,000 Monte Carlo draws. In the second round, the posterior distribution is constructed from 2,000 draws using the VAR adjusted for the small sample bias.

The web-appendix documents the robustness of some of the key results reported below, when applying the decomposition to a much smaller, trivariate VAR, using only data on output, inflation and the nominal interest rate:

IV.1 Full Sample

A result which consistently holds over the various samples considered here is that neutral technology shocks induce a strongly pro-cyclical real rate which is also a positive leading indicator for up to one year. For the full sample of data (1959-2006), this is depicted in the upper panel of Figure 3 which decomposes the filtered covariances between output and the real rate. Covariances add linearly, so they are a natural measure for the decomposition. The total covariances in Figure 3 are just a rescaling of the correlations reported in Figure 1 above. Figure 3 shows further that monetary shocks and news about future productivity induce negative covariances at leads between zero and up to two years. (To a much lesser, and largely insignificant extent, the same is true for investment specific technology shocks.) Turning to the nominal rate, all identified shocks contribute to its pro-cyclical and positively leading comovement with output. For brevity, these results are documented in a web-appendix, attached at the end of this document.


Figure 3A: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements Covariance Decomposition

Figure 3a: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements: please refer to the link below for figure data.

Figure 3A Data

Figure 3B: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements Conditional Correlations

Figure 3b: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1959-2006) computed from the VAR described in Section 3. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.
Figure 3B Data


When adding up the conditional covariances induced by the four structural shocks, there remains an unidentified component, inducing a counter-cyclical real rate, comoving negatively with output at leads and lags of up to a year. Whilst monetary policy and news shocks help to account for the counter-cyclical, negatively leading real rate, their strength does at best offset the pro-cyclical and positively leading behavior induced by technology shocks. Still, the results clearly demonstrate that conditional comovements are far from being as puzzling as suggested by KingWatson:1996.

The comovements induced by monetary policy and news shocks are also significant as can be seen from the lower panel of Figure 3. There is much larger uncertainty and small sample bias associated with the technology shocks, reflecting that they are identified from the more uncertain, long run behavior of the data CEV:2006:macroannual. The small bias becomes apparent when comparing the point estimates of the VAR (dashed line) with the mean of the bootstrapped small sample distribution.24 When considering shape and location of the bootstrapped distributions the conditional correlations for neutral technology shocks, it is however reassuring that they are tilted towards pro-cyclical point estimates.



Table 1: Variance Decomposition
Variables Mon. Policy Shock N-Tech Shock I-Tech Shock News Shock Nom. Trend Shock Rest Shock
Full Sample (1959-2006): Output 6.36 15.09 7.29 26.70   44.56
Full Sample (1959-2006): Nom. rate 11.24 11.04 3.72 43.91   30.09
Full Sample (1959-2006): Real rate 9.92 31.43 3.27 17.71   37.67
Full Sample (1959-2006): Inflation 4.30 2.60 13.24 29.06   50.80
Full Sample (1959-2006): Hours 5.11 16.39 6.93 31.16   40.40
Great Moderation (1982-2006): Output 0.88 56.50 5.39 15.23   22.00
Great Moderation (1982-2006): Nom. rate 3.31 14.24 2.18 55.83   24.45
Great Moderation (1982-2006): Real rate 3.54 16.85 6.84 43.56   29.21
Great Moderation (1982-2006): Inflation 0.52 18.22 1.43 14.81   65.02
Great Moderation (1982-2006): Hours 3.54 28.49 4.39 37.06   26.52
Great Inflation (1959-1979): Output 3.74 5.57 12.41 18.16 30.59 29.53
Great Inflation (1959-1979): Nom. rate 7.49 5.63 6.28 14.67 39.32 26.60
Great Inflation (1959-1979): Real rate 11.76 4.25 22.75 6.84 28.06 26.33
Great Inflation (1959-1979): Inflation 3.71 4.83 15.82 14.36 36.20 25.08
Great Inflation (1959-1979): Hours 4.74 2.73 11.58 22.67 30.83 27.44


Note: Variance decomposition for bandpass-filtered variables computed from the VARs described in Sections 3 (Full Sample and Great Moderation) and 4.3 (Great Inflation). "Mon. Policy" is the monetary policy shock, "N-Tech" and "I-Tech" refer to the neutral, respectively investment specific technology shocks and "News" refers to the news shocks about future productivity whose identification is described in Section 3.1. As described in Section 4.3, the VAR estimated for the Great Inflation allows for a common trend in inflation and real rates. Shocks to this trend are labeled "Nom. Trend" above.

Since covariances can be negative as well as positive, it is ambiguous to put a number like "percentage explained" on their decomposition. Table 1 reports variance shares for the bandpass-filtered fluctuations induced by each shocks for output, inflation, interest rates and hours. For the full sample of postwar data, the identified shocks account for about half the business cycle fluctuations in output, inflation and hours and up to two-thirds of the variations in nominal and real interest rates -- mostly due to neutral technology shocks and news about future productivity. In the sub-sample analysis discussed below, the unexplained share of variations will mostly drop below a third of the total.


Figure 4: Impulse Responses

Figure 4: Impulse Responses: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Estimates for U.S. data (1959-2006) from VAR, equation (1) described in Section 3. Responses of unfiltered variables to a one-standard deviation shock ( H(L)A(L)^{-1}Q). Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.Quarterly lags on the x-axis.
Figure 4 Data


So far the cyclical behavior of output and interest rates has been described in terms of bandpass-filtered covariances. Figure 4 documents the unfiltered impulse responses estimated for the full sample, and the results resonate very well with the filtered comovements discussed above. Because of the non-trivial effects of bc-filtering25 it is however not a foregone conclusion, that the picture emerging from the impulse responses should mirror the results for the bc-filtered comovements.

A monetary policy shocks increases the nominal rate for about a year, causing a prolonged contraction in output for up to four years as well as a reduction in inflation,26. In sum, the real rate rises while the economy contracts after a monetary shock. By construction, the neutral technology shock raises output permanently. As would be predicted by standard neoclassical growth models, e.g. such as the ones considered in KingWatson:1996, the technology induced growth in output is accompanied by an increase in the real rate for up to two years. Corroborating the results of Sims:News, output and hours drop in response to a news shock while the consumption output ratio increases.27 After an initial increase, the real rate drops as output recovers, in line with their counter-cyclical comovements documented for the business cycle frequencies in Figure 3. The full sample responses of real rate and output to investment specific shocks are largely insignificant.28



IV.2 Great Moderation

Reestimating the VAR described in Section 3 with data from the Great Moderation (1982-2006) yields considerably different results than what has been found above for the full sample of postwar data. However, just as in the full sample analysis, neutral technology shocks induce a pro-cyclical and positively leading real rate. Strikingly, the unconditional behavior of the real rate has been pro-cyclical and a positive leading indicator of output during the Great Moderation--just the opposite of what KingWatson:1996 have been puzzled about using data from 1959-1992.


Figure 5A: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Moderation) Covariance Decomposition

Figure 5a: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Moderation) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure 5A Data

Figure 5B: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Moderation) Conditional Correlations

Figure 5b: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Moderation) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1982-2006) computed from VAR described in Section 3. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.
Figure 5B Data


To a good extent the shift in the overall cyclicality of real rates can be attributed to an increase in the relative importance of neutral technology shocks as a source of business cycle fluctuations (see the middle panel of Table 1). Similarly, shocks to investment specific technology and monetary policy induce a pro-cyclical real rate, however without being quantitatively relevant.

