The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2011-06 Screen Reader version

Are Household Surveys Like Tax Forms: Evidence from Income Underreporting of the Self-Employed*


Erik Hurst
University of Chicago
Geng Li
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Benjamin Pugsley
University of Chicago
December 2010



Keywords: Household surveys, self-employed, income underreporting, Engel Curve

Abstract:

There is a large literature showing that the self-employed underreport their income to tax authorities. In this paper, we quantify the extent to which the self-employed also systematically underreport their income in U.S. household surveys. To do so, we use the Engel curve describing the relationship between income and expenditures of wage and salary workers to infer the actual income, and thus the reporting gap, of the self-employed based on their reported expenditures. We find that the self-employed underreport their income by about 30 percent. This result is remarkably robust across data sources and alternative model specifications. Failing to account for such income underreporting leads to biased conclusions. We document this bias in existing measures of earnings differentials, wealth differentials, precautionary savings, lifecycle earnings profiles, and earnings variation across MSAs. Our results show that it is naive for researchers to take it for granted that individuals will provide unbiased information to household surveys given their demonstrated tendency of providing distorted reports of the same information to other administrative sources.


1. Introduction

There is an abundance of evidence that finds that some individuals systematically underreport their incomes to tax authorities.1 Likewise, there is a sizeable literature showing that some participants in experiments will distort their behavior as a reaction to being studied.2 There is also evidence that some other types of administrative data, including Vital Statistics data, are not immune to problems of misreporting.3 Collectively, previous research has shown that individuals tend to misreport their actual behavior to data collectors and administrative agencies when the incentives to do so are sufficiently large (e.g., to avoid tax payments) and/or the cost of doing so is small (e.g., changing their behavior in experimental settings).

An implicit assumption made in the majority of empirical work using household survey data, however, is that the data within the household surveys are immune to such systematic errors.4 In doing so, researchers are assuming that the problems that plague tax data, experimental data, and other types of administrative data do not plague household survey data. In this paper, we assess whether such an assumption is valid. Specifically, we address whether the self-employed, who have been shown to have misreported their income to tax authorities, have also misreported their income to household surveys.

A natural question that arises is why would someone purposefully misreport their earnings to household surveys? On the one hand, there is very little direct benefit for an individual to underreport their income to household surveys. Unlike when reporting to tax authorities, misreporting income to household surveys does not lessen the individual's tax burden. On the other hand, there is also essentially no penalty associated with misreporting income to household surveys.

However, individuals, particularly the self-employed, may perceive other indirect net benefits associated with underreporting their income to household surveys. First, households may feel compelled to provide consistent measures of their income if they believe that their reports to the household survey may not be completely confidential. Given that the self-employed already have strong incentives to misreport their income to tax authorities and given that they face no penalty for misreporting to household surveys, even a small probability of self-incrimination may be enough to distort their survey responses. Second, unlike wage and salary employees who receive W-2 forms, the self-employed have to expend effort to accurately account for their true income. If the self-employed have already supplied an inaccurate report to tax authorities, it may simply be easier to reuse this report when responding to household surveys instead of computing an accurate one. With no penalty compelling an accurate response but some potential net benefits from providing a distorted one, economic theory predicts that households, particularly those who already underreport their income to a tax authority, have incentives to also underreport their income to household surveys. The extent of underreporting of income to household surveys, therefore, becomes an empirical question.

We focus our attention on the self-employed for two reasons. First, as noted above, there is a large literature showing that this group consistently and substantially underreports their income to the tax authorities. For example, for tax years 1985, 1988, and 1992, IRS random audits suggest that roughly 30-35 percent of nonfarm proprietor income was underreported.5 Second, the self-employed are a non-trivial fraction of household survey participants, comprising between 10 and 14 percent of a sample of prime-age working males. Furthermore, self-employment propensities differ markedly over the lifecycle, across gender and race, and across geographic areas. Consequently, as we show below, the extent to which the self-employed underreport their income has important effects on many different types of questions addressed in empirical economics using household survey data.

Our goals in this paper are threefold. First, we will infer the extent to which the self-employed underreport income within U.S. household surveys. As far as we know, this is the first paper that attempts to do so. To estimate the extent of underreporting, we follow a procedure similar to the one set forth in Pissarides and Weber (1989). This procedure estimates the relationship between expenditures and income for wage and salary workers and uses the estimated coefficients from this relationship to predict the income of the self-employed based on their reported level of expenditures. Using data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, we find that the self-employed underreport their income to household surveys by about 30 percent. These magnitudes are nearly identical across both surveys for similarly defined specifications.

The above procedure makes a few key assumptions. First, it assumes no differential underreporting of expenditures by the self-employed relative to wage and salary workers. Second, it assumes that the conceptual measures of income in household surveys are similar between wage and salary workers and the self-employed. Finally, it assumes that the underlying relationship between income and expenditures, absent any underreporting, is similar between wage and salary workers and the self-employed. We test for the validity of all of these assumptions, as well as provide a variety of additional robustness specifications, in later sections.

The second goal of the paper is to assess whether the extent of the underreporting of income correlates with observable economic or demographic characteristics. Research using data from actual tax returns finds that individuals are more likely to underreport their income when marginal tax rates are higher (Clotfelter, 1983) and that the self-employed in professional industries are less likely to underreport their income relative to those in non-professional industries (Andreoni et al., 1998). Additionally, understanding both the extent of underreporting and whether the underreporting is correlated with observables is important for gauging when and how ignoring the underreporting could potentially bias different analyses. We do find greater estimated underreporting of income in the early part of our sample (prior to 1986) when marginal tax rates were higher than later parts of the sample. We also find evidence that the self-employed with advanced degrees tend to underreport their income to household surveys to a much less extent.

The third and final goal of the paper is to show several examples of how ignoring the underreporting of income by the self-employed can bias many different types of empirical analyses. Not surprisingly, we show that studies that focus on earnings or savings differences between the self-employed and wage and salary workers are severely biased if the underreporting of income by the self-employed is not accounted for. For example, Hamilton (2000) finds that the earnings of the self-employed are 35 percent lower than that of otherwise similar wage and salary workers. However, accounting for the underreporting of income by the self-employed would dramatically reduce these estimated earnings gaps. Adjusting for the misreporting of income by the self-employed also reduces the well documented estimated wealth gaps (conditional on earnings and demographics) between the self-employed and wage and salary workers by roughly one third.

Moreover, we show that not accounting for the underreporting of income by the self-employed can lead to quantitatively different results in a variety of other settings. For example, we show that estimated results on the importance of precautionary savings are 13 percent lower when we account the extent to which the self-employed underreport their income. Similarly, given that self-employment propensities differ over the lifecycle and across space, measures of lifecycle and spatial differences in earnings are sensitive to the extent of underreporting of income by the self-employed. For example, we find that roughly between 5 and 10 percent of the decline in earnings between the ages of 45 and 65 in both the Consumer Expenditure Survey and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics can be explained by the underreporting of income by the self-employed given that self employment propensities rise with age.

Our work in this paper complements two different literatures. First, there is an important existing literature that looks at reporting errors within household surveys.6 For example, Bound et al. (1994) explore the extent to which classical measurement error is important for reported wage and earnings data in household surveys. Fitzgerald et al. (1998) examine the nature of survey attrition from household survey panels. Haider and Solon (2006) show that deviations between current and permanent income change over the lifecycle. Meyer et al. (2009) document the extent to which transfer income is underreported in household surveys. Aguiar and Bils (2010) look at differences in the underreporting of expenditures by different groups within household surveys and shows that these differences have been changing over time. Deaton (1997) outlines many potential data problems that could arise when using household surveys for empirical analysis. Our work adds to this literature by identifying another channel for reporting errors. We find that a large group of individuals, the self-employed, systematically underreport their income to household surveys. Additionally, we show that the same misreporting issues that appear in non-survey settings may also pass through to household survey responses.

Second, our work complements the large existing literature that estimates the extent of underreporting of income by the self-employed using data on actual tax returns. Much of this work uses data from the Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program (TCMP) and the recent National Research Program (NRP). The TCMP and NRP are stratified random samples of U.S. individual federal income tax returns that are subject to thorough examination by experienced IRS tax examiners.7 A separate strand of research uses data from actual tax returns (as opposed to random audits) to assess the amount of underreporting of income. For example, Feldman and Slemrod (2007) use tax return data from 1999 to estimate the relationship between charitable giving and income for those with only wage and salary income. Again, our study differs from theirs in that we analyze the underreporting of income by the self-employed to household surveys as opposed to tax authorities.8

Collectively, our work shows that it is naive for researchers to assume that individuals who are willing to misconstrue their behavior to other types of data sources would otherwise automatically provide accurate responses when participating in household surveys. While the benefits of providing distorted information to household surveys are small, so are the costs of providing accurate information. Such potential biases need to be accounted for when analyzing data from household surveys.

2. Data Description: CE, PSID and CPS

We use two nationally representative household surveys, the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CE) and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), for the majority of our empirical analysis. To explore the quality of income data within both surveys, we also supplement our analysis with data from the Current Population Survey (CPS). In this section, we describe all three surveys and discuss our sample selection criteria. The Data Appendix provides background information on all three data sources.

2A. The CE Sample

To construct our sample, we start with the NBER CE extracts which pool together all the waves between 1980 and 2003.9 We restrict the sample to households who report expenditures in all four quarters of the survey and sum the four quarterly responses to calculate an annual expenditure measure. We further restrict the sample to include only the households that have a male head between the ages of 25 and 55 (inclusive), and where the head reports currently working at least 30 hours in an average week and has worked at least 40 weeks during the previous year.10 These latter restrictions ensure that we focus on prime age individuals who are working full time. To avoid some ambiguities in classifying households, we further exclude any households where the male head is a wage and salary worker but the spouse (if present) was self-employed.11 We also restrict the sample by excluding any household who reported a positive amount of farm income. We exclude farmers because the relationship between income and food expenditures may differ for individuals who grow some of their own food. Finally, we exclude households with zero or negative reported measures of household income or zero reported measures of household expenditures.

In the work below, we explore how the relationship between income and expenditures for wage and salary workers compares to the relationship between income and expenditures for the self-employed. Using the CE data, we define three measures of expenditures and two measures of income. The three expenditure measures we explore are: total food expenditures, total nondurable expenditures, and total expenditures. Total food expenditures include expenditures on food consumed at home as well as expenditures on food consumed away from home. Following Aguiar and Hurst (2009), we define nondurable expenditures to include spending on food, alcoholic beverages, tobacco, clothing and personal care, housing services, utilities, domestic care services, nondurable transportation, nondurable entertainment, and "other" nondurable expenditures. For a full definition of each of these categories, see the online robustness appendix that accompanies this paper.12 Our total expenditure measure is the CE's measure of total household outlays including spending on nondurables, durables, education, health care, and other household outlays.

