The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2011-47 Screen Reader version

An Empirical Investigation of Consumption-based Asset Pricing Models with Stochastic Habit Formation*

Qiang Dai

and

Olesya V. Grischenko

October 19, 2011


Keywords: Asset pricing, consumption-based asset pricing models, habit formation, stochastic internal habit, aggregate equity, bond returns.

Abstract:

We econometrically estimate a consumption-based asset pricing model with stochastic internal habit and test it using the generalized method of moments. The model departs from existing models with deterministic internal habit (e.g., Dunn & Singleton (1983), Ferson & Constantinides (1991), and Heaton (1995)) by introducing shocks to the coefficients in the distributed lag specification of consumption habit and consequently an additional shock to the marginal rate of substitution. The stochastic shocks to the consumption habit are persistent and provide an additional source of time variation in expected returns. Using Treasury bond returns and broad equity market index returns, we show that stochastic internal habit formation models resolve the dichotomy between the autocorrelation properties of the stochastic discount factor and those of expected returns. Consequently, they provide a better explanation of time-variation in expected returns than models with either deterministic habit or stochastic external habit.

JEL Classification: E21, G10, G12


1 Introduction

Consumption-based capital asset pricing models (CCAPMs) with time non-separable preferences including habit formation have received considerable attention recently as a potential mechanism for explaining the equity premium puzzle (see, e.g., Sundaresan (1989), Abel (1990), Constantinides (1990), and Campbell & Cochrane (1999)). The joint behavior of stock and bond returns within the context of consumption-based models has been understood much less. In this paper we present a structural model with stochastic internal habits that helps resolve the dichotomy between the autocorrelation properties of the stochastic discount factors and those of bond returns.1 Our formulation nests many of the previously studied specifications along one or both of the following two dimensions. First, by adopting the GMM approach (Hansen, 1982), we are completely agnostic about the dynamics of the aggregate endowment or technology imposed in other papers, such as, e.g., Campbell & Cochrane (1999), Wachter (2006), and Bekaert, et al. (2010). This means that our model implicitly nests any parametric specifications of the aggregate endowment process. Second, we adopt a general parametric specification of the consumption habit process that nests many of the previous habit specifications. Specifically, we start with a standard geometric distributed lag specification, and then introduce a stochastic shock to the weights in the distributed lag. The timing of the new shock is such that it can be literally interpreted as an unexpected shock to the habit stock itself.2

Using the same econometric method, Dunn & Singleton (1986, DS) and Ferson & Constantinides (1991, FC) test the over-identifying restrictions implied by the stochastic Euler equations derived from such models, while being agnostic about the endowment specification and the nature of the temporal dependence of consumption. Heaton (1995), on the other hand, uses the simulated method of moments to estimate a model that incorporates both a parametric form of consumption durability and habit.3 ^{,}4 These studies find that there is empirical evidence for both consumption habit and local substitution. However, which effect dominates may depend on the decision interval, the instruments used in estimating the model, and the investment horizon. The overall goodness-of-fit test econometrically rejects all of the models. The econometric rejection of existing CCAPMs with time separable and time nonseparable utility is largely due to the notorious failure of these models to explain bond returns. Singleton (1993) and Heaton (1995) explore in depth such models' inability to explain the autocorrelation properties of bond returns. This problem arises because a stochastic discount factor (SDF henceforth) in the time separable models and some of the time nonseparable models is a simple function of the nearly i.i.d consumption growth process, and this makes it difficult for models to explain persistent properties of long-term bond returns.

The failure of earlier asset pricing models with time non-separable preferences to explain time-varying bond returns arises because both types of models, either external or internal habits, (Constantinides (1990) and Campbell & Cochrane (1999, CC), respectively) side-step the issue of term structure dynamics by imposing restrictions so that the real term structure is constant and flat. Several papers extend the CC model in order to accommodate stochastic interest rates. Campbell & Cochrane (1999) show how to extend their model by relaxing a parametric restriction on the specification of the surplus consumption ratio. However, in their model, interest rates and bond risk premium are perfectly correlated with consumption shock, which is counter-factual. Wachter (2006) relaxes the assumption of the CC model of an i.i.d. consumption growth rate and shows that interest rates and the risk premium have properties broadly consistent with observed bond return predictability in her model. Buraschi & Jiltsov (2007) develop a continuous term structure model in the context of the CC model and show that habit persistence can help reproduce various properties of the term structure. Bekaert, et al. (2009) also consider a generalized version of the CC model where a surplus consumption ratio is stochastic, which allows them to obtain some non-trivial implications for the term structure of interest rates. All of these extensions share the common feature that the external habit process is no longer locally deterministic.

There has been much less work done extending deterministic internal habit process to accommodate preference shocks. However, this venue is important in view of two recent empirical papers by Chen & Ludvigson (2009) and Grishchenko (2010), who investigate the properties of habit persistence at the aggregate level and conclude that aggregate data are more consistent with internal rather than external habit formation preferences. The reason is that internal habit generates the necessary autocorrelations in the stochastic discount factor via a non-trivial impact of current consumption on future marginal utility. This channel is absent in the external habit models where current consumption affects only the surplus consumption ratio, but the functional form of the marginal utility stays unaltered (compared to marginal utility in the time separable preferences). Dai (2003) is the first who introduces the stochastic internal habit model. He relaxes Constantinides' assumption of a constant investment opportunity set by allowing the instantaneous short rate to be driven by the level of the habit stock, and shows that the time-varying risk premium implied by the model is capable of explaining the violation of the Campbell & Shiller (1991) expectations hypothesis puzzle. In our work, the deterministic internal habit formation models of Sundaresan (1989) and Constantinides (1990), and the stochastic internal habit formation model of Dai (2003) are nested special cases in the continuous-time limit.

The presence of the habit shock in the economy - in addition to the consumption shock - breaks the tight linkage between asset returns and consumption growth rates in the standard CCAPM or its extension with deterministic habit. Economically, the habit shock can be broadly interpreted as a taste shock. Its high realization occurs in the bad state of the world, associated with the low dividend payoff and the low level of consumption. In this state, the additional dollar of return becomes even more valuable because marginal utility depends positively on this shock.

To our knowledge, this work is the first empirical investigation of stochastic internal habit models. It relates to prior and rather limited work on the impact of preference shocks on asset prices. Among the first, Campbell (1986) includes random shocks in the CRRA utility to examine the conjecture of Modigliani & Sutch (1966) that investor preferences might cause negative term premiums on long-term bonds. He argues that randomness in preferences (interpreted as taste shocks) generates predictable excess returns even when agents are risk-neutral. Normandin & St-Amour (1998) include taste shocks in the preference specification of Epstein & Zin (1989) to study their effect on the equity premium. They argue that taste shocks help alleviate the emphasis on the consumption risk in explaining the historical equity premium. More recently, Brandt & Wang (2003) allow for a preference shock in the CC model to be correlated with business-cycle factors. In a similar spirit, Bekaert, et al. (2010) allow for a latent preference shock in the CC model to be imperfectly correlated with consumption growth and interpret it as unexpected change in the "moodiness" of the investor behavior.5

In contrast to previous studies (with the exception of Bekaert, et al. (2009) and Bekaert et al. (2010)), we study the implications of introducing the preference shock to the habit stock to simultaneously explain time series properties of equity and bond returns.6 Our modeling and econometric framework allows us to address, among others, two important empirical questions.

Q1:
Do stochastic habit formation models explain long-term bond returns better than their deterministic counterparts?
Q2:
Do internal habit (IH) formation models and their external counterparts (EH) perform equally well when they are confronted by both equity and bond returns?

The answer to Q1 is an emphatic "yes!" We find that when the habit process is deterministic, the model is incapable of explaining quarterly holding-period returns of long-term bonds, regardless of whether the consumption habit is external or internal. When the consumption habit is internal and stochastic, the model better explains both equity and bond returns simultaneously. This suggests the joint importance of internal habit and taste shock in preferences, absent in models discussed above.

The answer to Q2 is negative. Based on Euler equations derived from the level of the three-month Treasury bill rate, the quarterly return of a 10-year long-term Treasury bond, and the quarterly return of the broad equity market index, the parameter estimates of IH models are all very reasonable. The point estimates of the coefficient of the relative risk aversion in the IH model (either deterministic or stochastic) are around 2, while they are roughly 8 for the deterministic EH models. In contrast, the parameter estimates of the stochastic EH models are such that either the relative risk aversion parameter or the subjective discount rate is in the wrong region when they are unconstrained. When the relative risk aversion parameter and the subjective discount rate are constrained to be positive, we find a corner solution in minimizing the GMM objective function under the optimal weighting matrix. This result suggests that EH models, whether deterministic or stochastic, cannot reconcile various moments of bond returns. Our results are complementary to the results in Dai, et al. (2010). The authors specify the dynamics of state variables (in contrast to our agnostic approach) and construct the maximum likelihood estimates of a nonlinear discrete time dynamic term structure model with CC-type external habit preferences in which bond prices are known in closed form. Consequently, Dai et al. show that such models do not match the key features of the conditional distribution of bond yields.