The second factor behind the change in the unconditional comovements is a different behavior in the responses to news shocks, which are estimated to induce a pro-cyclical real rate over the Great Moderation. Similar to the full sample results, the unfiltered impulse responses to news shocks still display a drop in aggregate activity while the real rate increases on impact before it drops shortly thereafter. However, in subsequent periods the movements in the real rate follow more closely the subsequent recovery in aggregate activity, compared to the more prolonged drop of the real rate after a news shock in the full sample estimates shown in Figure 4. (The impulse responses for the sub-samples are reported in a web-appendix attached at the end of this document.) These subtle changes in the unfiltered responses cause a significant shift in the cyclical components of real rate and output as witnessed by the decomposition results shown in Figure 5.



IV.3 Great Inflation

A notable feature of the Great Inflation (1959-1979) is the highly persistent rise in inflation, consistent with a common stochastic trend in inflation and nominal interest rates.29 Accordingly, the VAR specification described in Section 3 has been adapted to allow for such a common trend, by replacing the inflation rate with the change in inflation, and by replacing the nominal interest rate with the spread between the nominal interest rate and the contemporaneous inflation rate. This allows to identify permanent shocks to the common trend in inflation and nominal interest rates as described in Section 3.1.

In addition, the velocity of money, capacity utilization and wage markups have been dropped from the VAR, reflecting their very persistent behavior over this limited sample.30 The vector of VAR observables used for the Great Inflation sample is thus
\begin{align*} X_t &= \begin{bmatrix} \Delta p^I_t & \Delta a_t & \Delta \pi_t & c_t-y_t & x_t-y_t & l_t & i_t -\pi_t & i^L_t-i_t \end{bmatrix} \end{align*}


Figure 6A: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Inflation) Covariance Decomposition

Figure 6a: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Inflation) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure 6A Data

Figure 6B: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Inflation) Covariance Correlations

Figure 6b: Output and Real Rates: Conditional Comovements (Great Inflation) Covariance Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data.

Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1959-1979) computed from VAR allowing for a common trend in inflation and nominal rates as described in Section 4.3. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.

Figure 6B Data


In general, the real rate decomposition for the Great Inflation resembles what has been found above for the full sample: The real rate has been pro-cyclical and a negative leading indicator, conditional on neutral technology shocks it has been pro-cyclical and positively leading, and vice versa when conditioning on monetary policy shocks. However, both shocks play quantitatively a smaller role in accounting for the comovements between output and the real rate over the Great Inflation. As before, part of the real rate's counter-cyclical behavior is accounted for by news shocks.


What is new, is that a further part of the hitherto unexplained, counter-cyclical remainder of the real rate, can now be attributed to permanent inflation shocks. In response to a permanent increase in inflation, output rises temporarily whilst nominal rates do not sufficiently increase with inflation, causing a drop in real rates. These result are consistent with the (unfiltered) impulse responses found by Ireland:2007:jmcb:InflationTarget when estimating a New-Keynesian DSGE model with random walk shocks to an exogenous inflation target.31 The web-appendix reports similar decomposition results when allowing for a nominal trend over the entire sample of postwar data.


V Conclusions

An economic model specifies restrictions on how the economy responds to exogenous forces. Data may not conform to these predictions, either because the specified responses are wrong, or because the set of forces considered in the model does not sufficiently capture those impinging on the real world (or both).32 KingWatson:1996 report an output-interest rate puzzle, because of discrepancies in the unconditional correlations of output and interest rates in U.S. data and a variety of calibrated models. But it appears in a different light, once the bc-statistics are conditioned on structural shocks. At the root of the "puzzle" are not so much the transmission mechanisms of their models, but rather the interaction of several shocks and their relative importance in different sub-samples of the data. Three points stand out:

Conditional on technology shocks, the comovements between output and real rate lines up fairly well with standard models, be it the standard RBC model or the technology channel of textbook New-Keynesian models as studied by Gali:NewPerspectives, walsh:tb2 or Woodford:tb. For all specifications considered, the contemporaneous correlation between (bc-filtered) real rate and output is positive. Likewise, the real rate is a positive leading indicator of output for almost one year. Unconditionally, the real rate is widely reported to be just the opposite - namely counter- or a-cyclical and a negative leading indicator. Attempts to match this with technology shocks appear to be going in the wrong direction.33

The overall behavior of the real rate must be the outcome of an interaction of several shocks. Indeed: When conditioning on monetary shocks, the real rate is counter-cyclical and a negative leading indicator as predicted by the simple New-Keynesian models. In addition, news about future productivity contribute to the counter-cyclical behavior of the real rate over the postwar period. Such opposing responses to "supply" and "demand" shocks are a general theme in Keynesian models Benassy:1995.

The comovements between output and the real rate differ when comparing the Great Inflation (1959-1979) with the Great Moderation (1982-2006). As in the full sample, the real rate has been counter-cyclical during the Great Inflation, mostly due to permanent inflation shocks. However, during the Great Moderation the real rate has been pro-cyclical, with technology shocks playing a more prominent role in accounting for its comovements with output.

Acknowledgments

This paper is based on the first chapter of my dissertation at the University of Lausanne. I would like to thank the members of my thesis committee Jean-Pierre Danthine (chair), Philippe Bacchetta, Robert G. King and Peter Kugler, the editor, two anonymous referees as well as V.V. Chari, Jordi Gali, Jean Imbs, Jinill Kim, Andrew Levin, David Lopez-Salido and seminar participants at the Board of Governors, the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, the University of Lausanne and the Swiss National Bank for their many helpful comments and suggestions. All remaining errors are of course mine. The main part of this paper has been written while working at Study Center Gerzensee and I would like to thank the Center for its generous support during my dissertation. This research has been carried out within the National Center of Competence in Research "Financial Valuation and Risk Management" (NCCR FINRISK). NCCR FINRISK is a research program supported by the Swiss National Science Foundation. Earlier drafts of this paper have also been circulated under the title "Puzzling Comovements between Output and Interest Rates? Multiple Shocks are the Answer."


I Applying BC-Filters to VAR Model

Conceptually, the analysis in this paper is applicable to a wide class of bc-filters, including the HP-Filter, the approximate bandpass filter of BaxterKing:1999 as well as the exact bandpass filter. A classic reference for the necessary tools is Priestley:1981:spectral, and similar techniques are employed by ACEL and CKM:BCA. For the computations it is key that the bc-filter can be written as a linear, two-sided, infinite horizon moving average whose coefficients sum to zero:34 \tilde Y_t \equiv B(L) Y_t where B(L) = \sum_{k=-\infty}^\infty B_k L^k and B(1) = 0.