Throughout the paper, we use two different measures of household income. Our first measure of household income sums all labor earnings from wage and salary employment plus all earnings generated by one's business. For business earnings, we include both the return to labor and the return to capital.13 When creating this income measure, we include both the earnings of the male heads and their spouses (if a spouse was present). Our second measure of household income is total family income, which includes all earnings, asset income, and transfer income received by the household. This latter measure is the total amount of pre-tax resources that flow into the household during a given year that can be allocated to consumption.

There are pros and cons for analyzing each of the income measures. According to standard theories of consumption, household expenditures are determined by the present value of household resources earned over their lifetime. In this sense, it is appropriate to account for the returns accrued to both labor and capital. Accounting for asset income is potentially even more important in our analysis given that it is well documented that the self-employed have much higher levels of assets than wage and salary workers that can be used to fund current expenditures.14 However, asset levels, and consequently asset income, are in part determined by household preferences, the same preferences that determine household consumption behavior. We show below that these potential endogeneity concerns have only a limited effect on our results. Indeed, our estimates of the underreporting of income by the self-employed are quantitatively similar regardless of the measure of income we use.

Finally, within the CE, all workers are asked to classify their primary employment type as either working for someone else in the private sector, working for the government, or being self-employed. We refer to households in the first two groups as being wage and salary workers. Our final sample includes 27,219 households, of which 2,508 are counted as self-employed.

2B. The PSID Sample

Compared with the CE, the PSID only collects limited information on household expenditures. Over the period of our analysis, the only expenditure category that is measured with any consistency is food expenditures. When computing PSID food expenditures, we sum together expenditures on food consumed at home with food consumed away from home. We define our two measures of household income in a way similar to how they are defined within the CE.

We use the PSID data from 1980 to 1997 except for the 1988 and 1989 waves, during which food expenditures were not collected. We do not use the PSID data after 1997 because the PSID started collecting data biennially after 1997; prior to 1997, we can match food expenditures and income more closely. During a given survey year, households are asked to report their current weekly or monthly food expenditures and they are asked to provide extensive information about the income earned during the previous calendar year. As a result, we match the income reported by the household during survey year t+1 with the food expenditures reported by the household during survey year t, which is the standard approach in the literature.

Similar to the CE sample construction discussed above, we restrict the PSID sample to those households with positive food expenditure during a given year, whose heads are male between the ages of 25 and 55 (inclusive), report working for pay, report working at least 30 hours in an average week, and report having worked at least 40 weeks during the year in which food expenditures are measured.15 As with the CE data, we also exclude households with zero or negative measures of household income.

Within the PSID, individuals are asked to report whether on their main job they "are self-employed" or "employed by someone else." Individuals can report being only employed by someone else, only self-employed, or both employed by someone else and self-employed. We define self-employed households as being a household where the male head reports being self-employed only. Wage and salary households are defined as ones where the male head reports only working for someone else. We exclude households who report being both self-employed and working for someone else from our analysis. Lastly, we exclude all households where the head is a wage and salary worker but the spouse (if present) was self-employed. None of our results are sensitive to whether these households are included or excluded from the analysis. Finally, after applying these restrictions, our sample has 33,339 households, 4,140 of which are counted as self-employed.

2C. The CPS Sample

To assess the quality of the income data within the CE and PSID, we supplement our analysis with data from the March Annual Supplement to the Current Population Survey (CPS). We define the CPS sample to match the PSID and CE samples.16 Over the sample period of 1980 to 2003 applying these restrictions yields a CPS sample of 511,306 households, with 70,423 of those classified as self-employed.

3. Income and Expenditure Differences between Wage Workers and the Self-Employed

In this section, we present descriptive results on how the income and expenditure of the self-employed compare with those of the wage and salary workers. We find that, conditional on demographics, the self-employed tend to have lower levels of income while simultaneously having greater expenditures. This key discovery motivates our formal empirical tests in the subsequent sections. In what follows, we first convert all income and expenditure measures to year 2000 dollars using the Consumer Price Index and express them in log levels. We compute all estimates using the sampling weights of the respective surveys.

Table 1 shows descriptive statistics separately for wage and salary workers and the self-employed within the CE, PSID, and CPS samples. The table is divided into three panels. In panels A and B, respectively, we show statistics of the log real household income and expenditure measures. The PSID only has limited expenditure information and the CPS has no information on expenditure. In panel C, we show other descriptive statistics. The table shows that the differences in the unconditional averages between wage and salary workers and the self-employed are mostly consistent across surveys. Noticeably, on average, the self-employed have a somewhat higher level of total family income relative to wage and salary workers, but even greater differences across each measure of expenditures. Across all surveys, the self-employed are older, more likely to be married, better educated, and on average work 11 to 12 percent more annual hours. The difference in hours worked is notable and we will return to it when we address whether the expenditure differences could be driven by varying tastes for leisure or difference in home production needs for the self-employed.

Next, we partial out all of the differences explained by the different demographic characteristics and examine the conditional differences in measures of income and expenditures. To find these conditional differences we approximate the conditional expectations of income and expenditures by estimating the regression models  \displaystyle \log y_{it} =\delta _{0}^{y} +\delta _{1}^{y} D_{it} +\Psi ^{y} \prime X_{it} +\mu _{t}^{y} +\eta _{it}^{y} 1) and  \displaystyle \log c_{it} =\delta _{0}^{c} +\delta _{1}^{c} D_{it} +\Psi ^{c} \prime X_{it} +\mu _{t}^{c} +\eta _{it}^{c} , 2) where  y_{it} and  c_{it} indicate real measures of income and expenditure of household  i in year  t,  D_{it} is a dummy variable indicating whether or not  i is self-employed in year  t,  X_{it} is a vector of demographic controls,  \mu_{t} is a time fixed effect, and the  \eta _{it} terms are orthogonal prediction errors. The vector of household controls include: a series of five-year age dummies, four dummies indicating the education of the household head (exactly high school, some college, exactly college, and more than college; less than high school was omitted), a dummy if the household head was black, a dummy if the household head was married, and a series of family size dummies.

The conditional differences in income and expenditure line up rather closely across the three surveys. Tables 2 and 3 show the estimated conditional differences in income and expenditure across each survey, respectively. As seen from Table 2, conditional on demographic differences, the self-employed typically have lower income than wage and salary workers. Controlling for the compositional differences between the groups makes the results closer across surveys than the unconditional differences shown in Table 1. For example, for labor earnings plus business income, the self-employed earn 10 percent and 11 percent less than their wage and salary worker counterparts with the same demographic characteristics, respectively, within the CE and CPS samples. The gaps are largely similar for total family income in that the self-employed earn 8 percent less and 7 percent less, respectively, within the CE and the CPS. However, total family income of the self-employed is on average 7 percent higher than the wage and salary workers in the PSID sample.

In Table 3, we show the estimates from equation (2). While the self-employed, all else equal, generally reported earning less income than wage and salary workers, they also reported spending substantially more than wage and salary workers. Specifically, within the CE, the conditional differences show that the self-employed reported spending roughly 12 percent more on food, 13 percent more on nondurable expenditures, and 16 percent more on total expenditure. The conditional expenditure differences are nearly identical between the PSID and CE.

These purely descriptive measures of income and expenditure reveal an inconsistency. Across alternative surveys, the self-employed simultaneously earn less and consume more than their wage and salary counterparts. To determine whether income underreporting by the self-employed can account for the inconsistency we further examine the relationship between income and expenditure in both groups.

4. Detecting the Underreporting of Income of the Self-Employed

In this section, we first examine, assuming income reports are accurate, how the relationship between income and expenditures differs across the self-employed and wage and salary workers. Previewing our results, we find a similar relationship for both the self-employed and wage and salary workers except for a gap in levels of predicted expenditures. Then, by relaxing the accurate reporting assumption, we propose a method closely related to Pissarides and Weber (1989) to use the vertical distances in the Engel curves to infer whether, and by how much, the self-employed underreport their income relative to wage and salary workers. We use this method in Section 5 to quantify the extent of underreporting by the self-employed. Later, in Section 6, we show that the method is robust to a number of alternative model specifications that take into account other possible explanations for the gap in predicted expenditures, conditional on income, between the two groups.

Our central theme in understanding the conditional structural relationship between income and expenditure is the log-linear Engel curve. We show in section 6 that this is an appropriate form for the expenditure categories we consider. Our first goal is to understand whether the self-employed and wage and salary workers have a substantially different relationship between income and expenditures. For each group,  k, where  k indicates either self-employed ( k=S) or wage and salary ( k=W), we separately estimate log-linear Engel curves using alternative measures of income and expenditures. Here we assume that each household  i has preferences that, when conditioned on our set of controls, are such that the intertemporal optimization, at least to a first order approximation, generates Engel curves of the following form:  \displaystyle \ln c_{ikt} =\alpha _{k} +\beta _{k} \ln y_{ikt}^{p} +\Theta _{k} \prime X_{ikt} +\mu _{kt} +\varepsilon _{ikt} (3) where  \beta _{k} is the income elasticity,  X_{ikt} is our previously defined vector of controls less any education dummies, and  \varepsilon _{ikt} represents the cumulative effects of other unobserved determinants of the household's consumption. Here, we assume that households are able to borrow and lend in asset markets so that it is the permanent component of income,  y_{ikt}^{p} , that determines the household's consumption, as is standard in modern theories of consumption.17

Estimating (3) directly is of course problematic because even if the household's annual income reported to the CE and PSID were completely accurate it would only by chance coincide with  y_{ikt}^{p} .18 The household's annual income represents both  y_{ikt}^{p} and a transitory component. Here we label the household's income report  y_{ikt}^{} and assume for the moment that all households accurately report their current income,  y_{ikt}^{} , which we model as  y_{ikt}^{} =y_{ikt}^{p} \exp \left(\Omega _{k} \prime X_{ikt} +\nu _{ikt} \right) so that:  \displaystyle \ln y_{ikt} ^{} =\ln y_{it}^{p} +\Omega _{k} \prime X_{ikt} +\nu _{ikt} , (4) where  \Omega _{k} \prime X_{ikt} and  \nu _{ikt} represent respectively the predictable and unpredictable components of transitory income. We assume that the unpredictable component,  \nu _{ikt} , is orthogonal to both the controls  X_{ikt} and any unobserved determinants of the household's consumption  \varepsilon _{ikt} (i.e.,  E[X_{ikt} \nu _{ikt} ]=0 and  E[\nu _{ikt} \varepsilon _{ikt} ]=0). Rewriting (3) in terms of (4) implies:  \displaystyle \ln c_{ikt} =\alpha _{k} +\beta _{k} \ln y_{ikt}^{} +\Psi _{k} \prime X_{ikt} +\xi _{ikt} , (5) where  \Psi _{k} =\Theta _{k} -\beta _{k} \Omega _{k} and  \xi _{ikt} =\varepsilon _{ikt} -\beta _{k} \nu _{ikt} . Even with accurate income reports, the transitory income introduces attenuation bias in our estimation of  \beta _{k} from (5) since, by construction,  E[\ln y_{ikt}^{} \xi _{ikt} ]\ne 0. To mitigate the effects of measurement error in our estimation of equation (5), we instrument for  y_{ikt}^{} using educational attainment dummies. As is the usual case, the education dummies are highly predictive of household reported annual income in the first stage regressions for each group.