The data seems to favor internal relative to external habit formation for a reason. Introducing a stochastic shock to an external habits does not affect the the autocorrelation structure of the marginal rate of substitution because its functional form remains the same. In contrast, a stochastic habit shock materially impacts the performance of an internal habit formation model because it induces an additional term in the marginal rate of substitution that makes it more persistent. Our results are consistent with Ljungqvist & Uhlig (2000), who argue that when agents are "catching up with the Joneses", the social welfare in a competitive equilibrium is reduced relative to the socially optimal allocation that takes into account the negative externality of habit formation. Agents consume too much when productivity is high and too little when productivity is low. Government intervention (through income transfer) can induce competitive agents with external habit formation to achieve socially optimal consumption behavior. Thus, aggregate consumption behavior and asset prices seem to be more consistent with internal habit even though agents may exhibit external habit formation at individual levels. Overall, this evidence suggests that stochastic internal habit models should be preferred to their external counterparts when studying the joint behavior of the aggregate stock and bond returns.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we set forth a model specification and derive Euler equations. In Section 3 we discuss methodological issues related to our empirical study. In Section 4 we present empirical results for deterministic/stochastic external and internal habit models, discuss miscellaneous estimation issues and also report some robustness checks. We conclude in Section 5.


2 A CCAPM with stochastic habit formation

We assume that there exists a representative agent with a time non-separable expected utility:

\displaystyle V_0 = E \left[ \left. \sum_{t=0}^\infty\, e^{-\rho t} \, u(s_t) \right\vert I_0 \right], (1)

where  \rho > 0 is the subjective discount rate,  u(\cdot) is strictly increasing and strictly concave,  s_t is the service flow provided by the current and past "surplus consumption"  z_t \equiv c_t - x_t,  c_t is an exogenous aggregate consumption/endowment process,  x_t is the habit stock generated by the past aggregate consumption, and  I_t is the time- t information set. The service flow  s_t and the habit stock  x_t are defined by
\displaystyle s_t \displaystyle = \displaystyle D(L) \, z_t = \sum_{j=0}^\infty \delta^j z_{t-j}, (2)
\displaystyle x_t \displaystyle = \displaystyle B(L) ( 1 + \beta v_t )\, z_{t-1} = b \, \sum_{j=0}^\infty ( 1 - \kappa )^j \left( 1 + \beta v_{t-j} \right)\, z_{t-1-j}, (3)

where, conditional on  I_t,  v_{t+1} is a random variable with zero mean and unit volatility with an arbitrary correlation with the consumption shock,  L is the lag operator, and  D(L) and  B(L) are two geometrically distributed-lag operators:
\displaystyle D(L) = \sum_{j=0}^\infty \delta^j L^j, \,\, B(L) = b \sum_{j=0}^\infty ( 1 - \kappa )^j L^j, \,\, \delta > 0,\, b > 0, \, \kappa > 0.
In this setting,  \delta represents a service flow parameter,  \beta is the volatility of the habit shock,  b is the scaling parameter that indexes the importance of the habit formation level relative to the current consumption level, and  \kappa indexes the degree of "persistence", or "memory" in the habit shock. When  \beta = 0, the model reduces to the time-non-separable utility specification of Dunn & Singleton (1986), Ferson & Constantinides (1991), and Heaton (1995). If, in addition,  \delta = 0, the model reduces further to the habit formation of Sundaresan (1989) and Constantinides (1990), as the decision interval goes to zero. Finally, when  \delta = b = 0, the model reduces to the standard pure exchange economy of Lucas (1978) and Mehra & Prescott (1985) with time-separable utility.


2.1 Stochastic Euler Equations

Following Dunn & Singleton (1986), Ferson & Constantinides (1991), and Heaton (1995), we can derive the stochastic Euler equation for the model specified by equations (1) - (3). In Appendix 6, we show that, for any security with the price-dividend pair  (p_t, d_t), the following pricing equation holds:

\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t, t+1} \times R_{t,t+1} \right] = 1, (4)

where  R_{t,t+1} \equiv \frac{p_{t+1} + d_{t+1}}{p_t} is the one-period return for the security, and MRS is the marginal rate of substitution, given by
MRS\displaystyle _{t,t+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle e^{-\rho}\times \frac{\mbox{MUC}_{t+1}}{\mbox{MUC}_t}, \,\, \mbox{where} (5)
MUC\displaystyle _t \displaystyle = \displaystyle E_t\left[\sum_{j=0}^{\infty} e^{- \rho j}\times a_{t,j}\times u'(s_{t+j}) \right]. (6)

Here MUC _t is the marginal utility of consumption in terms of the value function at  t, and for the geometric distributed lag specification,7
\displaystyle a_{t,j} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \delta^j - \sum_{i=0}^{j-1}\delta^i b_{t,j-i}, \,\, j \geq 1, \,\,\,\, a_{t, 0} = 0, \,\,\,\,   where (7)
\displaystyle b_{t,j} \displaystyle = \begin{displaymath}\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \left[(1-\kappa)\prod_{i=1}^{j-1} - \prod_{i=0}^{j-1}\right][1 - \kappa - b(1 + \beta v_{t+i+1})], & \mbox{(internal),} \ 0, & \mbox{(external).} \end{array} \right.\end{displaymath} (8)

(By convention we set  \prod_{i=1}^0 (\cdot) = 1.)

For an internal habit formation model,  b_{t , j} \not= 0 for  j \geq 1, which means that the individual agent accounts for the consumption externality induced by her own consumption choice. Given a particular model parametrization with internal habit formation, the corresponding model with external habit formation is obtained by setting  b_{t, j} = 0 for all  j \geq 1.

Equation (4) can be extended to deal with returns on investment strategies with multiple holding periods. Let  R_{t,t+n} be the return on an investment strategy held for  n periods, then the same reasoning behind the derivation of (4) implies

\displaystyle E_t \left[ \frac{\mbox{MUC}_{t+n}}{\mbox{MUC}_t} \times R_{t, t+n} \right]= 1.     (9)


2.2 Determinants of MUC and MRS: intuition

To develop some intuition on the relative importance of various ingredients of the model, let us consider a first-order approximation of MUC _t when  \beta is small.8 First, note that when  \beta is small, the approximation of  a_{t, j} is given by

\displaystyle a_{t, j} = \delta^j - b_j ( 1 + \beta v_{t+1} ), \,\,\,\, b_j = b\, (1-\kappa)^{j-1}\, \left[ \frac{1 - \left(\frac{\delta}{1-\kappa} \right)^j}{1 - \frac{\delta}{1-\kappa}} \right], \,\,\,\, \textup{for} \,\,\,\, \forall j \geq 1.
Consequently, MUC _t allows the following decomposition:
\displaystyle \frac{\mbox{MUC}_t}{u'(s_t)} - 1 \displaystyle \approx \begin{displaymath}\begin{array}{cccc} \Psi_t^{(\delta)} + \Psi_t^{(b)} + \Psi_t^{(\beta)}, \end{array}\end{displaymath} (10)

where
\displaystyle \Psi_t^{(\delta)} = E_t \left[ \sum_{j=1}^\infty e^{-\rho j} \delta^j \frac{u'(s_{t+j})}{u'(s_t)} \right] \propto \delta,   \displaystyle \Psi_t^{(b)} = - E_t \left[ \sum_{j=1}^\infty e^{-\rho j} \, b_j \, \frac{u'(s_{t+j})}{u'(s_t)} \right] \propto b,  
\displaystyle \Psi_t^{(\beta)} = \beta \varrho b \bar{\sigma} (1-\gamma) e^{-\rho} S_t^{-1} \propto b \varrho \beta      

represent the expected future marginal utility or dis-utility (depending on the sign), from future service flow and consumption habit. In  \Psi_t^{(\beta)},  \varrho is the correlation between the consumption shock and the habit shock,  \bar{\sigma} is the volatility of the consumption growth rate,  1-\gamma is the relative risk aversion coefficient of the CRRA utility function, and  S_t is the surplus consumption ratio.