The bandpass-filter is a such a symmetric moving average. It is explicitly defined in the frequency domain and most of my calculations are carried out in the frequency domain. For frequencies \omega\, \in \, [-\pi,\pi], evaluate the filter at the complex number e^{-i\omega} instead of the lag operator L. This is also known as the Fourier transform of the filter which represents it as a series of complex numbers (one for each frequency \omega). Requiring B(1) = 0 sets the zero-frequency component of the filtered time series to zero. For instance, the bandpass filter passes only cycles between two and a half and eight years. For monthly data, it is specified as follows:
\begin{align*} B(e^{-i\omega}) &= \begin{cases} 1 & \forall \, \vert\omega\vert \, \in \, \left[\frac{2 \pi}{8 \cdot 12},\frac{2 \pi}{2.5 \cdot 12}\right] \ 0 & \text{otherwise} \end{cases}\end{align*}

This VAR framework is also capable of handling unit roots in Y_t. By construction, H(L) and thus Y_t has a unit root such that H(1) is infinite. When computing the bc-filtered spectrum S_{\tilde Y }(\omega), B(1) = 0 takes precedence over this unit root. It is straightforward to check that H(e^{i\omega}) is well defined everywhere, except at frequency zero. So we can think of the nonstationary vector Y_t as having a pseudo-spectrum S_{Y}(\omega) = C(e^{-i\omega}) \, \,C(e^{-i\omega})' where C(L)=H(L)\, A(L)^{-1} \, Q and which exists for every frequency on the unit circle except zero.


II Identification of News Shocks

This section describes the identification of news shocks about future productivity. The identification strategy follows BarskySims:News and Sims:News who identify news shock as "the shock orthogonal to technology innovations that best explains future variation in technology". While they use direct data on total factor productivity, their definition is applied here to labor productivity, as measured by the second element in the VAR observables defined in (1). In addition to requiring that news have no contemporaneous impact on labor productivity, they are assumed to be orthogonal to the other shocks identified in this study (neutral and investment-specific technology shocks as well as monetary policy shocks.35 This orthogonality constraint can be easily accommodated by extending the method of Uhlig:2004:gnp as explained below.

For this method it is convenient to express the identification in terms of an orthonormal matrix \tilde Q and not in terms of the matrix of impact coefficients Q defined in equation (2) above. These two are related via the Cholesky decomposition of the VAR's forecast error variance, \Sigma=E e_t e_t': \Psi \equiv \chol{(\Sigma)} and \tilde Q \equiv \Psi^{-1} Q. By construction we have \tilde Q \tilde Q'=I. We seek the column of \tilde Q, associated with the news shock. Denoting this column as \tilde q, it solves the following variance maximization problem

\begin{displaymath} \max_{\tilde q} \quad h_a' \left( \sum_{k=0}^{50} C_k \Psi \tilde q \; \tilde q' \Psi' C_k' \right) h_a = \tilde q' \underbrace{\left(\sum_{k=0}^{50} C_k' \Psi' h_a' \; h_a \Psi C_k \right)}_{\equiv S} \tilde q \end{displaymath} (2)


\begin{displaymath} \text{subject to} \quad \tilde q' \tilde q = 1 \quad\text{and}\quad (\Psi^{-1} \bar Q)' \; \tilde q = 0 \end{displaymath} (3)

where C_k are the coefficients of the VAR's vector moving average representation, C(L) =A(L)^{-1}, h_a selects the growth rate of labor productivity from the VAR defined in (1). \bar Q is a matrix with four columns, containing the previously identified three columns of Q as well as a fourth column ensuring that news shocks have no contemporaneous effect on labor productivity. This fourth column contains the slopes from regression the VARs forecast errors on the projection of the innovation in labor productivity off the space of forecast errors spanned by the previously identified three shocks.36

Uhlig:2004:gnp solves the above problem without the orthogonality constraint (6). In this case the problem reduces to finding the largest eigenvector of the positive definite matrix S defined in (5) with \tilde q being its normalized eigenvector.

A previous working paper version of this paper Mertens:szg:montblanc has extended Uhlig's computations to handle the orthogonality constraint (6) as follows:37 Let B be an orthonormal basis for the nullspace of \Psi^{-1} \bar Q. The set of permissible vectors \tilde q is then  \{ \tilde q : \tilde q = B z \; \forall \; z \in \mathbb R^n\} where n is the dimension of the nullspace. Reparametrized in terms of z, the problem reduces to set z equal to the normalized eigenvector of of B' S B associated with its largest eigenvalue, denoted z^\ast. The sign of z^\ast (and thus the sign of the news shock) is determined by making it raise the consumption-output ratio on impact. It should be noted that this sign restriction only affects the sign of first moments (e.g. impulse responses), but not the sign of second moments (e.g. conditional covariances), which are at the heart of this paper.


III Data

The dataset used for this study has been collected from FRED38 and the Federal Reserve Board's G17 releases, which are publicly available. All data is quarterly and expressed in logs.39 Quantity variables have been converted to per-capita units using the Bureau Labor Statistics (BLS) measure of the civilian population over 16, interest rates and inflation rates have been annualized.

The data is largely identical to the time series used by ACEL for the sample 1959 to 2006. The only major difference is the use of NIPA data to construct the relative price of investments as in GaliGambetti:2008:aej and JustinianoPrimiceri:2008:TVP:aer, who construct the (log) relative price of investments as a weighted average of the (log) deflators of nondurables and services consumption minus the weighted average of the (log) deflators for investment and durable consumption, with the weights given by the relative (nominal) shares of each spending category,40 whereas ACEL use data constructed by Fisher:2006:invtech.

In detail, output (y_t) is measured by real GDP per-capita and inflation is measured by the log-difference in the CPI index. As in ACEL, the (log-) ratios of consumption and investment to output,  c_t-y_t and  x_t-y_t , are computed from nominal consumption and investments as well as nominal GDP.41 Hours per capita, l_t are calculated from the BLS measure of nonfarm business hours. Wage markups, \mu_t=y^\$_t-h_t-w^\$_t, are computed from the difference of nominal GDP less hours worked, less the BLS measure of nominal compensation per hour in the nonfarm business sector. Capacity utilization,  u_t , is measured for the manufacturing industry as reported by the Federal Reserve Board's G17 release.42 The quarterly average of nominal yields on three month Treasury Bills is used for the nominal short-term interest rate, i_t. The term spread of nominal interest rates is computed from the short-term interest rate and the 10-year Treasury constant maturity rate. The velocity of money, v_t=y^\$_t-m_t, is computed from the log-difference between nominal GDP and the money-at-zero-maturity measure computed by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Part : Web-Appendix

This is the web-appendix with supplementary details of the VAR lag-length selection (Section I), additional results for the large VARs, which are also used in the main paper (Section II) as well as results for smaller, trivariate VARs, which use only data on output, inflation and the nominal short-term interest rate (Section III).


I Lag-Length Selection

Specification of the VAR's lag-length is based on a comparison of information criteria, bootstrapped Portmanteau tests and the ability of the VAR to replicate bc-correlation computed from applying the Bandpass filter of BaxterKing:1999 directly to the data.43 Lag-Length selection tables and plots of the autocovariance functions for the VARs used in the main paper are presented below.