Figures 1, 2, and 3 plot simple income-expenditure Engel curves estimated separately for the two groups. Figure 1 shows the results using CE data where nondurable expenditure is used as the expenditure measure. Figure 2 shows the results using CE data where food expenditure is the expenditure measure. Figure 3 shows the results using PSID data. In all three of these figures, the measure of income is household total family income. To facilitate comparison, for each figure, we show the predictive relationship between income and expenditure estimated by OLS and by 2SLS instrumenting for  \ln y_{ikt}^{p} .

A few things are of note of the estimated Engel curves shown in Figures 1-3.19 First, for all specifications, the Engel curve for the self-employed lies strictly above the Engel curve for the wage and salary workers over essentially the entire support of the data. In other words, for a given amount of income, the self-employed spend more on both food and total nondurable expenditures than the wage and salary workers. These are consistent with the descriptive results in Tables 1-3.

Second, for the IV specifications, the slopes of the Engel curves for the wage and salary workers are roughly similar to the slopes for the self-employed. For example, for food expenditures in the CE, the estimated income elasticities for the self-employed and for the wage and salary workers are 0.38 and 0.40, respectively (Figure 2). The comparable income elasticities using food expenditures in the PSID were 0.31 and 0.32, respectively (Figure 3). The differences in income elasticities were somewhat bigger using CE nondurable expenditure data (0.51 and 0.61, respectively). When we constrain the effect of covariates to be the same across groups, we find these slopes to be statistically indistinguishable across groups. Although we only show the figures using total family income as our income measure, the results are nearly identical if we use labor plus business income as our income measure.

Collectively, the above descriptive results suggest that if income reports in the surveys are accurate, the self-employed consume substantially more than wage and salary workers. We now outline a very simple model that relaxes the assumption of accurate reporting of income and allows us to estimate the magnitude of underreporting by the self-employed. In section 6, we discuss and rule out several alternative explanations for the excessive expenditures of the self-employed aside from underreporting. We begin with the same household preferences and market environment that generate the log-linear Engel curve described by (3). However, now we relax our earlier assumption of accurate income reporting to allow for the possibility of misreporting of income by the self-employed. For households of each type, we now assume their income reports to the household surveys are determined by  \displaystyle \ln y_{iWt} ^{} =\ln y_{iWt}^{p} +\Omega _{W} \prime X_{iWt} +\nu _{iWt} (6)  \displaystyle \ln y_{iSt} ^{} =\ln \kappa _{S} +\ln y_{iSt}^{p} +\Omega _{S} X_{iSt} +\nu _{iSt} (7) For each group, we assume that the observed income in any time period,  y_{ikt}^{} , is a noisy proxy of permanent income, where  \nu _{ikt} includes both any classical measurement error in the income report and the unpredictable component of transient variation around permanent income. As before, we assume that  \nu has mean zero and is orthogonal to the unobserved determinants of log expenditure,  \varepsilon .

Equations (6) and (7) embed two additional assumptions. First, we assume that self-employed households (k = S) systematically misreport their earnings by a factor,  \kappa _{S} . Although we do not impose that  \kappa _{S} \le 1, our empirical estimates below reveal that, in fact,  \kappa _{S} \le 1. For now, we assume that  \kappa _{S} is constant across self-employed households.20 Second, we assume that the wage and salary workers provide a systematically unbiased report of their income to household surveys i.e.,  \kappa _{W} =1. If wage and salary households also systematically misreport their income to household surveys,  \kappa _{S} would be an estimate of the differential systematic underreporting by the self-employed.

The goal of this section is to provide a method to estimate  \kappa _{S} . In order to do so, we also assume that the parameters of the two Engel curves are constant between the self-employed and the wage and salary workers. As seen in Figures 1-3, the slopes of the income-expenditure Engel curves do not differ dramatically between the two groups so this assumption is not at odds with the underlying data.21 Lastly, we assume that household expenditures are not differentially misreported between the two groups. This amounts to assuming that if the self-employed under or over report their expenditures systematically, the wage and salary workers under or over report their expenditures systematically to the same extent. We provide evidence for this assumption in Section 6.

Given these assumptions, we can estimate  \kappa _{S} via the following expression formed from combining (5) with (6) and (7):  \displaystyle \ln c_{ikt} =\alpha +\beta \log y_{ikt}^{} +\gamma D_{it}^{} +\Psi X_{ikt} +\mu _{t} +\xi _{ikt} , (8)

where  D is again a dummy variable indicating whether the household head is self-employed. As before  \Psi =\Theta -\beta \prime \Omega and the unobserved determinants are expressed as  \xi _{ikt} =\varepsilon _{ikt} -\beta \nu _{ikt} . The fraction of income reported by the self-employed,  \kappa _{S} , is identified as  \exp (\gamma /\beta ), and we form the estimate  \hat{\kappa }_{S} as  \exp (-\hat{\gamma }/\hat{\beta }) using the estimated coefficients from equation (8). We will often express our results in terms of the amount that the self-employed underreport their income to household surveys which can be defined as 1-  \hat{\kappa }_{S} . When estimating (8) using the pooled sample, we again instrument for reported  \ln y_{ikt}^{} using the set of education dummies. Estimating (8) with OLS would underestimate the income elasticity of consumption  \beta and hence overestimate  \kappa .

5. Estimating the Missing Income using Expenditures

In this section, we show the base results from estimating (8). Table 4 shows our estimates of both  \beta and  \gamma from equation (8) using different measures of expenditures separately for the CE and PSID samples. For comparison, we show both the OLS and IV results. Also, we separately show the results where we use total family income and household labor plus business income as our measure of household income. Remember that  \beta estimates the slope of the income-expenditure log-linear Engel curves pooled across the two groups while  \gamma estimates the average intercept gap between the log-linear Engel curves of the self-employed relative to the wage and salary workers. A positive value of  \gamma implies that, conditional on a given amount of reported income, expenditures for the self-employed are higher than the expenditures of the wage and salary workers.

As seen from Table 4, across all expenditure measures and across both surveys, estimates of  \gamma are positive and statistically different from zero (shown in panel B). For example, using the CE sample and using the nondurable expenditure measure, we estimate that the self-employed spend 18 percent more than wage and salary workers with similar reported income. The estimates of  \gamma are roughly similar whether or not we instrument for annual income. Moreover, the estimates are similar regardless of whether we use total family income or labor plus business income as our income measure. Finally, the estimates of  \gamma for food expenditures are similar between the PSID and CE samples. For example, using the IV specification and focusing on labor plus business income, the estimate of  \gamma in the CE sample was 0.15 (standard error = 0.01) while the estimate of  \gamma in the PSID was 0.11 (standard error = 0.01).

The estimates of  \beta from (8) are shown in Panel A of Table 4 and are similar to those shown in Figures 1-3. Not surprisingly, given the existence of transitory variation around permanent income, in addition to measurement error in annual income, the estimates of  \beta are sensitive to whether we estimate (7) via OLS or IV. The fact that current reported income is a noisy proxy of permanent income attenuates the estimated expenditure income elasticities. In all cases, the IV estimates of  \beta are higher than the OLS estimates of  \beta . The IV estimates of the income elasticities for food expenditures range from 0.31 to 0.40 across the various samples and specifications. The IV estimates of the income elasticities for total nondurables and total expenditures are much higher. These results are consistent with many empirical studies which find that food is a relative necessity compared to other consumption categories.

Table 5 presents the central results of the paper, quantifying the self-employed's missing income. In this table, we uses the estimates of  \beta and  \gamma shown in Table 4 to construct estimates of (1- \kappa  {}_{s})-the estimated underreporting of income by the self-employed relative to wage and salary workers. We estimate this reporting gap as  (1-\hat{\kappa }_{s} )=1-\exp \left(\frac{-\hat{\gamma }}{\hat{\beta }} \right)and compute standard errors using standard asymptotic approximations. In this table, we only show the results from the IV regressions, which are the appropriate way to estimate (8) given the measurement error in income.

The results of Table 5 are striking. The estimated amount of underreporting is similar across the two surveys and are very similar regardless of the measures of income and expenditures used in the estimation. For example, the estimated underreporting using total family income and food expenditures are 31.7 percent in the CE and 30.1 percent in the PSID. Using labor plus business income and food expenditures yields estimates of 33.5 and 34.9 percent, respectively, in the CE and PSID. The estimated underreporting is slightly smaller using broader measures of consumption. For example, the estimated underreporting ranges from 25-28 percent using nondurable expenditures and total expenditures, across the various specifications. {}^{ } All results are statistically significant at the one percent level.

The results in this section suggest that household surveys are like tax forms in that households with an incentive to misreport their income to the tax authorities also misreport their income to household surveys. The results also suggest more broadly that household surveys are not immune to the potential problems of mis-measurement that plague other types of data.

6. Examining the Validity of Key Identification Assumptions

In this section, we address the plausibility of our identifying assumptions, placing particular emphasis on underreporting as the first order source of differences in predicted expenditure. First, our model imposes, conditional on our controls, a log-linear Engel curve. Previous studies, including Pissarides and Weber (1989), have found this to be a reasonable approximation. Besides analytic convenience, we consider several alternative models incorporating higher order terms; in each of these models we fail to find consistent evidence that the higher order terms are either significant or quantitatively important. Despite potential nonlinearities for specific expenditure categories such as alcohol or clothing, we find the log-linear form fits the data well for food, nondurable, and total expenditures. Second, our base results constrain the effect of controls and the income elasticity to be identical across groups. In all samples, as noted above, we fail to reject equality of the covariate coefficient vector. We do find some weak evidence that the income elasticity of the self-employed is lower than wage and salary households. However, the difference is inconsistent across samples and small in magnitude.

Given our procedure, our estimate of underreporting remains the residual explanation for the difference in predicted expenditure across groups conditional on income. There are other potential explanations for this expenditure gap even if income were accurately reported. In the remainder of this section we address several alternative explanations and show that our estimates are robust to taking these alternative explanations into account.