Note that  \Psi_t^{(\delta)} = \Psi_t^{(b)} = \Psi_t^{(\beta)} = 0 when  \delta = b = 0 (the time-separable case), and  \Psi_t^{(b)} = \Psi_t^{(\beta)} = 0 whenever  b = 0 (no habit). When  b \not = 0, the relative magnitude of  \Psi_t^{(b)} and  \Psi_t^{(\beta)} depends on, in large part, the relative magnitude of  b, and  \varrho \beta. The magnitude of  \Psi_t^{(\beta)} relative to  \Psi_t^{(b)} is also controlled by the parameter  \kappa, or more precisely the "leverage ratio"  \frac{b}{\kappa}, which is the long-run mean of  (S_t^{-1}-1).

The decomposition (10) provides clear intuition for how model parameters are identified: given the preference parameters  \rho ,  \gamma , and the persistence parameter  \kappa, the parameters  \delta,  b, and  \beta are identified, respectively, from  \Psi_t^{(\delta)},  \Psi_t^{(b)}, and  \Psi_t^{(\beta)}. This intuition is helpful in guiding the choice of asset returns and instruments that help achieve identification and efficiency.

2.3 Discussion

Let  \epsilon_t be the shock to aggregate consumption growth rate. Our model implies that the pricing kernel is a function of the history of both the consumption shock  \epsilon_t and the habit shock  v_t. That is, for any  t < s,

MRS\displaystyle _{t, s} =   M\displaystyle (\epsilon_\tau, v_\tau: \tau \leq s; t, s). (11)

In general, the identity of the shocks that appear in the MRS (which means that they are priced risk factors) and the functional form of the MRS are part of the model specification. In this paper, however, we interpret the stochastic habit formation model as some "reduced-form" specification of an underlying structural model based on micro-economic foundations. In particular, we interpret the shock to the habit level as taste shock, that proxies some economy-wide shock different from the shock to the consumption growth rate. In this way, the aggregate asset returns are driven by two shocks, the endowment shock and the taste shock. Campbell (1986) and Normandin & St-Amour (1998) undertake similar interpretation of the random shocks in the preferences. They study different questions however. Campbell studies the effect of the taste shocks on bond premia, while Normandin & St-Amour study the impact of taste shocks on equity premia. In both papers, multiplicative shocks are added to the utility specifications, albeit to different ones: Campbell considers standard CRRA utility function, while Normandin & St-Amour consider Epstein-Zin preferences. More recently, Bekaert, et al. (2010) develop an extension to the external habit CC model by modeling a stochastic surplus consumption ratio where a preference shock to it is interpreted as an unexpected change in the "moodiness" of the investor behavior. Bekaert, et al. (2009) use this model to study the relative importance of the economic uncertainty (conditional variance of fundamentals) and change in the risk aversion.

Our preference specification (including the habit specification) allows us to derive a specific functional form for MRS. In order to make the model empirically testable, we choose an empirical proxy for the taste shock based on an educated guess of which macro variables may be the most relevant to asset pricing. Consequently, we will be testing the joint hypothesis that the model is correctly specified and the stochastic habit shock is correctly identified. This is important for a proper interpretation of our results.


3 Methodological and econometric issues

In this section, we discuss several methodological and econometric issues related to the estimation and testing of the model. Before we proceed, let us give a brief description of the GMM procedure to establish some notations.

In the most general form with pure habit (  \delta = 0), our model has five parameters, collected in the vector  \theta = (\rho, \gamma, \kappa, b, \beta)'. Let  R_{t,t+n} be a  K \times 1 vector of asset returns, and  Z_t \in J_t be a  M \times 1 vector of instruments. Then under the null, the following  K \cdot M orthogonality conditions must hold:

\displaystyle E\left[ h_{t, t+n} \otimes Z_t \right] = 0, \,\,   where\displaystyle \,\, h_{t, t+n} = \frac{\mbox{MRS}_{t+1}}{\mbox{MRS}_t} \times R_{t,t+n} - 1. (12)

Let  g_T = \frac{1}{T} \sum_{t=1}^{T} \epsilon_{t, t+n} denote the sample counterpart of the left hand side of equation (12), where  T is the sample length and  \epsilon_t is a  K \cdot M \times 1 vector obtained by stacking together all elements of  h_{t,t+n} \otimes Z_t. Then the GMM estimator,  \theta_T, solves
\displaystyle \theta_T =   arg\displaystyle \, \max_{\theta} \, T \, g_T' \, W_T^{-1} \, g_T,
where  W_t is the sample counter-part of the optimal weighting matrix (see Hansen (1982) for additional details).

Under the null, the GMM objective function  T \, g_T' W_T^{-1} g_T has an asymptotic  \chi^2 distribution with degrees of freedom equal to  (KM -   dim (\theta)). This provides an overall goodness-of-fit test.

3.1 Evaluation of the Euler equations

A well-known issue associated with the econometric estimation and test of internal habit formation models is that the "marginal utility of consumption", MUC _t, is defined in terms of the conditional expectation of future marginal utilities (see equation (6)). Two distinct approaches have been adopted to deal with this issue. Dunn & Singleton (1986), Ferson & Constantinides (1991), Ferson & Harvey (1992), etc., adopted the first approach, which avoids the evaluation of the conditional expectations altogether. Specifically, rewriting equation (9) as

\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MUC}_t - \mbox{MUC}_{t+n} \times R_{t,t+n} \right] = 0, (13)

and removing the conditional expectation operator by appealing to the law of iterated expectations, we obtain  E_t [ h_{t, t+n} ] = 0, where
Note that the "disturbance"  h_t has an MA( \infty) autocorrelation structure when the consumption habit is defined as a geometric distributed lag. Dunn & Singleton (1986), Ferson & Constantinides (1991), and Ferson & Harvey (1992) get around this problem by defining the consumption habit in terms of a limited number (typically one and at most two) of consumption lags. If we define the consumption habit using  q lags, then  h_t is MA( q) under the null that the model is correctly specified. This approach does not apply directly in our case because we have  q = \infty. Heaton (1995) adopted the second approach, which explicitly evaluates the conditional expectation by imposing a particular dynamic structure of the relevant state variables. Specifically, Heaton assumes that a bivariate process of aggregate consumption growth and aggregate dividend growth characterizes completely the dynamic evolution of the marginal utility of consumption. By modeling the state vector as a bivariate VAR, MUC _t can be computed numerically (at the estimated parameter values for the VAR). Heaton estimates the preference parameters using the simulated method of moments.

In principle, we can follow Heaton's approach to estimate our model. An added benefit of adopting Heaton's approach is that there is no requirement that the stochastic habit shock be observed. Our concerns about potential mis-specification errors associated with the VAR specification of the state vector and potential numerical errors in computing MUC _t, however, lead us to develop a new approach. The idea is to rewrite the Euler equation (13) as

\displaystyle E \left[ \left. \Phi_t - e^{-\rho n} \times \Phi_{t+n} \times \frac{u'(s_{t+n})}{u'(s_t)} \times R_{t, t+n} \right\vert I_t \right] = 0, (15)

where  I_t is the information set at  t, and
\displaystyle \Phi_t \equiv \sum_{j=0}^\infty e^{-\rho j} a_{t, j} \frac{u'(s_{t+j})}{u'(s_t)}.
Note that for pure external habit formation models (  \delta = 0 and  b_{t, j} = 0 for all  j \geq 1),  \Phi_t = 1, and the Euler equation is trivial to compute. For internal habit formation models (with or without local substitution), we adopt the following strategy.

First, we construct an information set  J_t \subseteq I_t that includes all the instruments we will use for estimating the model as well as  z_t \equiv \frac{u'(s_{t})}{u'(s_{t-n})} \times R_{t-n, t} and an appropriate number of its lags. Second, we condition the Euler equation (15) down to the information set  J_t:

\displaystyle E \left[ \left. \Phi_t - e^{-\rho n} \times \Phi_{t+n} \times \frac{u'(s_{t+n})}{u'(s_t)} \times R_{t, t+n} \right\vert J_t \right] = 0. (16)

Finally, we compute the linear projection of  \Phi_t into the information set  J_t, and substitute the projection  \hat{\Phi}_t into equation (16). Since the projection error,  \epsilon_t \equiv \Phi_t - \hat{\Phi}_t, is orthogonal to  J_t - by construction, equation (16) implies
\displaystyle E \left[ \left. \hat{h}_{t, t+n} \right\vert J_t \right] = 0, (17)

where
\displaystyle \hat{h}_{t, t+n} = \hat{\Phi}_t - e^{-\rho n} \times \hat{\Phi}_{t+n} \times \frac{u'(s_{t+n})}{u'(s_t)} \times R_{t, t+n}. (18)

Equations (17) and (18) are the "projected" Euler equations that we actually use in our econometric analysis. Under the null, the vector of projected disturbances  \hat{h}_{t, t+n} has a MA( n-1) autocorrelation structure. In particular, for one-period returns,  n=1,  \hat{h}_{t,t+1} should be martingale difference sequences.