Table A.2: Lag-Length Selection Criteria for (Large VAR, Full Sample)
VAR: lag VAR: T-K VAR: llf/T VAR: max root Information Criteria: AIC Information Criteria: HQIC Information Criteria: SIC Portmanteau Tests for lags: 4 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 8 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 10 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 12 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 16 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 18 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 20
1 178 -11.05 0.9881 23.49 24.41 25.75^{\dagger} 688.21** 1297.69** 1580.05** 1867.45** 2387.65** 2659.14** 2916.48**
2 166 -10.25 0.9899 23.19 24.94 27.53 458.73** 1024.55** 1303.42** 1590.83** 2092.52** 2357.49** 2607.01**
3 154 -9.48 0.9905 22.93 25.54 29.37 281.81 830.16** 1092.80** 1374.52** 1863.32** 2133.33** 2374.64**
4 142 -8.87 0.9918 23.03 26.50 31.59 207.07 721.60 988.32^\ast 1254.53^\ast 1745.60^\ast 2009.33^\ast 2261.62^\ast
5 130 -8.24 0.9977 23.11 27.44 33.79 165.41 651.57 928.10 1200.37 1715.08^\ast 1977.33^\ast 2238.14^\ast
6 118 -7.55 1.0055 23.06 28.26 35.89 177.79 600.30 874.35 1157.61 1680.78 1948.61 2209.05
7 106 -6.90 1.0022 23.12 29.20 38.12 194.70 571.37 856.21 1119.12 1620.36 1874.85 2124.78
8 94 -6.16 0.9940 23.02 29.98 40.19 241.23 610.63 914.81 1179.07 1676.77 1915.52 2146.17
9 82 -5.21 1.0031 22.50 30.35 41.86 299.36 635.32 870.95 1140.96 1649.86 1896.51 2136.42
10 70 -3.97 0.9993 21.43 30.18 43.01 394.48 828.13 1032.45 1316.03 1802.79 2064.12 2307.86
12 46 -1.08 1.0030 18.51^{\dagger} 29.07 44.56 591.20 1122.76 1375.56 1631.89 2125.80 2390.27 2624.10

Note: Model chosen with lag-length 3. ^{\dagger} denotes minimum IC. Q-statistics for Portmanteau test. \ast denotes significance at the 10%, \ast\ast at the 5%, \ast\ast\ast at the 1% level of bootstrapped distribution (2000 draws). The column labeled T-K reports the degrees of freedom in each estimation, measured by the number of observations after dropping initial values (T) less the number of VAR coefficients to be estimated (K). \text{llf}/T reports the log-likelihood of each VAR scaled by the number of observations. AIC, HQIC and SIC denote the Akaike Information Criteria, Hannan-Quinn and Schwarz Information Criteria, respectively.


Figure A.7: BC-Moments: Filtered VAR versus Data (Large VAR, Full Sample)

Figure A.7: BC-Moments: Filtered VAR versus Data (Large VAR, Full Sample): please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, E{\tilde Y_t \tilde Y_{t-k}'}. The thick lines plot unconditional correlations computed from filtering the VAR-Spectrum. The thin lines are their analogues computed from filtering the data first and then taking sample correlations. Data for the ex-ante real rate is constructed from fitted values of the VAR for expected inflation. The exact bandpass was used for the VAR-based correlations, and the Baxter-King approximation for the data (BaxterKing:1999 recommend a lag truncation of 12 in quarterly data, with monthly data, 12\times 4=48 is used here). (The thin lines plot mostly underneath the thick ones). Correlations on upper diagonal.
Figure A.7 Data


Table A.3: Lag-Length Selection Criteria for (Large VAR, Great Moderation)
VAR: lag VAR: T-K VAR: llf/T VAR: max root Information Criteria: AIC Information Criteria: HQIC Information Criteria: SIC Portmanteau Tests for lags: 4 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 8 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 10 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 12 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 16 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 18 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 20

1

84 -7.58 0.9854 17.92 19.34^{\dagger} 21.44^{\dagger} 552.92** 1074.39^\ast 1306.45 1573.62 2029.30 2260.28 2471.24
2 72 -5.68 0.9787 16.68 19.43 23.48 427.30 933.69 1174.00 1464.41 1915.26 2126.01 2360.92
3 60 -4.07 1.0218 16.10 20.18 26.22 361.85 892.27 1140.30 1432.11 1945.63 2200.74 2468.93
4 48 -2.74 0.9788 16.12 21.56 29.60 348.57 851.17 1140.38 1431.08 1927.28 2176.18 2455.66
5 36 -0.17 0.9989 13.72 20.54 30.61 428.87 960.38 1281.58 1593.88 2148.05 2422.73 2723.53
6 24 2.43 1.0126 11.33^{\dagger} 19.53 31.66 634.86 1142.21 1417.21 1698.30 2253.84 2553.62 2845.22

Note: Model chosen with lag-length 2. \dagger denotes minimum IC. Q-statistics for Portmanteau test. \ast denotes significance at the 10%, \ast\ast at the 5%, \ast\ast\ast at the 1% level of bootstrapped distribution (2000 draws). The column labeled T-K reports the degrees of freedom in each estimation, measured by the number of observations after dropping initial values (T) less the number of VAR coefficients to be estimated (K). \text{llf}/T reports the log-likelihood of each VAR scaled by the number of observations. AIC, HQIC and SIC denote the Akaike Information Criteria, Hannan-Quinn and Schwarz Information Criteria, respectively.



Figure A.8: BC-Moments: Filtered VAR versus Data (Large VAR, Great Moderation)

Figure A.8: BC-Moments: Filtered VAR versus Data (Large VAR, Great Moderation): please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, E{\tilde Y_t \tilde Y_{t-k}'}. The thick lines plot unconditional correlations computed from filtering the VAR-Spectrum. The thin lines are their analogues computed from filtering the data first and then taking sample correlations. Data for the ex-ante real rate is constructed from fitted values of the VAR for expected inflation. The exact bandpass was used for the VAR-based correlations, and the Baxter-King approximation for the data (BaxterKing:1999 recommend a lag truncation of 12 in quarterly data, with monthly data, 12\times 4=48 is used here). (The thin lines plot mostly underneath the thick ones). Correlations on upper diagonal.
Figure A.8 Data



Table A.4: Lag-Length Selection Criteria for (Large VAR, Great Inflation)
VAR: lag VAR: T-K VAR: llf/T VAR: max root Information Criteria: AIC Information Criteria: HQIC Information Criteria: SIC Portmanteau Tests for lags: 4 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 8 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 10 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 12 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 16 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 18 Portmanteau Tests for lags: 20
1 71 -6.85 0.9847 15.51 16.37^{\dagger} 17.65^{\dagger} 271.51^\ast 538.25^\ast 654.48 796.43 1112.04^\ast 1254.15^\ast 1385.88^\ast
2 62 -6.08 0.9918 15.60 17.23 19.68 197.50 477.95 603.71 733.81 1012.81 1155.47 1285.33
3 53 -5.13 0.9869 15.39 17.80 21.43 148.08 428.01 551.13 677.43 944.63 1075.99 1204.03
4 44 -4.27 0.9767 15.40 18.61 23.44 136.64 413.19 538.61 669.48 941.23 1076.62 1205.73
5 35 -2.99 0.9981 14.60 18.62 24.66 146.57 423.39 555.64 691.19 970.83 1127.91 1288.69
6 26 -1.41 1.0138 13.28^{\dagger} 18.12 25.39 250.10 533.02 649.68 804.84 1097.23 1248.38 1414.31
                           
Note: Model chosen with lag-length 2. \dagger denotes minimum IC. Q-statistics for Portmanteau test. \ast denotes significance at the 10%, \ast\ast at the 5%, \ast\ast\ast at the 1% level of bootstrapped distribution (2000 draws). The column labeled T-K reports the degrees of freedom in each estimation, measured by the number of observations after dropping initial values (T) less the number of VAR coefficients to be estimated (K). \text{llf}/T reports the log-likelihood of each VAR scaled by the number of observations. AIC, HQIC and SIC denote the Akaike Information Criteria, Hannan-Quinn and Schwarz Information Criteria, respectively.