6A. Potential Systematic Differences in the Reporting of Expenditures

The fact that some business expenditures can substitute for personal expenditures may undermine the validity of the assumption of no differential mis-reporting of household expenditures between the two groups. For example, the self-employed sometimes purchase vehicles for their business. In doing so, they may treat gasoline and maintenance associated with the vehicle as business expenses. Yet, if the self-employed also use that vehicle for personal use, it is possible that some of the expenses they attribute to the business actually should instead be recorded as household expenditures. The story could also hold in reverse. The self-employed could conceivably report all outlays on vehicle expenses as being personal consumption even though some of the expenses are for their business. Given this, the self-employed could be underreporting or overreporting their personal expenditures to household surveys.22

To test for the importance of this, we perform two separate exercises. First, using the CE sample, we re-estimate the amount of underreporting of income using a variety of expenditure subcategories in order to explore the robustness of the results across the subcategories. Then, we can verify whether expenditure subcategories that are likely not to be subject to the confounding of business and personal use yield different estimated underreporting gaps than categories where the potential substitution for business and personal use is larger. For example, while vehicle expenditures may be easily attributed to the business even if they were for personal use, it is less likely that an individual would attribute the spending on home utilities as being a business expense. To implement this procedure, we re-estimate (7) using the log of spending on different expenditure sub-categories as the dependent variable using the CE data. Focusing on utilities as a measure of expenditures yields an underreporting of income by the self-employed of roughly 30 percent, nearly identical to the food expenditure, nondurable expenditure, and total expenditure results.

Across all the subcategories we explored, nearly all of them yielded an estimated underreporting gap in the 20 to 30 percent range.23 One notable exception, however, is nondurable transportation expenditures (which includes spending on vehicle gasoline, car maintenance, parking fees, tolls, etc.). Using this subcategory, we estimate underreporting of income by the self-employed close to zero. This is consistent with anecdotes that the self-employed frequently classify a large amount of their vehicle expenditures associated with personal use as business expenses. Overall, however, we find no evidence that the results across any of the other expenditure categories differ in any substantive way from our main results even though the substitutability with business expenditures differs markedly across the categories.

The results above, however, raise a different question. Is it possible that the self-employed systematically misreport their expenditures on all categories? Although such a scenario is unlikely, it is possible for us to test this potential hypothesis directly. To do so, we estimate the relationship between the share of spending on a given category and total expenditures based on Deaton and Muellbauer's (1982) Almost Ideal Demand System. Our procedure tests for whether budget shares on necessary goods and luxury goods, conditional on total expenditure, differ between the self employed and wage and salary workers. If a group misreports their expenditures by a constant amount on all expenditure categories relative to another group, the estimated budget shares for luxury goods and necessity goods, conditional on total expenditures, will systematically differ between the two groups.

For example, consider a consumption category with an income elasticity significantly less than one (e.g., food expenditures at home). For such a consumption category, a group of households that systematically underreports (overreports) their expenditures by a constant amount relative to another group will have budget shares conditional on total expenditures that are lower (higher) than the other group. We repeat such an analysis for a variety of categories where the income elasticities are greater and less than one. Using this type of procedure, we fail to find any systematic misreporting of expenditures by the self employed relative to wage and salary workers.24 We also show these results in detail in the online robustness appendix. The combined results of our two robustness exercises make us confident that any misreporting of expenditures is not biasing our results in any meaningful way.

6B. Potential Other Reasons That Could Cause Systematic Differences in the Income- Expenditure Relationships.

In this subsection, we assess whether differences in the income-expenditure relationships between wage and salary workers and the self-employed are driven by factors other than the systematic underreporting of income by the self-employed. In particular, we examine 1) differences in desired expenditures due to differences in hours worked, 2) differences in desired saving propensities between the two groups, and 3) differences in the potential conceptual measures of income between the two groups.

Difference in Expenditures Due To Differences in Hours Worked

As documented in section 2, the self-employed do systematically work more hours than wage and salary workers, even within the restricted sample of individuals working full time. Depending on the sample, these differences in work hours average between 10 and 15 percent. Theory suggests that individuals who work more may engage in less home production compared to individuals who work less (Becker (1965) and Ghez and Becker (1975)), or that increased work hours may raise the marginal utility of consumption.25 Empirically, Aguiar and Hurst (2005, 2007, and 2009) show that a given consumption bundle produced with more market inputs, as opposed to time inputs, is indeed more expensive. To the extent that the self-employed engage in less home production, because they are allocating more hours to market work, expenditures may be higher simply because they are spending more for an equivalent consumption bundle.

To control for this potential difference in the market cost of the consumption bundle, we follow a procedure similar to that of Blundell, Browning, and Meghir (1994) and additionaly control for log work hours. We re-estimate (8) with a log work hours control using both total family income and labor plus business income to compute new estimates of  1-\hat{\kappa }, shown in columns (1) and (2), respectively, of Table 6. For each expenditure measure, the results are almost identical to the original estimation, making increased work hours an implausible explanation for the expenditure gaps.

Differences in Saving Propensities

A potentially more significant problem is the extent to which the self-employed have different saving incentives relative to wage and salary workers. If the self-employed face greater income risk, they may want to accumulate more wealth to insure themselves against potential shocks. Likewise, if the self-employed face more binding liquidity constraints, they may accumulate more wealth to overcome such constraints. Finally, if the self-employed receive fewer fringe benefits, they may have to save more for health shocks and for retirement. All of these factors will shift the income-expenditure relationship downward (as a result of the higher saving propensities), causing us to under-estimate the extent to which the self-employed underreport their income.

However, the self-employed may also have a higher tolerance for risk (Barsky et al., 1997). As a result, for a given amount of risk, the self-employed may have a lower desire to accumulate precautionary savings. The differences in risk preferences could result in less desired saving by the self-employed and, as a result, cause us to overstate the extent to which the self-employed underreport their income. A similar result would occur if the self-employed systematically expected higher income in the future.

We can assess whether such possibilities affect the expenditure gap by segmenting the sample by age. High expected future income, binding liquidity constraints, and the existence of labor income risk are much more important for young households relative to older households (Gourinchas and Parker, 2000). In columns (3) and (4) of Table 6 we re-estimate (8) on a sample of young and older households, respectively. We define younger households as households between the ages of 25 and 40 and define older households as households between the ages of 40 and 55. Across expenditure measures, the estimated amount of underreporting is very similar between old and young households. These results suggest that differences in future income expectations, differences in binding liquidity constraints, and differences in precautionary motives are likely not the primary driver of our results.26

As an additional robustness exercise, we examined the extent of underreporting by the level of household wealth. To do this, we augmented (8) to include dummies for whether the household was in the second wealth quartile, the third wealth quartile or the top wealth quartile along with our entrepreneurship dummy interacted separately with all of the wealth quartiles. The goals of this specification are twofold. First, we ask the general question as to whether differences in household wealth (which could result from past savings behavior) could explain the estimated underreporting by the self-employed. Second, the specification allows us to assess whether the extent to which households underreport differs by wealth quartiles. The specification, available in the robustness appendix, shows that the underreporting estimates do not differ significantly across the wealth quartiles.

Different Conceptual Measures of Income

Finally, we assess whether the above underreporting results could be driven by differences in the conceptual measures of income between the two types of individuals. We usually define income (net of taxes and transfers) as the economic resources that can be allocated to either consumption or savings. For wage and salary workers the distinction is usually straightforward. Any dollar earned is given to the household and then the household decides how much to allocate to consumption and savings.27 For the self-employed, however, this distinction may be more complex. The self-employed usually make a decision of how much of the return of the business to reinvest in the business (in the form of retained earnings) jointly with the decision of how much money they should withdrawal from the business in the form of self-employed business income. The true income measure of the self-employed should be any resources that they remove from their business to fund consumption and other types of saving as well as any retained earnings. Unfortunately in the CE and PSID we cannot observe any retained earnings. To the extent that some of the desired saving of the self-employed is done via retained earnings, the self-employed could have a higher propensity to consume out of the income they draw out of the business. This could explain the differential income-expenditure patterns documented above.

To test for the importance of the conceptual difference in income as an explanation of our results, we examine the underreporting behavior of the self-employed with zero reported business wealth relative to the underreporting behavior of the self-employed with non-zero business wealth. The assumption is that if the self-employed are reinvesting a substantial amount of their income into the business, it should show up in the value of their business. Such identification is made possible given the fact that a substantial fraction of the self-employed does not own a business or owns a business with little value (see Hurst and Lusardi 2004). This is consistent with the facts documented in Hurst and Pugsley (2010) showing that many of the self-employed are in industries where very little physical capital is needed (skilled craftsmen, real estate agents, lawyers, etc.).

Formally, we re-estimate (8) including separate dummies for the business wealth of the self employed. The specification, available in the robustness appendix, shows that the estimated underreporting gap is still substantial for those self-employed with zero business wealth. These finding suggest that the differences in the conceptual measures of income between the self-employed and the wage and salary workers is not the primary driver of the underreporting of income we documented above.

7. Differences in Underreporting across Different Groups and Tax Regimes

To bolster our case that households underreport their income to household surveys similarly to how they underreport their income to tax authorities, we explore whether factors that predict underreporting in the tax data are also found to predict underreporting within the household surveys. In particular, the literature exploring underreporting of income by the self-employed to tax authorities has found that underreporting is higher when marginal tax rates are higher (Clotfelter, 1983) and that there is some variation in the extent of underreporting across the self-employed in different industries. For example, Andreoni et al. (1998) find that the self-employed in professional industries underreport their income the least while those who are shopkeepers and restaurateurs underestimate their income the most. We find suggestive evidence of similar patterns within the household surveys.

To get a better sense of the changing nature of the underreporting over time, we look at the estimated underreporting separately for each year. To do this, we re-estimate (8) but instead of putting in the self-employment dummy alone we include the self-employment dummy interacted with individual year dummies. In Figure 4, we show the results using nondurable expenditure as our measure of expenditure and using total family income as our measure of income. Underreporting was high during the early 1980s (prior to 1986), fell between the late 1980s and mid 1990s and then started increasing during the late 1990s and early 2000.

Does the year-to-year variation in the extent to which the self-employed underreport their income correlate with prevailing tax regime within the U.S.? To explore this, we start by correlating the estimated coefficients of year dummies with measures of the aggregate tax regime. For our tax measure, we use the annual average marginal tax rate within the U.S. (inclusive of federal and state taxes) made available by the National Bureau of Economic Research.28 For reference, we plot this series in Appendix Figure A1. It is well known that the average marginal tax rate was high during the early 1980s, fell by roughly 15 percent (roughly 5 percentage points) through the mid 1980s due to the 1981 and 1986 tax reductions, increased gradually during the 1990s, and then fell again with the tax reductions in the early 2000s.A simple correlation of the estimated underreporting by the self-employed by year (as shown in Figure 4) with the average marginal tax rates within the U.S. (as shown in Figure A1) yields a correlation coefficient of 0.37 that is statistically significant. Most of this is driven by the high amount of underreporting prior to 1986, the sharp decline in underreporting between 1986 and the early 1990s, and the relative stability of the underreporting rate throughout most of the 1990s (aside from 1993 and 1994).

In Table 7, we explore this relationship more extensively and more concretely. In this table, we show how underreporting is related to the average marginal tax rate within the U.S. along with various other demographic controls. As above, we do this using nondurable expenditure from the CE (column 1), food expenditure from the CE (column 2), and food expenditure from the PSID (column 3). All specifications use log total family income as the income measure. To estimate these coefficients, we follow the same procedure discussed above for estimating the year dummies. In particular, we estimate (8) but add interactions between the self-employment dummy and the relevant demographic variables. We then use the estimated coefficients on the interactions to compute the gap of underreporting,  1-\kappa . Again, asymptotic standard errors are reported in parentheses.