The projection procedure does not affect consistency of the GMM estimators. However, it does affect inference. To obtain standard errors and test statistics properly, we need to (a) compute standard errors with the projection fixed at the converged parameter estimates; and (b) account for sampling noise in the first-stage linear projection when we compute the standard errors and test statistics in the second (GMM) stage.9

3.2 Empirical proxy for a stochastic habit (taste) shock

Implicit in our model is the assumption that economic agents observe both consumption and habit shocks, conditional on which consumption and portfolio demands are formed. As a consequence, the Euler disturbances  h_{t, t+n} or their projected versions  \hat{h}_{t, t+n} can not be constructed using consumption and return data alone, because they also depend on the realizations of the habit shock  v_1, \ldots, v_{t+n-1}, v_{t+n}. If the habit(taste) shocks are not observed by the econometrician, they must be integrated out in the Euler equations. Our new approach assumes that the econometrician also observes the habit shock, and identifies it with the shock to one of the observed macro-economic variables. Thus, our model should be treated as a semi-structural model (based on a particular parametric specification of the habit process and a particular assumption on the identity of the habit shocks). While we do not provide a formal justification for our semi-structural specification, we motivate our choice by the following intuition.

There are several reasons why the aggregate labor income shock may be a sensible empirical proxy for the stochastic habit shock. First, a growing body of work in asset pricing literature (see, e.g., Jagannathan & Wang (1996) and Lettau & Ludvigson (2001a)) suggests that aggregate labor income risk is a relevant source of risk factor in explaining equity returns. Second, a growing body of work in macroeconomics literature (see, e.g., Calvo (1983) and Christiano, et al. (2005)) suggests that both real marginal cost, which is closely related to the aggregate labor share, and wage rigidity are important in driving inflation and channeling the propagation of monetary shocks through the real economy. Both strands of literature suggest that labor income risk may play a non-trivial role in explaining asset returns, through either the cash flows (dividend and inflation risks) or the discount rates (pricing kernel). Since we take asset returns and endowment processes as given, the only place that the labor income risk can play a role is through the utility specification. In our framework, it can only enter the model through the shock to the habit stock. We directly estimate the sensitivity of the habit shock to the labor income shock (as the volatility of the habit shock) from the Euler equations.10

3.3 Miscellaneous issues

A practical issue that arises in estimating internal habit formation models is that the ex post realization of the marginal utility of consumption, namely (see equation (6)),

\displaystyle \sum_{j=0}^{\infty} e^{- \rho j}\, a_{t,j}\, u'(s_{t+j}),
may be negative. The situation occurs when the current consumption level is very high relative to subsequent realized level of consumption, so that the future dis-utility induced by the current high level of consumption is very large. This can be caused by a number of reasons. First, the model could be mis-specified. Second, even if the model is correctly specified, the realized MUC may be negative if it is not evaluated at the true parameter values. Third, even if the model is correctly specified, and the realized MUC is evaluated at the true parameter values, there is always a possibility that in a finite sample, random noises may drive the realized MUC negative. Optimality restrictions on the equilibrium consumption process only requires that the ex ante marginal utility of consumption be non-negative.

We base our estimation and testing procedure on the assumption that the null is correctly specified. This means that we need to impose restrictions on the admissible parameter region so that the ex post MUC stays positive. Such restrictions are also helpful in practice in making the GMM objective function more robust and the GMM estimation easier to converge. Finally, we check that the ex post MUC is strictly positive at the converged parameter estimates and the parametric restrictions that ensure MUC positivity are not binding.

Another practical issue is that based on the observed data, there is no guarantee that the surplus consumption  z_t \equiv c_t - x_t is strictly positive, because a large realization of the habit shock can send  x_t above  c_t under at least some parameter configurations. Fortunately, under realistic parameter values, this occurs only infrequently. Since this situation occurs at the tail end of the steady-state distribution, and most interesting economic behavior takes place at or near the long-run mean of the steady-state distribution, we can deal with this issue by designing a utility function  u(s) that coincides with a standard CRRA specification when s is sufficiently far away from 0, and is still well-behaved when  s is close to zero or slightly negative.11

This is not an unknown issue that arises with additive habit models. It has been addressed in the literature in the different context. Detemple & Zapatero (1991) impose a nonlinear parameter restriction to insure the nonnegativity of marginal utility. In addition, Chapman (1998) constructs an example of an endowment economy with linear internal habit formation such that implies negative marginal utility of with probability one. His calibration exercise assumes a specific endowment process (lognormal diffusion, Eq. (6), pg. 1225), which we are agnostic about. He finds that marginal utility is negative for a CRRA utility function when relative risk aversion is set to a specific range of values and other endowment process parameters match the sample moments of standard aggregate consumption and returns data. Yogo (2008) solves this issue by proposing a power reference-dependent utility function in which the representative household has power gain-loss utility in the spirit of Tversky & Kahneman (1992). In this set up, the marginal utility is always positive even when consumption falls below its subsistence (reference) level, by virtue of imposing the absolute value function on the difference between consumption and its subsistence level. For us, it is more a practical than modeling issue as we abstract from the specific form of the endowment process in the economy.

Finally, in a finite sample, it is not possible to construct the ex post realization of MUC as an infinite sum. All of our estimation results are based on truncating the infinite sum to 50 terms, which corresponds to the assumption that a habit shock dies out before twelve and half years. This represents a sufficiently long period for the MUC to be affected by habit shock so long as the mean reversion parameter  \kappa for the habit shock is not too small.


4 Empirical results

In this section, we report key empirical findings. We begin by describing the data. We then report estimation results and address the questions Q1 and Q2 raised in the introduction.


4.1 Data

Summary statistics of the macro variables and asset returns are reported in Table 1.

Consumption:
We use quarterly consumption data to estimate our model because it contains less measurement errors than monthly consumption data.12 Quarterly decision interval also allows us to focus on pure habit effect, as Heaton (1995) shows that local substitution is important only for decision intervals much shorter than a quarter. Consequently, we set  \delta = 0 throughout our empirical estimations. Our sample period is from the fourth quarter of 1951 to the fourth quarter of 2002.

We measure aggregate consumption as expenditures on non-durables and services excluding shoes and clothing.13 In order to distinguish between long-term habit persistence and short-term seasonality, we use seasonally adjusted data at annual rates, in billions of chain-weighted 2000 dollars.14 We define aggregate labor income as wages and salaries plus transfer payments plus other labor income minus personal contributions for social insurance minus taxes. Real aggregate labor income is obtained by deflating nominal aggregate labor income by the implicit chain-type price deflator (2000=100).

Real per capita consumption and labor income is obtained by dividing real aggregates by a measure of U.S. population. The latter is obtained by dividing real total disposable income by real per capita disposable income. Consumption, labor income, price deflator, and measure of population are obtained from NIPA (National Income and Product Account) tables.15

Asset returns:
Nominal quarterly U.S. broad value-weighted equity index returns as well as three-month and 10-year Treasury Bond Portfolio returns are obtained from CRSP (Center for Research in Security Prices). Real asset returns are deflated by the implicit chain-type price deflator (2000=100).
Instruments:
We use two sets of instruments. The first one is the standard set of lagged consumption growth and asset returns used in the previous studies to estimate the parameters and test the Euler equation model. One of the potential problems with consumption data is time aggregation, which means that consumption decisions are made more frequently than the observation interval, and thus, measured consumption is the sum of the expenditures of the interval. Ferson & Constantinides (1991) argue that time aggregation can induce a spurious correlation between the error terms and information set, thereby increasing the order of the MA process followed by  u_t. Variables in the information set at time  t, which were not in the information set at  t-1, may not be valid instruments for testing over-identifying restrictions (12). We nevertheless estimate our model using this set of instruments for comparative purposes. Another set of variables is described in Section 4.7.

Next, we need to obtain the habit shock  v_t. We proxy  v_t as the aggregate labor income shock obtained from the following bivariate process with 4 lags for  f_t = (c_t,\, w_t)':

\displaystyle f_t = A_0 + A_1 f_{t-1} + A_2 f_{t-2} + A_3 f_{t-3} + A_4 f_{t-4} + \Sigma u_t,     (20)

where  c_t is the log real per capita consumption growth,  w_t is the log real per capita labor income growth,  u_t \sim N(0, I). The residuals from the estimated VAR equation (20) are plotted in Figure 1.

To get a sense of what the habit stock looks like under reasonable parameterizations of the model, Figure 2 plots real consumption, habit stock, and surplus consumption based on the following baseline parameterization:  \rho = 0.01,\, \gamma = -2,\, \kappa = 0.028,\, b = 0.372,\, \delta = 0,\, \beta = 0. These parameters correspond roughly to those calibrated by Dai (2003), so they are broadly consistent with some key moments of equity and bond returns.