Figure A.9: BC-Moments: Filtered VAR versus Data (Large VAR, Great Inflation)

Figure A.9: BC-Moments: Filtered VAR versus Data (Large VAR, Great Inflation): please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, E{\tilde Y_t \tilde Y_{t-k}'}. The thick lines plot unconditional correlations computed from filtering the VAR-Spectrum. The thin lines are their analogues computed from filtering the data first and then taking sample correlations. Data for the ex-ante real rate is constructed from fitted values of the VAR for expected inflation. The exact bandpass was used for the VAR-based correlations, and the Baxter-King approximation for the data (BaxterKing:1999 recommend a lag truncation of 12 in quarterly data, with monthly data, 12\times 4=48 is used here). (The thin lines plot mostly underneath the thick ones). Correlations on upper diagonal.
Figure A.9 Data



II Additional Results for Large VARs

This section reports the following results:

Figure A.10: Impulse Responses (Large VAR, Great Moderation)

Figure A.10: Impulse Responses (Large VAR, Great Moderation): please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Estimates for U.S. data (1982-2006) from VAR, equation (1) in Section 3 of the main paper. Responses of unfiltered variables to a one-standard deviation shock ( H(L)A(L)^{-1}Q). Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.Quarterly lags on the x-axis.
Figure A.10 Data


Figure A.11: Impulse Responses (Large VAR, Great Inflation)

Figure A.11: Impulse Responses (Large VAR, Great Inflation): please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Estimates for U.S. data (1959-1979) from VAR with nominal trend, described in Section 4.3 of the main paper. Responses of unfiltered variables to a one-standard deviation shock ( H(L)A(L)^{-1}Q). Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.Quarterly lags on the x-axis.
Figure A.11 Data


Figure A.12A: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Full Sample) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.12a: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Full Sample) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.12A Data

Figure A.12B: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Full Sample) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.12b: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Full Sample) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1959-2006) computed from VAR described in Section 3 of the main paper. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.
Figure A.12B Data


Figure A.13A: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Moderation) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.13a: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Moderation) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.13A Data

Figure A.13B: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Moderation) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.13b: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Moderation) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1982-2006) computed from VAR described in Section 3 of the main paper. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.
Figure A.13B Data


Figure A.14A: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Inflation) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.14a: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Inflation) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.14A Data

Figure A.14B: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Inflation) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.14b: Output and Nominal Rates (Large VAR, Great Inflation) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1959-1979) computed from VAR allowing for a common trend in inflation and nominal rates as described in Section 4.3 of the main paper. Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.Quarterly lags on the x-axis.
Figure A.14B Data


Figure A.15: Impulse Responses (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend)

Figure A.15: Impulse Responses (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend): please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Estimates for U.S. data (1959-1979) from VAR with nominal trend. Responses of unfiltered variables to a one-standard deviation shock ( H(L)A(L)^{-1}Q). Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.Quarterly lags on the x-axis.
Figure A.15 Data


Figure A.16A: Output and Real Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.16a: Output and Real Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.16A Data


Figure A.16B: Output and Real Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.16b: Output and Real Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1982-2006) computed from VAR with nominal trend. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.
Figure A.16B Data


Figure A.17A: Output and Nominal Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.17a: Output and Nominal Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.17A Data


Figure A.17B: Output and Nominal Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.17b: Output and Nominal Rates (Full Sample w/Nominal Trend) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1982-2006) computed from VAR with nominal trend. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.
Figure A.17B Data



III Results for Small VARs

As a robustness check, this appendix reports decomposition results obtained from smaller, trivariate VARs, using the bare minimum of variables, which are needed to model output and the real interest rate: output growth, inflation and the nominal interest rate. As in the main paper, a common trend in inflation and nominal rate is allowed for when estimating the VAR for the Great Inflation. The trivariate VAR cannot be used to identify as many shocks as with the larger VAR used in the main paper. Attention is limited here to the identification of neutral technology shocks, as being the sole driver of the permanent component in output, as well as nominal trend shocks (when estimating the VAR for the Great Inflation). Confirming results from the main paper, the key findings from this exercise are that the real rate is pro-cyclical when conditioned on technology shocks, and counter-cyclical when conditioned on nominal trend shocks during the Great Inflation.

In the main paper, the permanent component of labor productivity is driven by neutral and investment-specific technology shocks. Since hours are assumed to be stationary, the permanent component of labor productivity is identical to the permanent component of output and the technology shocks identified here correspond to a mixture of both types of technology shocks identified in the main paper. In all three samples considered (Full, Great Moderation and Great Inflation), the real rate is pro-cyclical when conditioned on technology shocks.

For the VAR specification with stationary inflation, results are also reported for "Monetary Policy" which are simply identified by projecting the innovation of the nominal rate off the technology shocks and the innovation in inflation, which is unlikely to properly account for endogenous policy responses to variations in aggregate activity and inflation. Still, the results mirror the conditionally counter-cyclical behavior of the real rate reported in the main paper for the larger VARs.


Figure A.18A: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Full Sample) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.18a: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Full Sample) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.18A Data


Figure A.18B: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Full Sample) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.18b: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Full Sample) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1959-2006) computed from a trivariate VAR using output growth, inflation and the nominal interest rate. Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.Quarterly lags on the x-axis.
Figure A.18B Data


Figure A.19A: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Moderation) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.19a: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Moderation) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.19A Data


Figure A.19B: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Moderation) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.19b: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Moderation) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1982-2006) computed from a trivariate VAR using output growth, inflation and the nominal interest rate. Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.Quarterly lags on the x-axis.
Figure A.19B Data


Figure A.20A: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Inflation) Covariance Decomposition

Figure A.20a: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Inflation) Covariance Decomposition: please refer to the link below for figure data.
Figure A.20A Data


Figure A.20B: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Inflation) Conditional Correlations

Figure A.20b: Output and Real Rate decomposed with Small VAR (Great Inflation) Conditional Correlations: please refer to the link below for figure data. Note: Bandpass-filtered moments, \cov{(\tilde y_t, \tilde r_{t-k})}, for U.S. data (1959-1979) computed from trivariate VAR using output growth, the change inflation and the difference between the nominal interest rate and inflation, which allows for a common trend in inflation and the nominal rate. Quarterly lags on the x-axis.Lower panel: Bootstrapped standard-errors bands with Kilian:1998's small sample adjustment (1000 draws in first round, 2000 draws in second). Percentiles are shaded: 95% (light) and 68% (dark). The sold line is the mean of the bootstraps. The dashed line is the point estimate of the VAR.
Figure A.20B Data