As seen from Table 7, very few variables enter significantly. Moreover, the standard errors are large in all the specifications, making it hard to rule out either large negative or large positive effects with most of the control variables. A few patterns, however, do emerge. First, even conditional on control variables, the average marginal tax rate is still a significant predictor of the extent of underreporting. Most of this identification comes from the fact that underreporting was much higher in pre-1986 when average marginal tax rates were higher. After 1986, the variation between the average marginal tax rate and the extent of income underreporting by the self-employed was essentially zero. Given the power issues, the results are only suggestive. But, the results do show that underreporting was markedly higher prior to 1986 when average marginal tax rates were higher. This evidence is broadly consistent with the results using actual tax return data.

The only additional significant result that emerges from Table 7 is that those with advanced educational degrees are less likely to underreport their income. We do not have enough power to look at individual industries in isolation. However, most of the self-employed individuals with advanced degrees are professionals such as doctors, dentists, lawyers, and accountants. In all of these professions, the self-employed may find it more difficult to hide their income given that there is usually a detailed paper trail on the other side of the transaction. This is particularly true for doctors, dentists, and other medical professions given that they often bill insurance companies for their services rendered. The point estimates from columns 1 and 3 suggest that those with professional degrees underreport their income by 12 percentage points and 23 percentage points less, respectively, than households with a high school degree or less. Again, the evidence is broadly consistent with the literature using tax filings that find professionals are less likely to underreport their income.

8. The Importance of Income Underreporting by the Self-Employed

In this section, we show how not accounting for the systematic underreporting of income by the self-employed can lead to biased conclusions in a variety of settings. To do so, we re-examine several empirical examples where variation from the self-employed plays a prominent role. For the most part, we restrict the scope to results that can be explored using our existing PSID and CE samples. But, for some analyses, we must slightly change the sample criteria.29 Below, we only give a brief overview of the procedures. Collectively, the results in this section underscore our central point that taking a household survey at face value without thinking about the incentives the households have to report correctly could undermine a wide range of empirical analyses.

8A. Differences in Earnings between the Self-Employed and Wage and Salary Workers

The most straightforward implication of our findings pertains to papers that estimate earnings differentials between wage and salary workers and the self-employed. In a recent example, Hamilton (2000) estimates the returns to job tenure and experience in both self-employment and wage employment. Using data from the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP), he constructs lifecycle wage profiles separately for wage and salary workers and for the self-employed under several alternative measures of self-employed income. He finds the median self-employed individual's wages, cumulating over 10 years, are 35 percent lower than a comparable wage and salary worker, and he assigns a prominent role to non pecuniary returns to self-employment over alternative explanations.

Throughout his analysis, Hamilton did not adjust his estimates for the fact that the earnings data of the self-employed could be substantially underreported. In this subsection, we do not attempt to replicate the analysis of Hamilton using the SIPP data. The reason for this is that it is obvious that not accounting for the underreporting of income by the self-employed will severely bias these results. As we show above, the self-employed earnings are underreported by roughly 25 to 30 percent. This difference is only mitigated slightly once we control for differences in work hours between the two groups. As a result, it is likely that a substantial amount of the earnings gap estimated by Hamilton is simply due to the measurement error in household surveys with respect to self-employment income. {}^{ }30

8B. Difference in Wealth Holdings between the Self-employed and Wage and Salary Workers

There is a separate literature that focuses on differences in wealth between the self-employed and wage and salary workers. Most of this work examines the importance of financial frictions facing the self-employed. The argument goes that because the self-employed face binding liquidity constraints they must accumulate additional wealth to self finance their entrepreneurial projects. For example, both Gentry and Hubbard (2004) and Cagetti and De Nardi (2006) document that the self-employed hold a disproportionate amount of the aggregate wealth within the U.S.. Gentry and Hubbard (2004) go further and show that even conditional on income, the self-employed hold higher wealth than wage and salary workers. Cagetti and De Nardi (2006) use such relationships to calibrate a model of financial constraints facing business owners to explain the skewed wealth distribution within the U.S..

The differential conditional wealth relationship between the self-employed and wage and salary workers depends on the extent to which the self-employed income is reported without error. To the extent that the self-employed underreport their income, the conditional wealth holdings of the self-employed relative to wage and salary workers will be overstated.

To illustrate this point, we use data from the 1984, 1989, and 1994 PSID. Our sample is otherwise the same as we used above. Using this data, we regress log total wealth (inclusive of home equity) on a self-employment dummy, current household income, and the demographic variables included above when estimating equations (1) and (2). With this specification, we exclude those households with non-positive wealth. Similar to the results documented by others in the literature, we find that the net worth of the self-employed is 93 log points higher than wage and salary workers (a coefficient on the self-employment dummy of 0.93 with a standard error of 0.05). If, however, we adjust for the potential misreporting of income by the self-employed, the estimated wealth differences fall dramatically. To do this, we simply add 30 percent to the current income reports of the self-employed and then re-estimate the above equation. Modifying the income of the self-employed reduced the estimated wealth gap to 63 log points (standard error = 5 log points). As a result, roughly one third of the estimated conditional wealth differences is simply due to the underreporting of income by the self-employed.

8C. The Empirical Importance of Precautionary Savings

The first two examples show how accounting for the underreporting of income by the self-employed could lead to substantial changes in the results that directly compare the economic behavior of the self-employed to that of wage and salary workers. In the next several examples, we show that the underreporting of income by the self-employed can bias a variety of other types of analyses.

We start by focusing on the importance of precautionary savings. Carroll and Samwick (1998) use data from the PSID during the 1980s to explore the relationship between wealth holdings and income risk conditional on the level of income and other demographics. They measure income risk as the variance of actual household income as well as decompose the variance of household income into its permanent and transitory components. They instrument income risk using industry dummies. They conclude that up to 50 percent of household wealth accumulation for households under the age of 50 is due to precautionary motives.

Defining a sample that is analogous to Carroll and Samwick and using their same specification, we find that 47.5 percent of household saving can be attributed to precautionary motives. This estimate is nearly identical to the results reported in their work.31 However, if we increase the income of the self-employed by 30 percent to adjust for the underreporting, the estimated importance of precautionary savings is 13.5 percent lower (from 47.5 percent to 41.1 percent). What drives this decline? Industries in which the self-employed are more prevalent are also the industries which are found to have more income risk. When regressing wealth on income risk controlling for household income, it appears that households in industries where there is more income risk are holding more wealth for a given amount of income. However, some of this relationship is simply due to the fact that we are mismeasuring the level of income for those households. Our results show that ignoring the income underreporting of the self-employed can introduce substantial upward biases in the importance of precautionary savings in explaining total wealth accumulation of younger households.

8D. Adjustments to Life Cycle Earnings Profiles

Self-employment probabilities change over the lifecycle. For example, within our PSID, CE and CPS sample, the fraction of individuals that are self-employed rises from 5.0 percent, 5.9 percent and 5.1 percent respectively when households are 25 to 19.1 percent, 11.2 percent and 16.5 percent respectively when households are 45. They rise further to 39.5 percent, 21.6 percent and 28.3 percent when households are 65. Given that the self-employment propensities are changing over the lifecycle, the extent to which individual earnings is measured with error is changing over the lifecycle.

How much of the decline in average earnings between the ages of 45 and 65 could be driven by the underreporting of income by the self-employed? Within the PSID, CE and CPS samples, respectively, average earnings fell by 27.3 percent, 21.5 percent and 14.3 percent between the ages of 45 and 65.32 Simply adjusting for underreporting reduces these declines by 1.4, 3.2, and 3.6 percentage points. Taken together, between 5 and 10 percent of the decline in lifecycle earnings between the ages of 45 and 65 in the PSID and the CE can be accounted for by the underreporting of income by the self-employed.

8E. Spatial Differences in Average Earnings

Finally, we show that the underreporting of income by the self-employed could bias conclusions about the spatial differences in earnings. As shown by Glaeser (2007), self-employment propensities differ markedly across U.S. cities. Given this, comparing earnings across space will yield biased results if one does not account for differences in self-employment propensities across space.

Using the Public Use Microdata Sample (PUMS) from the 2000 Census, we illustrate this point. We construct a sample of male heads between the ages of 25 and 64, who are currently working, usually work more than 30 hours per week, and worked 40 weeks during the previous year. We further restrict this sample to only include individuals who live in a defined MSA. Within this sample, we find a tremendous amount of variation in self-employment rates across MSAs. Across the MSAs, the mean and median self-employment rates were 12.5 percent and 11.9 percent, respectively. The standard deviation in self-employment rates across the MSAs was 2.9 percent.

To illustrate the potential for the underreporting of income by the self-employed to yield biased results when computing earnings differentials across place, we look at a few pair wise comparisons. To do this, we examine conditional earnings differentials. Specifically, we regress log earnings on one year age dummies and a series of education, usual hours worked per week, and weeks worked per year dummies. We then compare these residuals, with and without adjusting for the underreporting of income by the self-employed, across MSAs.

For example, not accounting for the underreporting of income and conditional on the demographic and work hour adjustments, individuals in our sample from Nassau County New York earned 8.9 percent more than individuals in our sample from Detroit. 16.8 percent of the individuals from Nassau County were self-employed while only 10.2 percent of the individuals from Detroit were self-employed. Adjusting upward the income of all self-employed individuals, conditional on observables, by 30 percent, increases the Nassau-Detroit earnings differential by nearly 20 percent (from 8.9 percent to 10.6 percent). The earnings differential between the Barnstable-Yarmouth, Massachusetts MSA (which has the highest self-employment rate among MSAs at 25.5 percent) and the Kokomo, Indiana MSA (which has the lowest self-employment rate among MSAs at 6.0 percent) gets reduced by 35 percent when adjusting for income underreporting by the self-employed (from -14.7 percent to -9.6 percent).

8F. Potential Other Applications

The above results show that not accounting for the underreporting of income of the self-employed can lead to quantitatively important biases when comparing the income and savings behavior of the self-employed with wage and salary workers, when computing the economic importance of precautionary savings, when estimating lifecycle earnings profiles, and when computing earnings differentials across space. There are many other situations where not adjusting for the underreporting of income by the self-employed can potentially lead to quantitatively important biases. For example, given that self-employment propensities differ across races and genders, failing to account for the underreporting of income could lead to biased estimates of racial and gender earnings gaps. Likewise, there is much interest in comparing the borrowing and default behavior of the self-employed to wage and salary workers. Not properly measuring income for the self-employed could lead to biased results in this setting as well. We leave an assessment of the quantitative importance of these potential biases to future work.