4.2 Deterministic habit: risk premium

We begin by estimating the risk-aversion parameter  \gamma for three models with no habit (NH), deterministic external habit (DEH), and deterministic internal habit (DIH).16 For the model with no habit,  b = \kappa = 0. For habit models, we fix  b = 0.328 and  \kappa = 0.072, which correspond to a pair of values for  a = \kappa + b and  b used by Constantinides (1990). Grishchenko (2010) estimates these parameters in the deterministic habit model set up and finds that they are broadly consistent with Constantinides (1990) values.17 For all three models, we fix  \rho = 0.01. The instruments used for the estimation include two lags of consumption growth rates and two lags of equity returns. Estimation results are reported in Table 2. There are two panels in the table. The top panel reports results when the excess return on the value-weighted NYSE index is used to identify the risk aversion parameter. For NH model, the estimate for the relative risk aversion  1-\gamma is 85.9148. Thus, we recover the equity premium puzzle. For DEH model, the coefficient  1-\gamma drops down to  8.9498, indicating that the presence of consumption habit helps resolve the equity premium puzzle. For DIH model, the coefficient  1-\gamma reduces further to 2.90. For all three models, the parameter  \gamma is sharply identified, and the over-identifying restrictions implied by the equity premium, alone, are not rejected.18 At this point, the data favor the DIH, with much lower  \chi^2 than either NH or DEH. The bottom panel reports estimation results when both the equity premium and the risk premium on a long-term 10-year Treasury bond are used under the same model specifications and same parameterization.19 The coefficients of the relative risk aversion decline as we proceed from NH to DEH, and then to DIH, and have a similar magnitude to Panel A's estimates of RRA. Including a long-term bond represents an additional challenge for the models. Indeed, the  p-values for the overall goodness-of-fit test decline for all three models. So, we reject all three models when a long-term bond is included in the estimation.20

The results reported in Table 2 confirm some well-known facts about the standard CCAPM and deterministic habit formation models. First, the equity premium can be fit easily if there is no constraint on the curvature of the utility function, namely,  1-\gamma. The equity premium puzzle arises because the relative risk aversion parameter required to fit the equity premium is too large relative to what is required to explain individual behavior (in terms of portfolio holdings and life-cycle patterns). Second, these models do not explain long-term bond risk premium. Adding long-term bond risk premium leads to the deterioration of the model fit. Intuitively, the real interest rate risk and the consumption growth rate are very weakly correlated in the data (about -0.025), and have the opposite sign (negative) from what a standard consumption-based model would predict (positive). Since deterministic habit merely amplifies the risk premium, and does not affect the sign of the risk premium, all three models (NH, DEH, and DIH) would predict the wrong sign for bond risk premium when  1-\gamma is positive. This basic tension in CCAPM and deterministic habit formation models is even more apparent when the models are forced to explain short-term interest rate as well. We will now consider this case.

4.3 Deterministic habit: risk-free rate and risk premium

In Table 3, we free up the subjective discount rate  \rho in our three basic models (NH, DEH, DIH), and use the risk-free rate (3-month T-bill rate) to generate additional moment conditions to identify  \rho . The models are still required to fit both the equity premium,  R^m_{t,t+1} - R^f_{t,t+1}, and the 10-year bond risk premium,  R^{b, 10}_{t,t+1} - R^f_{t,t+1}, (so that the risk aversion parameter  1-\gamma is identified). Two panels in Table 3 correspond exactly to the panels in Table 2, except that in the former, the risk-free rate also enters the Euler equation, and two lags of the risk-free rate serve as additional instruments.

The top panel shows that DIH is able to explain both the risk-free rate and the equity premium at reasonable values of  \rho and  \gamma :  \hat{\rho} = 0.04 and  \hat{\gamma} = -0.93. In contrast, NH and DEH models are rejected based on the conventional levels of  p-values. In addition, the parameter values have the wrong signs. A priori, we expect  \rho > 0 (agents are impatient) and  \gamma < 0 (agents are more risk averse than log-utility). When  \gamma is constrained to be non-positive in the estimation, GMM finds the corner solution  \gamma = 0. The bottom panel shows that including the 10-year bond return leads to substantial deterioration of all three models. The point estimates are qualitatively similar to those in the top panel, indicating that the long-term bond return does not have much bite in the context of these models.

To understand this behavior, note that there are two basic forces that pull the risk aversion parameter in two different directions in these models. First, the negative correlation between the real consumption growth rate and the real risk-free rate can be explained only if  1-\gamma is negative. Second, the high equity premium can be explained only if  1-\gamma is positive and large. Both NH and DEH give up explaining the equity premium in order to reconcile with the negative correlation between the consumption growth and risk-free rate.

Since  0 < 1-\gamma < 1, the level of the risk-free rate can be fit only if the subjective discount rate is negative. To see this, note that, in NH, the unconditional mean of the Euler equation for the risk-free rate implies approximately (under the assumption that the consumption growth rate is i.i.d.) that  e^{- \rho/4} \times e^{-(1-\gamma) \times g/4 + \frac{(1-\gamma)^2}{2} \sigma^2 / 4} = e^{-r/4}, or  \rho = r - (1-\gamma) \times g + \frac{(1-\gamma)^2}{2} \sigma^2. where  g = 3.15\% is the average consumption growth rate (consumption plus service),  \sigma = 1.28\% is the volatility of the consumption growth rate, and  r = 1.4\% is the average risk-free rate (see Table 1 for the sample moments). For  \gamma = 0.1672,  \rho = -0.006. For DEH, the risk-free rate is priced by the growth rate of the surplus consumption ratio, which has the same mean growth rate of  g, but a higher volatility:  \sigma \approx 1.28\% \times \frac{b + \kappa}{\kappa} = 7.11\%. This implies  \rho = 1.6\%. Alternatively, the estimated value of  \rho implies that  r = 0.26\% for NH and  r = -2.35\% for DEH.

4.4 Stochastic habit: risk premium

Next, we explore the benefit of introducing a stochastic shock to the consumption habit by freeing up the parameter  \beta . The resulting habit models are denoted SEH (for stochastic external habit) and SIH (for stochastic internal habit). Table 4 reports results when  \gamma and  \beta are jointly estimated using the excess return on a broad stock market index and the excess return on the 10-year Treasury bond. As a simple robustness check, we report results based on three different measures of equity market returns: value-weighted NYSE index return, value-weighted NYSE/AMEX index return, and value-weighted NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ index return. The results are qualitatively the same. Thus, we will now focus on results based on value-weighted NYSE index return (Panel A).

For both models, the risk-aversion parameter  \gamma is sharply identified and qualitatively similar to those reported in the Panel B of Table 2. SEH yields  \hat{\gamma} = -8.53 whereas SIH produces  \hat{\gamma} = -2.91. The habit volatility parameter  \beta is not very precisely identified in SEH, but is sharply identified in SIH:  \hat{\beta}(SEH) = 0.0047 with the standard error of 0.0496,  \hat{\beta}(SIH) = -0.0254 with the standard error of 0.0116. We reject SEH at conventional confidence levels whereas we do not reject SIH. Both results indicate that introducing a stochastic shock in the external habit formation model does not help very much in explaining risk premium on both equity and long term bonds. In contrast, it has a very significant positive impact on the goodness-of-fit of the internal habit formation model.

4.5 Stochastic habit: risk-free rate and risk premium

Next, we free up the subjective discount factor  \rho in addition to  \gamma and  \beta parameters. Table 5 reports the estimation results when  \rho ,  \gamma , and  \beta are jointly estimated, using the risk-free rate, the value-weighted NYSE index return, and the 10-year Treasury bond return. Comparing these results to those reported in Panel B of Table 3, we see a larger improvement for the goodness-of-fit for SIH than for SEH. For internal habit specifications we have:  \chi^2 (DIH) = 50.26 vs.  \chi^2 (SIH) = 43.77. However, for external habit specifications we have:  \chi^2 (DEH) = 51.04 vs.  \chi^2 (SEH) = 46.86. These differences are also reflected in the fact that the parameter  \beta is not sharply identified in SEH, whereas it is sharply identified in SIH:  \hat{\beta}(SEH) = -0.2128 with the standard error of 0.2340,  \hat{\beta}(SIH) = -0.0133 with the standard error of 0.0040. In addition, SEH model does not seem to have an ability to identify the subjective discount rate:  \hat{\rho} = -0.0030 with the standard error of 0.0127. However, the point estimate of the subjective discount rate in the SIH model is well identified, albeit low.