Stefania Albanesi, V. V. Chari, and Lawrence J. Christiano.
Expectation traps and monetary policy.
The Review of Economic Studies, 70(4):715-741, October, 2003.
David Altig, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and Jesper Linde.
Firm-specific capital, nominal rigidities and the business cycle.
NBER Working Papers, 1103
4, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, January 2005.
Robert B. Barsky and Eric R. Sims.
News shocks.
NBER Working Papers, 1531
2, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, September 2009.
Marianne Baxter and Robert G. King.
Productive externalities and business cycles.
Discussion Paper 53, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics, 1991.
Marianne Baxter and Robert G. King.
Measuring business cycles: Approximate band-pass filters for economic time series.
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4):575-593, 1999.
Paul Beaudry and Alain Guay.
What do interest rates reveal about the functioning of real business cycle models?
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 20(9-10):, 1661
-1682, 1996.
Paul Beaudry and Franck Portier.
Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations.
The American Economic Review, 96(4):, 1293
-1307, September 2006.
Jean-Pascal Bénassy.
Money and wage contracts in an optimizing model of the business cycle.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 35(2):303-315, April, 1995.
Ben S. Bernanke.
The Great Moderation.
Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, Washington D.C., February, 2004.
Ben S Bernanke and Alan S Blinder.
The federal funds rate and the channels of monetary transmission.
The American Economic Review, 82(4):901-21, 1992.
Olivier Jean Blanchard and Danny Quah.
The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances.
The American Economic Review, 79(4):655-673, September, 1989.
Michele Boldrin, Lawrence J. Christiano, and D.M. Fisher.
Habit persistence, asset returns, and the business cycle.
The American Economic Review, 91(1):149-166, March, 2001.
Craig Burnside.
Detrending and business cycle facts: A comment.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 41(3):513-532, 1998.
John Y. Campbell and Robert J. Shiller.
Cointegration and tests of present value models.
The Journal of Political Economy, 95(5):, 1062
-1088, October 1987.
Fabio Canova.
Detrending and business cycle facts.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 41(3):475-512, 1998
a.
Fabio Canova.
Detrending and business cycle facts: A user's guide.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 41(3):533-540, 1998
b.
V. V. Chari, Patrick J. Kehoe, and Ellen R. McGrattan.
Business cycle accounting.
Econometrica, 75(3):781-836, May, 2007.
Lawrence J. Christiano and Martin Eichenbaum.
Current real-business cycle theories and aggregate labor-market fluctuations.
The American Economic Review, 82(3):430-450, June, 1992.
Lawrence J. Christiano and Robert J. Vigfusson.
Maximum likelihood in the frequency domain: the importance of time-to-plan.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(4):789-815, 2003.
Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans.
Monetary policy shocks: What have we learned and to what end?
In HandbookMacro, chapter 2.
Volume 1A.
Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and Robert Vigfusson.
What happens after a technology shock?
Working Paper, 9819
, NBER, July 2003.
Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, and Robert Vigfusson.
Assessing structural vars.
In Daron Acemoglu, Kenneth Rogoff, and Michael Woodford, editors, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 2006
, chapter 1. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2006.
Richard Clarida, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler.
Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(1):147-180, February, 2000.
Timothy Cogley and James M. Nason.
Effects of the hodrick-prescott filter on trend and difference stationary time series implications for business cycle research.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 19(1-2):253-278, 1995.
Timothy Cogley, Giorgio E. Primiceri, and Thomas J. Sargent.
Inflation-gap persistence in the U.S.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(1):43-69, January, 2010.
Wouter J. den Haan.
The comovement between output and prices.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(1):3-30, 2000.
Francis X Diebold, Lee E Ohanian, and Jeremy Berkowitz.
Dynamic equilibrium economies: A framework for comparing models and data.
Review of Economic Studies, 65(3):433-51, 1998.
Michael Dotsey, Carl Lantz, and Brian Scholl.
The behavior of the real rate of interest.
Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 35(2):91-110, February, 2003.
John T. Dunlop.
The movement of real and money wage rates.
The Economic Journal, 48(191):413-434, September, 1938.
Jonas D.M. Fisher.
The dynamic effects of neutral and investment specific technology shocks.
The Journal of Political Economy, 114(3):413-451, October, 2006.
Neville Francis and Valerie A. Ramey.
Measures of per capita hours and their implications for the technology-hours debate.
Working Paper, 1169
4, NBER, October 2005.
Neville R. Francis, Micheal T. Owyang, and Athena T. Theodorou.
The use of long-run restrictions for the identification of technology shocks.
The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 85(6):53-66, November/December, 2003.
Jeffrey C. Fuhrer and George R. Moore.
Monetary policy trade-offs and the correlation between nominal interest rates and real output.
The American Economic Review, 85(1):219-239, March, 1995.
Jordi Galì.
Technology, employment, and the business cycle: Do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?
The American Economic Review, 89(1):249-271, 1999.
Jordi Galì.
New perspectives on monetary policy, inflation, and the business cycle.
In Mathias Dewatripont, Lars Peter Hansen, and Stephen J. Turnovsky, editors, Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress of the Econometric Society, chapter 6, pages 151-197. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 2003.
Jordi Gali and Luca Gambetti.
On the sources of the Great Moderation.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1):26-57, January, 2009.
Jordi Galì and Pau Rabanal.
Technology shocks and aggregate fluctuations: How well does the RBC model fit postwar U.S. data?
NBER Working Paper, 1063
6, July 2004.
Bruce E. Hansen.
Rethinking the univariate approach to unit root testing: Using covariates to increase power.
Econometric Theory, 11(5):, 1148
-71, 1995.
Lars P. Hansen.
Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators.
Econometrica, 50(4):, 1029
-1054, July 1982.
A.C. Harvey and A. Jaeger.
Detrending, stylized facts and the business cycle.
Journal of Applied Econometrics, 8(3):231-47, 1993.
Robert J. Hodrick and Edward C. Prescott.
Postwar U.S. business cycles: An empirical investigation.
Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 29(1):1-16, February, 1997.
Peter N. Ireland.
Changes in the federal reserve's inflation target: Causes and consequences.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39(8):, 1851
-1882, December 2007.
Nir Jaimovich and Sergio Rebelo.
Can news about the future drive the business cycle?
The American Economic Review, 99(4):, 1097
-1118, September 2009.
Alejandro Justiniano and Giorgio E. Primiceri.
The time-varying volatility of macroeconomic fluctuations.
The American Economic Review, 98(3):604-41, June, 2008.
J. M. Keynes.
Relative movements of real wages and output.
The Economic Journal, 49(193):34-51, March, 1939.
Lutz Kilian.
Small-sample confidence intervals for impulse response functions.
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(2):218-230, May, 1998.
Robert G. King and Sergio T. Rebelo.
Low frequency filtering and real business cycles.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17(1-2):207-231, 1993.
Robert G. King and Mark W. Watson.
Money, prices, interest rates, and the business cycle.
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1):35-53, February, 1996.
Robert G. King, Charles I. Plosser, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson.
Stochastic trends and economic fluctuations.
The American Economic Review, 81(4):819-40, 1991.
Thomas A. Lubik and Frank Schorfheide.
Testing for indeterminacy: An application to U.S. monetary policy.
The American Economic Review, 94(1):190-217, March, 2004.
Elmar Mertens.
Puzzling comovements between output and interest rates? Multiple shocks are the answer.
Working Paper 05.05, Study Center Gerzensee, 2007.
Edward C. Prescott.
Theory ahead of business cycle measurement.
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 25:11-44, 1986.
M.B. Priestley.
Spectral Analysis and Time Series.
Probability and Mathematical Statistics. Elsevier Academic Press, Amsterdam, 1981.
Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer.
A new measure of monetary policy: Derivation and implications.
The American Economic Review, 94(4):, 1055
-1084, September 2004.
Julio J. Rotemberg.
Prices, output, and hours: An empirical analysis based on a sticky price model.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 37(3):505-533, 1996.
Julio J. Rotemberg and Michael Woodford.
An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy.
In Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg, editors, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1997
, pages 297-346. The MIT Press, Cambridge (MA), 1997.
Thomas J. Sargent.
The Conquest of American Inflation.
Princeton University Press, Princeton (NJ), 1999.
Thomas J. Sargent.
Macroeconomic Theory.
Economic Theory, Econometrics, and Mathematical Economics. Academic Press, New York, 2nd edition, 1987.
Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe and Martin Uribe.
What's news in business cycles.
NBER Working Papers, 1421
5, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, August 2008.
Matthew D. Shapiro and Mark W. Watson.
Sources of business cycle fluctuations.
In Stanley Fischer, editor, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1988
, pages 111-148. The MIT Press, Cambridge (MA), 1988.
Christopher A. Sims.
Interpreting the macroeconomic time series facts: The effects of monetary policy.
European Economic Review, 36(5):975-1000, , 1992.
Christopher A. Sims and Tao Zha.
Error bands for impulse responses.
Econometrica, 67(5):, 1113
-1156, 1999.
Christopher A. Sims and Tao Zha.
Were there regime switches in U.S. monetary policy?
The American Economic Review, 96(1):54-81, March, 2006.
Eric R. Sims.
Expectations driven business cycles: An empirical evaluation.
University of Notre Dame, mimeo, May, 2009.
Frank Smets and Rafael Wouters.
Shocks and frictions in U.S. business cycles: A bayesian DSGE approach.
The American Economic Review, 97(3):586-606, June, 2007.
James H. Stock and Mark W. Watson.
Why has U.S. inflation become harder to forecast?
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 39(S1):3-33, February, 2007.
James H. Stock and Mark W. Watson.
Business cycle fluctuations in U.S. macroeconomic time series.
In HandbookMacro, chapter 1.
Volume 1A.
Lorie Tarshis.
Changes in real and money wages.
The Economic Journal, 49(193):150-154, March, 1939.
John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, editors.
Handbook of Macroeconomics.
Number 15 in Handbooks in Economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, 1999.
Harald Uhlig.
What moves GNP?
Econometric Society, 2004
North American Winter Meetings, Econometric Society, August 2004.
Carl E. Walsh.
Monetary Theory and Policy.
The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 2nd edition edition, 2003.
Mark W Watson.
Measures of fit for calibrated models.
The Journal of Political Economy, 101(6):, 1011
-41, 1993.
Michael Woodford.
Interest and Prices.
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2003.