9. Conclusion

Essentially all empirical work using data from household surveys assumes that household income is not systematically mismeasured. However, there is reason to believe that this assumption may not hold, particularly for the self-employed. Research from tax audits finds that the self-employed substantially underreport their income to tax authorities. What was less known to the research community is the extent to which the self-employed also underreport their income within U.S. surveys. Our paper contributes to the literature by filling this gap.

Using data from both the Consumer Expenditure Survey and the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, we find that the self-employed underreport their income by about 30 percent within household surveys relative to wage and salary workers. The results are remarkably consistent across both surveys. As robustness analyses, we implement a sequence of alternative specifications that relax various elements of our assumptions. Our results are essentially unchanged throughout. Consistent with data from the tax audits, we also find that the amount of underreporting was higher when marginal tax rates were higher and was lower among those with an advanced degree.

The results in this paper have implications for many literatures that use the income data reported in U.S. household surveys. In particular, we show that research that compares the earnings or saving behavior between the self-employed and wage and salary workers will yield substantially biased results if the research does not account for the underreporting of income by the self-employed. Moreover, we show that in many other settings, failing to account for the underreporting of income by the self-employed can lead to quantitatively biased conclusions. In particular, we show this to be true with respect to studies of the importance of precautionary savings, lifecycle earnings profiles, and differences in earnings across MSAs.

The results in this paper also point to a potentially bigger concern. There is an active literature showing that individuals will respond to incentives when reporting information to administrative sources (like tax authorities) or alter their behavior when participating in experiments. Yet, researchers often ignore the potential of such problems spilling over into the household surveys that we use for much of our economic analysis. It is naive to assume that individuals who are willing to misconstrue their behavior to administrative sources would otherwise automatically provide accurate responses when participating in household surveys. While it is likely true that the benefits of providing distorted information to household surveys are small, it is also likely true that the costs of providing accurate information are also small. To the extent that individuals would have to exert effort to provide an accurate response to household surveys or feel compelled to maintain consistency in light of concerns about confidentiality, economic theory would suggest that they would continue to provide the erroneous information, even if there is no direct benefit of doing so. We show these effects are present with respect to the income reporting of the self-employed. Future work should try to identify and explore other situations in which individuals may provide systematically biased information to household surveys.

Bibliography

Aguiar, Mark and Mark Bils (2010). "Has Consumption Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality", University of Rochester Working Paper.

Aguiar, Mark and Erik Hurst (2009). "Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditures", University of Chicago Working Paper.

Aguair, Mark and Erik Hurst (2007). "Lifecycle Prices and Production", American Economic Review, 97(5), pp. 1533-59.

Aguiar, Mark and Erik Hurst (2005). "Consumption vs. Expenditure", Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), pp. 919-48.

Andreoni, James, Brian Erard, and Jonathan Feinstein (1998). "Tax Compliance," Journal of Economic Literature, 36(2), pp. 818-60.

Banks, James, Richard Blundell, and Arthur Lewbel (1997). "Quadratic Engel Curves and Consumer Demand," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 79(4), pp. 527-39.

Barsky, Robert, Miles Kimball, Thomas Juster, and Matthew Shapiro (1997). "Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Study," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), pp. 537-79.

Becker, Gary (1965). "A Theory of the Allocation of Time." The Economic Journal, 75, pp. 493 - 517.

Blank, Rebecca, Kerwin Charles and James Sallee (2009). "A Cautionary Tale about the Use of Administrative Data: Evidence from Age of Marriage Laws," American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 1(2), pp. 128-49.

Blundell, Richard, Martin Browning, and Costas Meghir (1994), "Consumer Demand and the Life-Cycle Allocation of Household Expenditures," Review of Economic Studies, 61, 57-80.

Bound, John, Brown, Charles, Duncan, Greg, and Rodgers, Willard (1994). "Evidence on the Validity of Cross Sectional and Longitudinal Labor Market Data", Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 12(3), pp. 345-68.

Bound, John, Charles Brown, and Nancy Mathiowetz (2001). "Measurement Error in Survey Data", in Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 5, eds. J.J. Heckman and E. Leamer, Elsevier Science.

Cagetti, Marco, and De Nardi, Mariacristina (2006). "Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 106(5), pp. 835-70.

Carroll, Chris and Samwick, Andrew (1998). "How Important is Precautionary Saving?" Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 80(3), pp. 410-9.

Clotfelter, Charles (1983). "Tax Evasion and Tax Rates: An Analysis of Individual Returns," Review of Economics and Statistics, 65(3), pp. 363-73.

Deaton, Angus (1997). The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy. World Bank Publication.

Deaton, Angus and John Muellbauer (1980). "An Almost Ideal Demand System," American Economic Review, 70(3), pp. 312-26.

Feldman, Naomi and Joel Slemrod (2007). "Estimating Tax Noncompliance with Evidence from Unaudited Tax Returns", Economic Journal, vol. 117 (518), pp. 327-52.

Fitzgerald, John, Peter Gottschalk, and Robert Moffitt (1998). "An Analysis of Sample Attrition in Panel Data: The Michigan Panel Study of Income Dynamics", Journal of Human Resources, 33(2), 251-99.

Gentry, William and R. Glenn Hubbard (2004). "Entrepreneurship and Household Saving," Advances in Economic Analysis & Policy, 4(1), Article 8.

Ghez, Gilbert and Gary Becker (1975). The Allocation of Time and Goods over the Life Cycle, Columbia University Press, New York.

Gibson, John, Bonggeun Kim and Chul Chung (2009). "Using Panel Data to Exactly Estimate Income Under Reporting of the Self-employed". Labor Economics Working Papers, East Asian Bureau of Economic Research.

Glaeser, Edward (2007). "Entrepreneurship and the City". Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper No. 2140.

Gorodnichenko, Yuriy, Jorge Martinez-Vazquez, and Klara Sabirianova Peter (2009). "Myth and Reality of Flat Tax Reform: Micro Estimates of Tax Evasion Response and Welfare Effects in Russia," Journal of Political Economy, 117(3), pp. 504-554.

Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier and Jonathan Parker (2002), "Consumption over the Life Cycle," Econometrica, January 2002, 70, 1, 47-89.

Haider, Steven and Gary Solon (2006). "Life-Cycle Variation in the Association Between Current and Lifetime Earnings". American Economic Review, 96(4), 1308-1320

Hamilton, Barton H. (2000). "Does Entrepreneurship Pay? An Empirical Analysis of the Returns to Self-Employment." Journal of Political Economy vol. 108 (3), pp. 604-31.

Hurst, Erik and Lusardi, Annamaria (2004). "Liquidity Constraints, Household Wealth, and Entrepreneurship", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 112(2), pp. 319-47.

Hurst, Erik and Ben Pugsley (2010). "The Non Pecuniary Benefits of Small Business Ownership", University of Chicago Working Paper.

Johansson, Edvard (2005). "An Estimate of Self Employment Income Underreporting in Finland", Nordic Journal of Political Economy, vol 31(1), pp. 99 - 109.

Levitt, Steve and John List (2009). "Was there Really a Hawthorne Effect at the Hawthorne Plant? An Analysis of the Original Illumination Experiments", NBER Working Paper 15016.

Meyer, Bruce, Wallace K.C. Mok, and James Sullivan (2009). "The Under-Reporting of Transfers in Household Surveys: Its Nature and Consequences" Harris School Working Paper #09.03,

Moskowitz, Tobias J., and Vissing-Jorgensen, Annette (2002). "The Returns to Entrepreneurial Investment: A Private Equity Premium Puzzle?" American Economic Review vol. 92(4), pp. 745-78.

Pissarides, Christopher and Guglielmo Weber (1989). "An Expenditure Based Estimate of Britain's Black Economy", Journal of Public Economics, vol. 39(1), pp. 17-32.

Schuetze, Herb (2002). "Profiles of Tax Noncompliance Among the Self Employed in Canada:1969-1992." Canadian Public Policy, vol. 28(2), pp. 219-37.

Slemrod, Joel (1985). "An Empirical Test for Tax Evasion," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 67(2), pp. 232-38.

Slemrod, Joel (2007). "Cheating Ourselves: The Economics of Tax Evasion," Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(1), pp. 25-48.


Data Appendix

This appendix gives background information on all the data sources used in this paper.

CE Data

The CE is conducted by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The primary objective of the survey is to collect detailed household expenditure information to update the weights used to construct the Consumer Price Index. However, the household level data of the CE have also been used extensively in academic research to explore household consumption behavior. The CE is a quarterly survey and its modern version started in 1980. In addition to detailed information on household expenditures, the CE collects key information on household demographics, income, and employment status. The CE interviews a consumer unit up to five times, once every 3 months. The first interview is conducted to establish contact with, and collect such data on, the interviewees; the subsequent four interviews are carried out to collect most of the expenditure data. In the fifth interview, demographic, income, and labor supply variables are updated. After the fifth interview, the consumer unit leaves the sample and new units are added to the sample, giving the CE a rotating sample structure.

PSID Data

The PSID is a longitudinal survey conducted by the Institute of Social Research at the University of Michigan. The PSID collects extensive information on employment history, demographic characteristics, and household income.

CPS Sample

The CPS is a monthly survey of about 50,000 households conducted jointly by the U.S. Census Bureau and the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. It is the primary source of labor force characteristics of the U.S. population. For our analysis, we use data from the March Annual Supplement to the CPS. Households surveyed in March answer additional detailed questions about their annual income and employment in the previous calendar year.

To match the PSID and CE sample selection criteria, we use annual data from 1980 to 2003 and restrict our analysis to households with a civilian male household head, whose age is between 25 and 55 (inclusive), who worked at least 40 weeks during the last calendar year and usually worked at least 30 hours per week in paid or self-employment. We further restrict the sample by excluding households with a male wage and salary worker, but whose spouse (if present) was self-employed. Lastly, we exclude any remaining households who had non-positive labor plus business family income or who had any farm income. To extend the sample to include up to 65 year olds in section 8, we apply the same sample restrictions except now including ages 25-65 inclusive. We define two measures of household income within the CPS: family labor earnings plus family business income and total family income. The two income measures are defined analogously to the way they were defined in the CE and the PSID. Finally, self-employed households are defined as those households whose male head reports that for his longest job during the last year he was self-employed.33


Table 1: Descriptive Statistics for Self-Employed and Wage and Salary Worker Samples, CE, PSID, and CPS
Income Measure/Sample Data Set CE Self Employed Data Set CE Wage Workers Data Set PSID Self Employed Data Set PSID Wage Workers Data Set CPS Self Employed Data Set CPS Wage Worker
Panel A: Income Measures Total Family Income 10.87 10.86 11.20 11.00 10.97 10.93
Panel A: Income Measures Labor Plus Business Income 10.81 10.84 11.02 10.91 10.87 10.88
Panel B: Expenditure Measures Food Expenditure 8.85 8.67 8.97 8.73 - -
Panel B: Expenditure Measures Nondurable Expenditure 9.98 9.78 - - - -
Panel B: Expenditure Measures Total Expenditure 10.74 10.51 - - - -
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures Average Age of Head 41.4 39.0 40.7 37.9 41.7 39.2
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures % Education = 12 26.9 29.2 20.5 24.0 29.7 33.8
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures % Education = Some College 23.2 23.3 31.2 31.2 22.7 23.8
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures % Education = College 20.3 18.9 21.4 19.2 20.1 18.7
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures % Education = Graduate School 17.9 12.5 14.9 9.9 17.8 11.6
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures % Black 3.4 7.8 2.7 9.7 3.2 8.9
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures % Married 83.2 80.6 86.7 78.6 86.1 81.8
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures Average Family Size 3.4 3.26 3.30 3.10 3.36 3.22
Panel C: Other Labor Supply and Demographic Measures Average Head Work Hours 2,561 2,317 2,560 2,293 2526 2280
Sample Size 2,508 24,704 4,207 29,639 70,423 440,883

Notes: This table compares income, expenditure, and demographic variables between the self-employed and wage and salary workers within the CE, PSID, and CPS. Each sample is restricted to include all households with male heads between the ages of 25 and 55 (inclusive) who are working full time. Additional sample restrictions for each survey are discussed in the text.