4.6 Discussion

The reported empirical results help answer the two questions raised in the introduction. Our results show that introducing a shock to the consumption habit allows the model to explain long-term bond returns better than deterministic habit formation models. Furthermore, the beneficial effect of a habit shock is much more evident in internal rather than in external habit formation models. To understand these results, we note that the habit shock may help explain asset returns because it can potentially modify the autocorrelation property of the marginal rate of substitution. In an external habit formation model, the habit shock affects the marginal rate of substitution' autocorrelation property only through the surplus consumption ratio dynamics. The reason is that the functional form of the MRS,

MRS\displaystyle _{t, t+1} = e^{-\rho} \, \frac{\mbox{MUC}_{t+1}}{\mbox{MUC}_t}, \,\, \mbox{MUC}_t = u'(z_t), \,\, z_t = c_t - x_t,
remains the same as that derived from a deterministic external habit formation model. Since the addition of a new shock does not materially affect the growth rate of the surplus consumption ratio, the MRS continues to have difficulty reconciling the autocorrelation structure of long-term bond returns. In contrast, the presence of the habit shock materially affects the functional form of the internal MRS. To develop some intuition, we again appeal to the first-order Taylor expansion introduced in Section 2.2. Within the context of the model specification estimated here, the marginal utility of consumption for an internal habit formation model is given by
   MUC\displaystyle _t \approx u'(z_t) + \Psi_t^{(b)} + \beta \lambda S_t^{-1},
where  \Psi_t^{(b)} captures the expected future dis-utility due to internal habit, and the last term captures the effect of habit shock on the marginal utility of consumption. Therefore, the presence of the habit shock alters the properties of the MRS in a fundamental way. In particular, it makes the MRS more persistent.


4.7 Additional tests and robustness checks

  1. Standard errors. Standard errors reported above are based on two-stage estimation (linear projection and GMM as separate stages). This two-step procedure might affect inference. The results from one-stage estimation (linear projection and GMM in one step) indicate that while all standard errors are larger due to sampling noises in the linear projection coefficients, they do not qualitatively change the conclusions. In particular, parameter estimates in internal habit formation models are different from zero at the conventional levels of statistical significance.
  2. Instrumental variables. We have also used other instruments to check the robustness of our results: unit vector, lagged values of consumption growth, a proxy for the log consumption-wealth ratio  cay_t,21 "relative T-bill rate" ( RREL, which is measured as the three-month T-bill rate minus its four-quarter moving average) and the lagged value of the excess return on the Standard&Poor 500 (SP&500) stock market index ( SPEX) over the three-month T-bill rate. Lettau & Ludvigson (2001a) find that  cay_t has a strong predictive power for stock returns over one quarter to several year horizons. In their subsequent (2001b) paper they show that this variable forecasts portfolio returns too. Campbell (1991), Hodrick (1992), and Lettau & Ludvigson (2001a) find that  RREL has a forecasting power for excess returns at a quarterly frequency.22 One of the problems associated with nonlinear GMM is the weak instruments problem, or the weak identification problem of the model parameter vector  \theta. While this issue can be identified more easily in the linear instrumental variables models, it is more difficult to deal with it in the present set up. Stock, et al. (2002) provide an excellent survey of this issue.23 They argue that one of the informal detection of the weak identification in the GMM setting can be done through addition or change of instrumental variables. Our results show that the choice of instruments does not affect results qualitatively, and therefore, it is unlikely that our results are driven by the presence of weak instruments in our set up.


5 Conclusion

In this paper, we econometrically estimate and test a consumption-based asset pricing model with stochastic habit formation using generalized method of moments. The key contribution to the asset pricing literature on habit formation is the study of the novel preference specification, namely, stochastic internal habit formation. The model departs from existing models with deterministic internal habit (e.g., Dunn & Singleton (1986), Ferson & Constantinides (1991), and Heaton (1995)), by introducing shocks to the coefficients in the distributed lag specification of consumption habit and consequently an additional shock to the marginal rate of substitution. Stochastic shocks to the consumption habit are persistent and provide an additional source of time-variation in expected returns. Economically, we interpret shocks as taste shocks in the economy. Empirically, we proxy these unobserved shocks by aggregate labor income shocks. We show that stochastic internal habit formation models resolve the dichotomy between the autocorrelation properties of stochastic discount factor and those of expected returns, providing a better explanation of time-variation in expected equity and long-term bond returns than models with either deterministic or stochastic external habit. This evidence suggests that stochastic internal habit models should be preferred to external habit counterparts when studying the joint behavior of the aggregate stock and bond returns.

Appendix


6 Derivation of the stochastic Euler equation

Consider an arbitrary security with price-dividend pair  (p_t, d_t). Suppose that, at  t, the representative agent buys  \alpha share of the security and holds it for one period, she gives up  \alpha p_t of consumption at  t, but receives additional consumption  \alpha (p_{t+1} + d_{t+1}). Since no-trade is optimal for the representative agent,  \alpha = 0 is the solution to

\displaystyle V_t = \max_{\alpha} \, E\left[ \left. u(\tilde{s}_t) + E\left[ \left. \sum_{j=1}^\infty e^{-\rho j} u(\tilde{s}_{t+j}) \right\vert c_{t+1} + \alpha (p_{t+1}+d_{t+1}), \tilde{x}_{t+1} \right] \right\vert c_t - \alpha p_t, x_t \right],
where  \tilde{s}_t and  \tilde{x}_t are the service flow and habit process defined over the consumption process  \tilde{c}_t with
\displaystyle \tilde{c}_\tau \displaystyle = \displaystyle c_\tau - \alpha p_\tau, \,\,   if\displaystyle \,\, \tau = t,  
\displaystyle \tilde{c}_\tau \displaystyle = \displaystyle c_\tau + \alpha (p_\tau + d_\tau), \,\,   if\displaystyle \,\, \tau = t+1,  
\displaystyle \tilde{c}_\tau \displaystyle = \displaystyle c_\tau, \,\,   otherwise\displaystyle .  

The first order condition with respect to  \alpha, evaluated at  \alpha = 0, gives
\displaystyle p_t \, \frac{\partial V_t^*}{\partial c_t} = E_t \left[ e^{-\rho} \, (p_{t+1} + d_{t+1}) \, \frac{\partial V_{t+1}^*}{\partial c_{t+1}} \right],
where  V_t^* = E_t \left[ \sum_{j=0}^\infty e^{-\rho j} u(s_{t+j}) \right]. Rearranging terms, we obtain equation (5).

Evaluating the derivative of  V_t^* with respect to  c_t explicitly:

MUC\displaystyle _t = \mathbb{E}_t\left[\sum_{j=0}^{\infty}e^{- \rho j}\, u'(s_{t+j}) \, a_{t,j} \right],     (21)

where  a_{t, j} = \frac{\partial s_{t+j}}{\partial c_t} = 1. Equation (6) is obtained by noting that
\displaystyle \frac{\partial s_{{t+j}}}{\partial c_t} \displaystyle = \begin{displaymath}\frac{\partial }{\partial c_t}\left( \frac{c_{t+j}}{1 - \delta L} - \frac{x_{t+j}}{1 - \delta L} \right) = \left\{ \begin{array}{l} 1, \,\, j = 0, \ \delta^j - \sum_{i=0}^{j-1}\delta^i\frac{\partial x_{t+j-i}}{\partial c_t}, \,\, j > 0, \end{array} \right.\end{displaymath}  
\displaystyle \frac{\partial x_{t+j}}{\partial c_t} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \left\{ \begin{array}{l} b (1 + \beta v_{t+1}), \,\, j = 1, \ \frac{\partial x_{t+1}}{\partial c_t}\prod_{i=1}^{j-1} \left[1-\kappa-b (1 + \beta v_{t+i+1}) \right], \,\, j > 1. \end{array} \right.  


7 Distributed lag with arbitrary weights

Suppose that  \delta = 0, and  x_{t+1} = \sum_{j=0}^J b_j \, (1 + \beta v_{t+1-j}) z_{t-j}, then  a_{t,0} = 1,  a_{t,j} = - b_{t,j},  b_{t,j} \equiv \frac{\partial x_{t+j}}{\partial c_t} for  j \geq 1. The time-varying coefficients  \{b_{t, j}: j \geq 1\} capture an extra unit of current consumption's marginal effect on future habit levels, and can be computed through the following recursion:

\displaystyle b_{t, 1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \phi_{t, 0},  
\displaystyle b_{t,k+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \phi_{t+k,k} - \sum_{j=0}^{k-1} \phi_{t+k,j} \, b_{t,k-j}, \,\, 1 \leq k \leq J,  
\displaystyle b_{t,k+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle - \sum_{j=0}^{J} \phi_{t+k, j} \, b_{t, k-j}, \,\, k > J.  

where  \phi_{t+k, j} = b_j ( 1 + \beta v_{t+1+k-j}) \in I_{t+1+k-j} for  0 \leq j \leq k and  0 \leq k \leq J. Note that  \phi_{t+j,j} = b_j (1 + \beta v_{t+1}) \in I_{t+1} for  \forall j. If  b_j = b (1-\kappa)^j, then the recursion simplifies to:
\displaystyle b_{t, 1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle \phi_{t, 0},  
\displaystyle b_{t,k+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle b_{t,1} \prod_{j=1}^{k} \left( 1 - \kappa - \phi_{t+j,0} \right), 1\leq k \leq J,  
\displaystyle b_{t,k+1} \displaystyle = \displaystyle - \sum_{j=0}^{J} \phi_{t+k, j} \, b_{t, k-j}, \,\, k > J.  