Footnotes

* The views in this paper do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve Board, or any other person in the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Open Market Committee. Any errors or omissions should be regarded as solely those of the author. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D.C. 20551. [email protected] Return to Text
1. [p.35]KingWatson:1996. The inverted leading indicator property has been the subject of various empirical studies, for example Sims:1992 and BernankeBlinder:1992. The expression "negative leading indicator" is synonymous. Return to Text
2. When it can be applied without confusion, I use the phrase "business cycle filter", or short "bc-filter", to describe the bandpass filters developed and applied in BaxterKing:1999 and StockWatson:HandbookMacro or the filter of ["HP"]HP:1997 since each eliminates nonstationary and other low frequency components from a time series. These filters differ mainly in that the typical bandpass filters eliminates not only cycles longer than 32 quarters but also those shorter than 6 quarters, while this latter high-frequency component is retained in the HP filter. Return to Text
3. This evidence is broadly in line with previous studies, see for instance the stylized facts collected by [Table 2]StockWatson:HandbookMacro for bandpass-filtered U.S. data. The facts are also significant as can be seen from the confidence intervals plotted in Panel b) of Figure 3. Return to Text
4. Neither sample includes more data for 2007 and later, since the disruptions in financial markets introduce numerous issues which are beyond the scope of this paper. Return to Text
5. KingWatson:1996 use data from 1959-1992. Return to Text
6. Money is neutral in RBC models, so they have not much to say here. Conditional on monetary shocks, output remains in steady state and correlations are zero. Return to Text
7. Amongst others, these changes have been attributed to differences in the conduct of monetary policy ClaridaGaliGertler:2000:mprules,LubikSchorfheide:2004:determinacy or variations in the nature of shocks hitting the economy SimsZha:2006:regimeswitching. Return to Text
8. BeaudryGuay:1996:realrates recognize the importance of conditioning on technology, too. They use cointegrating properties between output, consumption and investment derived by KPSW:1991, which are similar in spirit to my specification described in Section 3.1. When conditioning on these permanent shocks, they report negative correlations between output growth and the unfiltered real rate. Since growth rates amplify high-frequency fluctuations instead of focusing on business cycle characteristics, these results are not directly comparable to my approach and the puzzle framed by KingWatson:1996. Return to Text
9. Another line of attack in this area has been opened by DotseyLantzScholl:2003 by pointing out that the real rate evidence is sensitive to the choice of price deflator used for constructing the real rate. The widely reported counter-cyclicality of the real rate is particularly strong when deflating with the CPI which is used in this paper. It is a-cyclical or weakly pro-cyclical using the deflator for personal consumption expenditures (PCE). I can replicate this with my VAR, too. However, the basic results for conditional comovements between output and real rate remain valid. These alternative results for the PCE deflator are available from the author upon request. Return to Text
10. RotembergWoodford:1997 look only at output and the nominal rate. They use linear detrending instead of the stochastic procedures considered here. Still they find similar patterns of covariation and juxtapose their results to the puzzle posed by KingWatson:1996.FNrowodetrending Return to Text
11. All quantity variables shall be per-capita without further mention. Return to Text
12. For convenience, I dropped the constants such that X_t is mean zero. This is without loss of generality since estimating a VAR from demeaned data is equivalent to running a VAR with constants. Return to Text
13. See for example RotembergWoodford:1997, ACEL or SmetsWouters:2006:aer. Return to Text
14. This builds on the identification strategy of Gali:1999 who identified technology shocks as the sole driver of variations in the permanent component of labor productivity. Return to Text
15. This is easy to see from y_t = (y_t - l_t) + l_t where l_t are log hours (per capita). A stochastic trend in output will be identical to the one of labor productivity if l_t\sim I(0). While both the measurement of hours and the treatment of their stationarity have been found to be contentious issues, see for example FrancisRamey:2005:percapitameasure, CEV:2003 and GaliRabanal:2004, my results for bc-filtered comovements are robust to whether hours are included in levels or differences. The covariate-augmented Dickey-Fuller test of Hansen:1995:CADF also rejects the unit-root hypothesis for hours in my sample at the 1% level, when using the VAR data as covariates. Return to Text
16. Dots represent otherwise unrestricted numbers. Return to Text
17. The negative sign of a_{11} associates the investment specific shock with a permanent decrease in the relative price of investments. Return to Text
18. An alternative method, yielding the same results, would be the instrumental variables regressions of ShapiroWatson:1988, which are also used by ACEL. Return to Text
19. The vector X_t defined in (1) can thus be written as X_t=\begin{bmatrix}Z_t' & i_t & v_t & i^L_t-i_T \end{bmatrix}' and Z_t contains \Delta p^I_t, \Delta a_t ,  \pi_t ,  c_t-y_t ,  x_t-y_t , l_t,  \mu_t and  u_t . Return to Text
20. Absent an exact collinearity in the VAR residuals, the nullspace of \begin{bmatrix}Z_t' & \varepsilon_t^I & \varepsilon_t^a \end{bmatrix} is exactly of rank one. Return to Text
21. The identification of BlanchardQuah:1989 relies on a Choleski factorization of the spectral density of X_t at frequency zero. In (3), the two technology shocks are identified as the first two elements of this lower triangular factorization. This factorization allows both technology shocks to have permanent effects on the third VAR element -- inflation in this case -- as well. However, the long-run effects of both technology effects on inflation are insignificant. This has been verified by two types of statistical tests, both relying on instrumental variables regressions as in ShapiroWatson:1988. First, a Wald test fails to reject that both technology coefficients are jointly zero with a p-value of 67%, when estimating the unrestricted inflation equation as in BlanchardQuah:1989. Secondly, the inflation equation could also be estimated while imposing the over-identifying of zero long-run effects from technology shocks on inflation. The J-statistic of Hansen:1982 fails to reject the overidentifying restrictions with a p-value of 42%. To ensure that the covariance decompositions add up exactly, I employ the Blanchard-Quah factorization which is equivalent to the unrestricted inflation equation, for details on this equivalence see for example FrancisOwyangTheodorou:2003:longruntech. Return to Text