Table 2: Conditional Log Income Differences for Full Time Wage and Salary Workers and Self-Employed
  Data Sets/Specification I. Income = Total Family Income Data Sets/Specification II. Income = Labor Earnings + Business Income
Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Dummy: Self-Employed -0.08 0.07 -0.07 -0.10 -0.01 -0.11
Dummy: Self-Employed standard error (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01)
Demographic Controls Included Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Dummies Included Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Sample CE PSID CPS CE PSID CPS

Notes: The table shows the regression of household income on a self-employment dummy and additional demographic and year controls. In panel I, our measure of income is total family income for the household. In panel II, our measure of income is labor earnings of the household plus household business income. We run the regressions separately within each of the three surveys. For example, columns (1) - (3) show the results from the same regression, but using data from the CE, PSID, and CPS surveys, respectively. All regressions control for: a series of five year age dummies, four dummies indicating the education of the household head (exactly high school, some college, exactly college, and more than college; less than high school was omitted), a dummy if the household head was Black, a dummy if the household head was married, and a series of family size dummies. The CE, PSID, and CSP samples are the same as the ones defined in Table 1. Robust standard errors are in parenthesis.


Table 3: Conditional Log Expenditure Differences For Full Time Wage and Salary Workers and Self-employed
Data Sets/Dependent Variables I. CE Food I. CE Nondurable I. CE Total II. PSID Food
Dummy: Self-Employed 0.12 0.13 0.16 0.14
Dummy: Self-Employed standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Demographic Controls Included Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year Dummies Included Yes Yes Yes Yes

Notes: The table shows the regression of household expenditure on a self-employment dummy and additional demographic and year controls. In panel I, we show the estimates using CE data. In panel II, we show the estimates using PSID data. For the CE sample, we explore conditional differences between the self-employed and the wage and salary workers using three measures of expenditures: food (column 1), nondurable expenditures (column 2), and total expenditures (column 3). The PSID sample has information only on food expenditures. All regressions control for: a series of five year age dummies, four dummies indicating the education of the household head (exactly high school, some college, exactly college, and more than college; less than high school was omitted), a dummy if the household head was black, a dummy if the household head was married, and a series of family size dummies. The CE and PSID samples are the same as the ones defined in Table 1. Robust standard errors are in parenthesis.

Table 4: Log Expenditure Differences Between Self-Employed and Wage Workers,

Conditional on Log Income and Demographics

Sample/Expenditure Measure I. Income = Total Family Income OLS I. Income = Total Family Income IV II. Income = Labor Earnings Plus Business Income OLS II. Income = Labor Earnings Plus Business Income IV
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta CEX, Nondurable Expenditure 0.37 0.60 0.34 0.61
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta CEX, Nondurable Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta CEX, Total Expenditure 0.42 0.76 0.39 0.76
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta CEX, Total Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta CEX, Food Expenditure 0.26 0.40 0.25 0.40
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta CEX, Food Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta PSID, Food Expenditure 0.30 0.32 0.29 0.31
Panel A: Estimates of  \beta PSID, Food Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma CEX, Nondurable Expenditure 0.17 0.18 0.18 0.19
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma CEX, Nondurable Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma CEX, Total Expenditure 0.20 0.21 0.21 0.23
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma CEX, Total Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02)
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma CEX, Food Expenditure 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.16
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma CEX, Food Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma PSID, Food Expenditure 0.12 0.11 0.14 0.13
Panel B: Estimates of  \gamma PSID, Food Expenditure standard error (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)

Notes: This table shows the OLS and IV estimates of equation (8) from the text. Equation (8) estimates the relationship between log household expenditures and log household income conditional on a self-employment dummy and other demographics. The coefficient on log household income is denoted as  \beta and the coefficient on the self-employment dummy is denoted  \gamma . The demographic controls are the same as the controls used to estimate the results in Tables 2 and 3, aside from the education dummies. We use the education dummies as the instruments for income in the IV specifications. As with the results in Tables 2 and 3, we estimate the regression using different measures of expenditures and for different samples (indicated down the rows) and for different measures of household income (indicated across the columns). Robust standard errors are shown in parentheses. The samples are the same as the ones discussed in Table 1.

Table 5: Predicted Fraction of Income Underreported by Self-Employed,

Baseline Specification

Expenditure Measure Estimate of (1- \kappa ), in Percent Income = Total Family Income Estimate of (1- \kappa ), in Percent Income = Labor Earnings Plus Business Income
CEX, Nondurable Expenditure 25.5 27.5
CEX, Nondurable Expenditure standard error (1.5) (1.6)
CEX, Total Expenditure 24.5 26.5
CEX, Total Expenditure standard error (1.5) (1.5)
CEX, Food Expenditure 31.7 33.5
CEX, Food Expenditure standard error (2.0) (2.0)
PSID, Food Expenditure 30.1 34.9
PSID, Food Expenditure standard error (2.2) (1.9)

Notes: This table shows the estimates of the amount of underreporting of income by the self-employed, denoted by (1 -  \kappa ), using the estimates of  \beta and  \gamma from Table 4. We show the different estimates of (1- \kappa ) using different measures of expenditure, using data from the different surveys, and using different measures of income. In this table, we only show the estimates using the  \beta and  \gamma estimates from the IV specifications. Asymptotic standard errors are computed for the transformation 1- \kappa using a robust estimate of the variance covariance matrix.


Table 6: Predicted Fraction of Income Underreported by Self-Employed, Alternate Specifications
Expenditure Measure Specification/Sample 1 Specification/Sample 2 Specification/Sample 3 Specification/Sample 4
CEX, Nondurable Expenditure 25.2 27.4 26.6 24.4
CEX, Nondurable Expenditure standard error (1.5) (1.6) (2.7) (1.8)
CEX, Total Expenditure 24.5 26.7 24.2 24.6
CEX, Total Expenditure standard error (1.5) (1.5) (2.6) (1.7)
CEX, Food Expenditure 31.5 33.5 35.7 28.6
CEX, Food Expenditure standard error (2.0) (1.9) (3.7) (2.2)
PSID, Food Expenditure 28.6 34.1 30.1 28.4
PSID, Food Expenditure standard error (2.2) (1.8) (3.0) (3.0)
Income Measure Total Labor Plus Business Total Total
Specification Include Log Work Hours as a Control Include Log Work Hours as a Control Restrict To Heads With Age 25-40 Restrict To Heads With Age 40-55

Notes: This table shows the amount of underreporting of income by the self-employed (1- \kappa ) for alternate specifications of equation (8) from the text. All specifications in this table are based on the IV specification using CEX data with total nondurable expenditures as the expenditure measure. As a result, these estimates should be compared to row (1) of Table 5. In columns (1) and (2), we add log work hours to our vector or control variables. The first column uses total family income as the income measure while the second column uses labor plus business income as the income measure. In columns (3) and (4), we split the samples by age (young vs. old). In columns (5) and (6), we only use data from the 1984, 1989, and 1994 PSID because they are the only years that collect information on household business wealth. In column (5), we only include the self-employed with zero business wealth. In column (6), we only include the s elf employed with more than $10,000 in business wealth. For all specifications, the sample is otherwise the same as the one described in the note to Table 1. Asymptotic standard errors are computed for the transformation 1- \kappa using a robust estimate of the variance covariance matrix. Table 7: Explaining the Income Gap Among the Self-Employed, Percentage Changes to (1- \kappa )

Table 7: Explaining the Income Gap Among the Self-Employed, Percentage Changes to (1- \kappa )
Variable I. CE (1) Nondurable Expenditure I. CE (2) Food Expenditure II. PSID (3) Food Expenditure
Average marginal federal tax rate (percent) 2.24 2.76 1.56
Average marginal federal tax rate (percent) standard error (0.89) (1.18) (0.84)
Age: 40-55 1.91 0.62 3.45
Age: 40-55 standard error (3.86) (5.32) (4.63)
Ed = Some College 4.94 6.04 14.51
Ed = Some College standard error (5.15) (6.72) (4.74)
Ed = College -5.62 -3.03 2.20
Ed = College standard error (5.08) (6.81) (6.16)
Ed = More than College -11.48 -2.89 -23.03
Ed = More than College standard error (6.00) (7.47) (9.74)
Black 10.39 2.98 6.03
Black standard error (16.30) (18.43) (11.25)
Married -8.19 -21.05 -4.11
Married standard error (5.47) (8.63) (9.39)
Income Measure Total Family Total Family Total Family

Note: This table shows how the estimates of (1- \kappa ) change with economic and demographic variables. To get these estimates, we re-estimate equation (8) with the relevant variable of interest interacted with a self-employment dummy. To get this specification, we also included the average marginal federal tax rate as a separate control. The results in this table are based on the IV specification using the relevant specifications. All specifications use total family income as the income measure. Panel I shows the results using CE data while panel II shows the results using PSID data. The samples are the same as the ones used in Table 1. Asymptotic standard errors are computed for the transformation 1- \kappa using a robust estimate of the variance covariance matrix.


Figure 1: Relationship Between Total Family Money and Nondurable Expenditure, CE

Panel A: OLS Estimation

Figure 1. Description below.

Notes: This figure shows the OLS estimates of the Engel curves as specified in equation (3) in the text, separately for wage/salary workers (solid line) and the self-employed (dashed line). We evaluate both curves at the sample means of the demographic control for the pooled sample. The estimated intercepts for the self-employed and the wage/salary workers, respectively, are 7.02 and 5.55. The estimated slopes for each group, respectively, are 0.27 and 0.39. The sample for each specification are the same as the ones described in the notes to Table 1.