If  J = \infty, we do not need the second equation, and the first equation recovers the result for the geometric distributed lag specification.


Bibliography

A. B. Abel (1990).
Asset prices under habit formation and catching up with the Joneses'.
American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 80:38-42.
G. Bekaert, et al. (2010).
Stock and bond pricing with moody investors'.
Journal of Empirical Finance 17:867-894.
G. Bekaert, et al. (2009).
Risk, uncertainty, and asset prices'.
Journal of Financial Economics 91(1):59-82.
A. S. Blinder, et al. (1985).
The time series consumption function revisited'.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1985(2):465-521.
M. Brandt & K. Wang (2003).
Time-varying risk aversion and unexpected inflation'.
Journal of Monetary Economics 50(7):1457-1498.
A. Buraschi & A. Jiltsov (2007).
Habit formation and macroeconomic models of the term structure of interest rates'.
Journal of Finance 62(6):3009-3063.
G. A. Calvo (1983).
Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework'.
Journal of Monetary Economics 12(3):383-396.
J. Campbell & J. Cochrane (1999).
By force of habit: A consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior'.
Journal of Political Economy 107(2):205-251.
J. Y. Campbell (1986).
Bond and stock returns in a simple exchange model'.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics 101(4):785-804.
J. Y. Campbell (1991).
A variance decomposition for stock returns'.
Economic Journal 101(405):157-179.
J. Y. Campbell & R. J. Shiller (1991).
Yield spreads and interest rate movements: A bird's eye view'.
Review of Economic Studies 58:495-514.
D. A. Chapman (1998).
Notes and comments: Habit formation and aggregate consumption'.
Econometrica 66(5):1223-1230.
X. Chen & S. C. Ludvigson (2009).
Land of addicts? An empirical investigation of habit-based asset pricing models'.
Journal of Applied Econometrics 24(7):1057-1093.
L. J. Christiano, et al. (2005).
Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy'.
Journal of Political economy 113(1):1-45.
G. Constantinides (1990).
Habit formation: A resolution of the equity premium puzzle'.
Journal of Political Economy 98(3):519-543.
Q. Dai (2003).
Term structure dynamics in a model with stochastic internal habit formation'.
Mimeo, NYU.
Q. Dai, et al. (2010).
Discrete-time affine term structure models with generalized market prices of risk'.
Review of Financial Studies 23(5).
J. B. Detemple & F. Zapatero (1991).
Asset prices in an exchange economy with habit formation'.
Econometrica 59(6):1633-1657.
D. Duffie & K. Singleton (1993).
Simulated moments estimation of Markov models of asset prices'.
Econometrica 61:929-952.
K. Dunn & K. Singleton (1983).
An empirical analysis of the pricing of mortgage backed securities'.
Journal of Finance 36:769-799.
K. Dunn & K. Singleton (1986).
Modeling the term structure of interest rates under nonseparable utility and durability of goods'.
Journal of Financial Economics 17:27-55.
L. Epstein & S. Zin (1989).
Substitution, risk aversion and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: A theoretical framework'.
Econometrica 57:937-969.
W. E. Ferson & G. M. Constantinides (1991).
Habit formation and durability in aggregate consumption: empirical tests'.
Journal of Financial Economics 29:199-240.
W. E. Ferson & C. R. Harvey (1992).
Seasonality and consumption-based asset pricing'.
Journal of Finance 47(2):511-552.
A. R. Gallant & G. Tauchen (1996).
Which moments to match?'.
Econometric Theory 12:657-681.
C. Gourieroux, et al. (1993).
Indirect inference'.
Journal of Applied Econometrics 8:S85-S118.
O. V. Grishchenko (2010).
Internal vs external habit formation: The relative importance for asset pricing'.
Journal of Economics and Business 62:176-194.
L. Hansen (1982).
Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators'.
Econometrica 50:1029-1286.
J. Heaton (1995).
An empirical investigation of asset pricing with temporically dependent preference specifications'.
Econometrica 63(3):681-717.
C. Heyerdahl-Larsen (2010).
Asset prices and real exchange rates with deep habits'.
Working paper, London Business School.
R. J. Hodrick (1992).
Dividend yields and expected stock returns: Alternative procedures for inference and measurement'.
Review of Financial Studies 5:357-386.
R. Jagannathan & W. Wang (1996).
The conditional CAPM and the cross-section of expected returns'.
Journal of Finance 51(1):3-53.
M. Lettau & S. Ludvigson (2001a).
Consumption, aggregate wealth, and expected stock returns'.
Journal of Finance 56(3):815-849.
M. Lettau & S. Ludvigson (2001b).
Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A cross-sectional test when risk premia are time-varying'.
Journal of Political Economy 109(6):1238-1287.
L. Ljungqvist & H. Uhlig (2000).
Tax policy and agregate demand management under catching up with the Joneses'.
The American Economic Review 90(3):356-366.
R. Lucas (1978).
Asset prices in an exchange economy'.
Econometrica 46:1429-1445.
R. Mehra & E. C. Prescott (1985).
The equity premium: A puzzle'.
Journal of Monetary Economics 15:145-161.
F. Modigliani & R. Sutch (1966).
Innovations in interest rate policy'.
The American Economic Review 56(1/2):178-197.
M. Normandin & P. St-Amour (1998).
Substitution, risk aversion, taste shocks and equity premia'.
Journal of Applied Econometrics 13(3):265-281.
T. Santos & P. Veronesi (2010).
Habit formation, the cross section of stock returns and the cash flow risk puzzle'.
Journal of Financial Economics 98(2):385-413.
K. J. Singleton (1993).
Econometric implications of consumption-based asset pricing models'.
In J. J. Laffont & C. A. Sims (eds.), Advances in Econometrics, Sixth World Congress. Cambridge University Press.
J. H. Stock & J. H. Wright (2000).
GMM with weak identification'.
Econometrica 68:1055-1096.
J. H. Stock, et al. (2002).
A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized method of moments'.
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 20(4).
S. M. Sundaresan (1989).
Intertemporally dependent preferences and the volatility of consumption and wealth'.
Review of Financial Studies 2:73-88.
A. Tversky & D. Kahneman (1992).
Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty'.
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5:297-323.
J. H. Van Binsbergen (2007).
Deep habits and the cross section of expected returns'.
SSRN eLibrary, http://ssrn.com/paper=1101456.
J. Wachter (2006).
A consumption-based model of the term structure of interest rates'.
Journal of Financial Economics 79(2):365-399.
M. Yogo (2008).
Asset prices under habit formation and reference-dependent preferences'.
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 26(2).
Figure 1: VAR residuals.
Consumption and labor income data are measured as log real per capita consumption growth and log real labor income growth. The sample period is from 1952:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

This figure presents residuals from the estimated Vector Auto Regression Model (20). Consumption and labor income data are measured as log real per capita consumption growth and log real labor income growth. The sample period is from 1952:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

Figure 2: Consumption, habit stock, and surplus consumption.
Panel A represents consumption, habit stock, and surplus consumption level time series for model parameters rho = 0.01, gamma = -2, kappa = 0.072,b = 0.328, beta = 0. Panel B presents consumption, habit stock, and surplus consumption growth rates. The sample period is from 1952:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

Panel A represents consumption, habit stock, and surplus consumption level time series for model parameters  \rho = 0.01, \gamma = -2, \kappa = 0.072,\ b = 0.328,\, \beta = 0. Panel B presents consumption, habit stock, and surplus consumption growth rates. The sample period is from 1952:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.