22. Business cycle filters have also been criticized for creating spurious cycles, originally by HarveyJaeger:1993:detrending and followed by CogleyNason:1995:filtering as well as in the discussion between Canova:1998:detrending Canova:1998:detrending,Canova:1998:userguide and Burnside:1998:comment_on_Canova. Whilst most of these papers focused on the HP filter, their analysis also applies to the bandpass filter. But the bc-filtered statistics employed here can be perfectly justified from the perspective of model evaluation in the frequency domain: The goal is not to match data and model over all spectral frequencies, but only over a subset which is associated with "business cycles". For the United States this is typically taken to be 6 to 32 quarters following the NBER definitions of Burns and Mitchell BaxterKing:1999,StockWatson:HandbookMacro. Formal concepts of model evaluation in this vein have been advanced by Watson:1993:MeasuresOfFit, DieboldOhanianBerkowitz:1998, as well as ChristianVigfussion:2003. Using the concept of the pseudo-spectrum this extends also to nonstationary variables, notwithstanding the analysis of HarveyJaeger:1993:detrending. Return to Text
23. Estimating the VAR over the full sample of postwar data, the largest root of the VAR amounts to 0.9905, see. When performing the bootstraps, a rejectance sampling is applied considering only stable VARs such that the long run restrictions can be applied. Return to Text
24. Unfortunately, the small sample adjustment used from Kilian:1998 is only partially successful here. The bootstraps are generating by treating the point estimates as true values. As a counterfactual exercise, the bootstraps have also been repeated, generating longer samples, with the result that the mean of the bootstrapped distributions becomes identical to the point estimates, just as suggested by large sample theory. Return to Text
25. For a critical discussion see for instance Canova:1998:detrending or KingRebelo:1993:filtering. Return to Text
26. The reduction in inflation follows after an initial upwards blip in the first period after the shocks, mirroring previous results of a price puzzle, which is for example evident in the estimates of ACEL as well. Return to Text
27. By construction, the response of output per hours (labor productivity) to a news shocks is zero. In addition, the sign of the news shock is identified such that "positive" news lift the consumption output ratio. The sign of the (identical) impact responses of output and hours is however unrestricted. Return to Text
28. After an initial increase in output, the estimated output responses to an investment specific shock displays even a prolonged, but temporary decline in real activity. The long-run effect of an investment specific shock on output is positive, but only at horizons beyond the ten years shown in Figure 4. Re-estimating separate impulse responses for the Great Moderation and the Great Inflation, the output responses to investment specific shocks are generally more positive, mirroring also the results reported by Fisher:2006:invtech who uses a similar sub-sample split. Return to Text
29. See for example CampbellShiller:1987, StockWatson:2007:inflationforecast or CogleyPrimiceriSargent:2010:inflationgap. Return to Text
30. Since there are less observables, and an additional long-run shock, one cannot impose as many zero restrictions on the impact responses to monetary policy as in the larger VAR specified in equation (1). As a compromise, the impact responses of the price of investments, as well as the ratios of consumption and investment to output have been left unrestricted (as before, the response of the term spread remained unrestricted as well). For the Great Inflation, the identified shocks may thus also reflect some of the systematic responses of monetary policy to aggregate activity. But the impulse responses reported in the web-appendix, still display the typically contractionary behavior of activity and inflation after a policy shocks. Return to Text
31. Ireland:2007:jmcb:InflationTarget uses data from 1959-2004. Return to Text
32. A case in point is how ChristianoEichenbaum:1992 add government spending shocks to RBC theory to resolve the dunlop38:_movem_real_money_wage_rates/tarshis39:_chang_real_money_wages/keynes39:_relat_movem_real_wages_output debate on the overall cyclicality of real wages, the issue is also summarized by [p. 487]Sargent:Macro:tb. In a similar vein, BaxterKing:1991:FedMin enrich the RBC model with demand shocks. Return to Text
33. See for instance the RBC modifications of BeaudryGuay:1996:realrates and BCF:2001 with habit preferences and frictions like capital accumulation and sectoral factor immobility. BeaudryGuay:1996:realrates recognize the importance of conditioning on technology. But since they use a quite different detrending method their results of a counter-cyclical real rate even after conditioning on technology are hard to compare with the results in this study. See also Footnote 0. Return to Text
34. Of course, some coefficients B_k can be zero. So B(L) could also be the first-difference filter. But meaningful bc-filters should also be symmetric, such that they have a zero phase shift. Otherwise, comovements over one frequency band, say business cycles, could be attributed by the filter to other frequencies, like growth. Return to Text
35. When applying the VAR decomposition to the Great Inflation as discussed in Section 4.3, the news shocks are also required to be orthogonal to the nominal trend shocks. Return to Text
36. The fourth column of \bar Q thus contains the slopes from regressing the forecast errors e_t onto the residual \tilde e^a_t in the regression e^a_t=\beta_1 \varepsilon^I_t +\beta_2 \varepsilon^a_t +\beta_3 \varepsilon^m_t + \tilde e^a_t. Return to Text
37. BarskySims:News proceed similarly. Return to Text
38. Federal Reserve Economic Data, maintained by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Return to Text
39. The nominal interest rate is computed from the log of the annualized gross interest rate. i_t = \log(1+I_t/100) where I_t is the annualized percentage rate quoted by FRED. Return to Text
40. The deflators are constructed as the ratios of nominal to real expenditure in each category, using the following formulas: PCDG/PCDGCC96 (durables), PCND/PCNDGC96 (nondurables), PCESV/PCESVC96 (services) and FPI/FPIC1 (investment). Return to Text
41. Consumption is the the sum of nondurables, services and government consumption. Investment is the sum of household consumption of durables and gross private domestic investment. Return to Text
42. An index of total capacity utilization is only available since 1967. Return to Text
43. Since the large sample distribution of the Portmanteau tests tend to over-reject for U.S. macro data, the critical values are bootstrapped as in ACEL. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text