Figure 1 Panel B: IV Estimation

Figure 1. Description below.
Accessible Version

Notes: This figure shows the OLS estimates of the Engel curves as specified in equation (3) in the text, separately for wage/salary workers (solid line) and the self-employed (dashed line). We evaluate both curves at the sample means of the demographic control for the pooled sample. The estimated intercepts for the self-employed and the wage/salary workers, respectively, are 4.37 and 3.12. The estimated slopes for each group, respectively, are 0.51 and 0.61. The sample for each specification are the same as the ones described in the notes to Table 1.


Figure 2: Relationship Between Total Family Money and Food Expenditure, CE

Panel A: OLS Estimation

Figure 2. Description below.

Notes: This figure shows the OLS estimates of the Engel curves as specified in equation (3) in the text, separately for wage/salary workers (solid line) and the self-employed (dashed line). We evaluate both curves at the sample means of the demographic control for the pooled sample. The estimated intercepts for the self-employed and the wage/salary workers, respectively, are 6.54 and 5.68. The estimated slopes for each group, respectively, are 0.21 and 0.28. The sample for each specification are the same as the ones described in the notes to Table 1.


Figure 2 Panel B: IV Estimation

Figure 2. Description below.
Accessible Version

Notes: This figure shows the OLS estimates of the Engel curves as specified in equation (3) in the text, separately for wage/salary workers (solid line) and the self-employed (dashed line). We evaluate both curves at the sample means of the demographic control for the pooled sample. The estimated intercepts for the self-employed and the wage/salary workers, respectively, are 4.73 and 4.29. The estimated slopes for each group, respectively, are 0.38 and 0.40. The sample for each specification are the same as the ones described in the notes to Table 1.


Figure 3: Relationship Between Total Family Money and Food Expenditure, PSID

Panel A: OLS Estimation

Figure 3. Description below.

Notes: This figure shows the OLS estimates of the Engel curves as specified in equation (3) in the text, separately for wage/salary workers (solid line) and the self-employed (dashed line). We evaluate both curves at the sample means of the demographic control for the pooled sample. The estimated intercepts for the self-employed and the wage/salary workers, respectively, are 6.18 and 5.18. The estimated slopes for each group, respectively, are 0.24 and 0.32. The sample for each specification are the same as the ones described in the notes to Table 1.


Figure 3 Panel B: IV Estimation

Figure 3. Description below.
Accessible Version

Notes: This figure shows the OLS estimates of the Engel curves as specified in equation (3) in the text, separately for wage/salary workers (solid line) and the self-employed (dashed line). We evaluate both curves at the sample means of the demographic control for the pooled sample. The estimated intercepts for the self-employed and the wage/salary workers, respectively, are 5.47 and 5.23. The estimated slopes for each group, respectively, are 0.31 and 0.32. The sample for each specification are the same as the ones described in the notes to Table 1.


Figure 4: Estimates of the Underreporting of Income By Self-Employed Over Time, CEX Data

Figure 4. Description below.
Accessible Version

Notes: This table shows the estimates of underreporting (1- \kappa ) by year using the CEX data (IV specification) where nondurable income is the expenditure measure and total family money is the income measure. To get these estimates, we re-estimated equation (8) including year dummies interacted with the self-employed dummy. Robust standard error bands are shown as the dashed lines.


Appendix Figure A1 - The Average Marginal Tax Rate in the U.S.

Figure A1. Description below.

Notes: Figure shows the time series variation in the average marginal tax rate. See text for details.



Footnotes

* We would like to thank the following for their helpful comments and discussions: Kerwin Charles, Raj Chetty, Steve Davis, Joshua Gottlieb, Bruce Meyer, Matt Notowidingo, Michael Palumbo, Jesse Shapiro, and Bob Willis. We would also like to thank seminar participants at Boston College, Chicago, Harvard Business School, Penn State, Stanford, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. The views presented in this paper are those of the authors and do not represent those of the Federal Reserve Board or its staff. Hurst and Pugsley gratefully acknowledge the financial support provided by the George J. Stigler Center for the Study of Economy and the State. Additionally, Hurst thanks the financial support provided by the University of Chicago's Booth School of Business. Return to Text
1. See, for example, Clotfelter (1983), Slemrod (1985), Feinstein (1991), Andreoni et al. (1998), Slemrod (2007), and Feldman and Slemrod (2007). Return to Text
2. This phenomenon is sometimes referred to as the Hawthorne Effect, named for a series of studies at the Hawthorne Works factory where workers' productivity initially improved while under observation but declined soon after. There is a large literature within the social sciences on the Hawthorne Effect. See Levitt and List (2009) for a recent discussion. Return to Text
3. For example, Blank et al. (2009) compares administrative data from Vital Statistic records to data from the U.S. Census to show that in states where minimum age of marriage laws were binding, younger individuals appeared to have lied about their age to government officials when applying for their marriage license. Return to Text
4. There is an important literature examining measurement error in household surveys. We briefly discuss some of this literature below. When doing so, we discuss how our results contribute to this literature. Return to Text
5. Source: "Individual Income Tax Gap Estimates for 1985, 1988, and 1992" which can be found at http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/p141596.pdf. The degree of underreporting was even higher in recent years when the IRS estimated that 57 percent of nonfarm proprietor income was underreported in tax year 2001, see: "Reducing the Federal Tax Gap: A Report on Improving Voluntary Compliance" which can be found at http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-news/tax_gap_report_final_080207_linked.pdf Return to Text
6. Bound et al. (2001) survey nearly fifty years of research examining the extent to which household survey data are measured with error. Return to Text
7. There is much work using the TCMP and NRP data to assess the underreporting of income on U.S. tax returns. For a summary of this literature, see the recent surveys by Andreoni et al. (1998) and Slemrod (2007). Return to Text
8. Several authors have examined the underreporting of income by the self-employed within household surveys from other countries. For example, Pissarides and Weber (1989) use their expenditure-based method to detect the underreporting of income by the self-employed within Britain's 1982 Family Expenditure Survey. They find that the self-employed underreported their income by roughly 35 percent within Britain in 1982. Using a similar methodology, Johansson (2005) finds that the self-employed underreport their income by 16-40 percent in Finland, Schuetze (2002) finds 17 percent underreporting in Canada, and Gibson, Kim, and Chung (2009) find roughly 40 and 50 percent underreporting in Korea and Russian, respectively. Gorodnichenko et al (2009) use household expenditure data and changes in national tax policy to examine the extent to which taxes are evaded in Russia. Return to Text
9. See http://www.nber.org/data/ces_cbo.html for details on the NBER CE extracts. Return to Text
10. Male heads are indentified as those male individuals who self report themselves as being a head or, to be consistent with the PSID, those males who are married to someone who reports themselves as being a head. Return to Text
11. Such households constitutes 3.1 percent of the CE sample. Our results are not sensitive to whether or not we include such households within our self-employed or wage and salary worker sample. Return to Text
12. The online robustness appendix can be found athttp://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/erik.hurst/research/. The definitions we use are the same as the ones used in Aguiar and Hurst (2009). Following Aguiar and Hurst (2009), we do not include health or education expenditures in our measure of nondurable goods expenditure. Return to Text
13. The fact that both the return to business labor and the return to business capital is combined together in our base measure of earnings is done out of necessity. The CE does not separately distinguish between the two components of business income. A similar decision is made with respect to the PSID data (described below). While the PSID does attempt to distinguish business labor income from business capital income, such a distinction is imputed for most households. Return to Text
14. See Hurst and Lusardi (2004) and the references cited within. Return to Text
15. Because the PSID is a longitudinal survey, we are able to restrict the sample to those whose head had worked at least 40 weeks in the year during which the expenditure occurred. In contrast, in the CE sample, the annual working week restriction refers to the number of weeks in the year prior to expenditure. Return to Text
16. The details of the CPS sample are discussed in the Data Appendix. Return to Text
17. We do not require that markets are complete, only that the household is able to save and borrow in some form sufficient to support a lifetime budget constraint in expected value. In section 6, we explore whether differential liquidity constraints between the two groups can explain the patterns we see in the data. Return to Text
18. Given the nature of the PSID data, we could have exploited the panel nature of the PSID by constructing a multi-year average income measure. In a prior draft of this paper, we did just that. We made a 3-year average income and expenditure PSID sample. Using that sample, we regressed log three year average food expenditure on three year average income, our vector of controls X, and the time dummies. The results from the three year average PSID sample and the instrumented version of below using the one year PSID sample were nearly identical. As a result, to save space, we only show here the results using the one year PSID samples. However, if one is interested in the three year average results, they are available upon request from the authors. Return to Text
19. To plot the Engel curves, we evaluate our estimate of using means of pooled self-employed and wage and salary workers for each sample. Return to Text
20. Later in the paper, we explore how  \kappa varies across different demographic groups and across different tax regimes. Return to Text
21. Moreover, we cannot reject equality of the coefficients on the vector of controls between the two groups. Return to Text
22. For some categories of expenditure, such as gasoline, the CE explicitly asks the share of that expenditure used for business. For some other expenditure categories, such as auto repairs and parking, the CE explicitly reminds the consumers not to include such expenditure for business use. However, it is still possible that the some consumers counted personal expenditure as business expenditure or vice versa, leading to reporting inaccurate personal expenditure to the CE. Return to Text
23. A full description of these results can be found in the online robustness appendix. Return to Text
24. We are not saying that wage and salary workers report their expenditures without error. What our test uncovers is whether there is any differential systematic misreporting by the self employed relative to wage and salary workers. Return to Text
25. Aguiar and Hurst (2009) show that non separable preferences between consumption and leisure are isomorphic to separable preferences between consumption and leisure with a home production sector that combines expenditures and time to produce the consumption good. Return to Text
26. Our results are not sensitive to the age cutoff. Even looking at 45-55 year olds or 50-55 year olds, we see little change in our estimates of the amount of underreporting. Return to Text
27. Fringe benefits such as pension contributions are an exception. Return to Text
28. See http://www.nber.org/ taxsim/ally/. The series was computed by Daniel Feenberg and is based on micro data file provide by the Statistics of Income Division of the IRS. Return to Text
29. A full discussion, including details on specifications and sample restrictions can be found in the online robustness that accompanies this paper. Return to Text
30. We want to stress that we are not saying that non pecuniary benefits are not important for the self-employed. Moskowitz and Vissing-Jorgensen (2002) do account for the fact that the self-employed do underreport their income. Even with this adjustment, they still conclude that non pecuniary benefits of self-employment could be very large. Return to Text
31. The details of the specification and sample can be found in the online robustness appendix. Return to Text
32. A more formal analysis of this question would want to adjust for either individual or cohort fixed effects. This example is only meant to be illustrative. Return to Text
33. To determine the class of employment, the CPS interviewer asks a series of questions about the individual's employer to determine whether he worked for a private firm, for a government (federal, state, or local), worked without pay in family business, or were self-employed (incorporated or unincorporated). Since we have already excluded those individuals working without pay, wage and salary workers are defined as those working for a private firm or for a government. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text