Table 1: Descriptive statistics
This table reports means, standard deviations and the first five autocorrelations of the data. Panel A reports the statistics of aggregate seasonally-adjusted (SA) real quarterly consumption series and aggregate labor income. NDS refers to nondurable consumption plus services. Panel B reports the statistics of the real quarterly returns on value-weighted portfolios on NYSE, NYSE and AMEX, and NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ exchanges. Panel C reports the statistics of the real quarterly returns on Treasury bond indices. Nominal returns are converted into real returns by dividing them by one plus the growth rate of the seasonally unadjusted Consumer Price Index. The sample period is from 1947:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

Panel A: Macroeconomic variables statistics

  Mean Std. Dev.  \rho_1  \rho_2  \rho_3  \rho_4  \rho_5
Nondurables plus services, SA 0.0315 0.0128 0.3125 0.2017 0.2057 0.0717 0.0269
Nondurables, SA 0.0195 0.0166 0.1234 0.2140 0.1038 0.0068 0.0747
Services, SA 0.0428 0.0148 0.4344 0.2835 0.3426 0.1293 0.0446
Real labor income growth 0.0333 0.0254 -0.0835 0.0786 0.0449 -0.0389 0.0090

Panel B: Equity index returns

  Mean Std. Dev.  \rho_1  \rho_2  \rho_3  \rho_4  \rho_5
VWR - NYSE 0.0703 0.1574 0.0685 -0.0640 -0.0113 0.0192 -0.0030
VWR - NYSE/AMEX 0.0699 0.1585 0.0658 -0.0621 -0.0137 0.0159 -0.0025
VWR - NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ 0.0683 0.1658 0.0630 -0.0566 0.0061 0.0051 -0.0057

Panel C: Treasury bond returns

  Mean Std. Dev.  \rho_1  \rho_2  \rho_3  \rho_4  \rho_5
3-month T-bill 0.0140 0.0180 0.4646 0.3904 0.4388 0.3756 0.1937
10-year T-bond 0.0183 0.0819 0.0719 0.0335 0.1296 0.0744 -0.2176


Table 2: Deterministic habit: Estimation of  \gamma
This table reports GMM estimated coefficients of the preference parameter  \gamma in the deterministic habit ( \beta = 0) formation case. Parameters  b = 0.328,\, \kappa = 0.072, and  \rho = 0.01 are fixed in this estimation. The following Euler equations are estimated:

\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (R^m_{t,t+1} - R^f_{t,t+1}) \right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle 0,  
\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (R^{b,10}_{t,t+1} - R^f_{t, t+1}) \right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle 0,  

where  R^f_{t,t+1} is the three-month T-bill rate (known at  t),  R^m_{t,t+1} is the quarterly holding-period return on the value-weighted NYSE equity market index,  R^{b,10}_{t, t+1} is the quarterly holding-period return on a 10-year Treasury bond. Instruments are unit vector, one- and two-period lagged consumption growth rate, and one- and two-period lagged asset returns. NH stands for the base-line model without habit formation; DEH stands for the deterministic external habit formation model; DIH stands for the deterministic internal habit formation model.  TJ_T is the overall goodness-of-fit statistic that has  \chi^2(DF) asymptotic distribution, where  DF is the number of degrees of freedom specific to each panel.  p-value is the probability value that  TJ_T exceeds the minimized sample value of the GMM criterion function. The sample period is from 1947:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

Panel A: No long-term T-Bond included, DF = 4

Model  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  TJ_T  p-value
NH -84.9148 2.3126 7.9656 0.0928
DEH -7.9498 1.0908 8.7061 0.0689
DIH -1.8994 0.0438 4.9215 0.2954

Panel B: 10-year T-Bond included, DF = 13

Model  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  TJ_T  p-value
NH -139.7899 1.1919 23.7577 0.0334
DEH -7.8087 0.8355 32.6927 0.0019
DIH -2.0438 0.0353 28.3454 0.0081


Table 3: Deterministic habit: Joint estimation of  \rho and  \gamma
This table reports GMM estimated coefficients of the preference parameters  \rho and  \gamma in the deterministic habit ( \beta = 0) formation case. Parameters  b = 0.328 and  \kappa = 0.072 are fixed in this estimation. The following Euler equations are estimated:

\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (1 + R_{t,t+1}) \right] = 1.      

Panel A reports estimation results with  R_{t,t+1} = (R_{t,t+1}^f, R_{t,t+1}^m), where  R^f_{t,t+1} is the three-month T-bill rate (known at  t),  R^m_{t,t+1} is the quarterly holding-period return on the value-weighted NYSE equity market index. Panel B reports estimation results with  R_{t,t+1} = (R_{t,t+1}^f, R_{t,t+1}^m, R_{t,t+1}^{b,10}), where  R_{t,t+1}^{b,10} is the quarterly holding-period return on a 10-year Treasury bond. Instruments are one, one- and two-period lagged consumption growth rate, and one- and two-period lagged asset and bond returns. (When  \gamma is constrained to be negative, the GMM estimation finds the corner solution (  \gamma = 0)).  TJ_T is the overall goodness-of-fit statistic that has  \chi^2(DF) asymptotic distribution, where  DF is the number of degrees of freedom specific to each panel.  p-value is the probability value that  TJ_T exceeds the minimized sample value of the GMM criterion function. The sample period is from 1947:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

Panel A:  R_{t,t+1} = (R_{t,t+1}^f, R_{t,t+1}^m),\, DF = 12

Model  \hat{\rho} s.e.  \hat{\rho}  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  TJ_T p-value
NH -0.0215 0.0069 0.1672 0.1766 29.4625 0.0034
DEH -0.0179 0.0032 0.8294 0.0331 30.0297 0.0028
DIH 0.0409 0.0466 -0.9345 0.4712 23.4604 0.0241

Panel B:  R_{t,t+1} = (R_{t,t+1}^f, R_{t,t+1}^m, R_{t,t+1}^{b,10}),\, DF = 25

Model  \hat{\rho} s.e.  \hat{\rho}  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  TJ_T p-value
NH -0.0208 0.0054 0.1534 0.1344 46.7029 0.0053
DEH -0.0094 0.0059 0.6467 0.0839 51.0445 0.0016
DIH 0.0534 0.0393 -1.0247 0.3535 50.2571 0.0020


Table 4: Stochastic habit: Joint estimation of  \gamma and  \beta
This table reports GMM estimated coefficients of the preference parameter  \gamma and the volatility of the habit shock  \beta . Parameters  b = 0.328,  \kappa = 0.072, and  \rho = 0.01 are fixed in this estimation. The following Euler equations are estimated:

\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (R^m_{t,t+1} - R^f_{t,t+1}) \right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle 0,  
\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (R^{b,10}_{t,t+1} - R^f_{t, t+1}) \right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle 0,  

where  R^f_{t,t+1} is the three-month T-bill rate (known at  t),  R^m_{t,t+1} is the quarterly holding-period return on the value-weighted NYSE equity market index,  R^{b,10}_{t, t+1} is the quarterly holding-period return on a 10-year Treasury bond. Instruments are one, one- and two-period lagged consumption growth rate, and one- and two-period lagged asset and bond returns. SEH stands for stochastic extern habit, and SIH stands for stochastic internal habit.  TJ_T is the overall goodness-of-fit statistic that has  \chi^2(12) asymptotic distribution.  p-value is the probability value that  TJ_T exceeds the minimized sample value of the GMM criterion function. The sample period is from 1947:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

Panel A: Value-weighted NYSE index

Model  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  \hat{\beta} s.e.  \hat{\beta}  TJ_T p-value
SEH -8.5344 6.7888 0.0047 0.0496 31.6562 0.0016
SIH -2.9065 0.4839 -0.0254 0.0116 23.9664 0.0206

Panel B: Value-weighted NYSE/AMEX index

Model  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  \hat{\beta} s.e.  \hat{\beta}  TJ_T p-value
SEH -8.4483 6.7537 0.0036 0.0503 31.7751 0.0015
SIH -2.7955 0.4528 -0.0279 0.0112 23.4363 0.0242

Panel C: Value-weighted NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ index

Model  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  \hat{\beta} s.e.  \hat{\beta}  TJ_T p-value
SEH -8.3294 6.6915 0.0044 0.0500 31.3037 0.0018
SIH -1.9477 0.2015 -0.0566 0.0075 17.9489 0.1173



Table 5: Stochastic habit: Joint estimation of  \rho ,  \gamma , and  \beta
This table reports GMM estimated coefficients of the preference parameters  \rho,\, \gamma, and the volatility of the habit shock  \beta . Parameters  b = 0.328 and  \kappa = 0.072 are fixed in this estimation. The following Euler equations are estimated:

\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (1 + R^f_{t,t+1} \right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle 0,  
\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (1 + R^m_{t,t+1} \right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle 0,  
\displaystyle E_t \left[ \mbox{MRS}_{t,t+1} (1 + R^{b,10}_{t,t+1} \right] \displaystyle = \displaystyle 0,  

where  R^f_{t,t+1} is the three-month T-bill rate (known at  t),  R^m_{t,t+1} is the quarterly holding-period return on the value-weighted NYSE equity market index,  R^{b,10}_{t, t+1} is the quarterly holding-period return on a 10-year Treasury bond. Instruments are one, one- and two-period lagged consumption growth rate, and one- and two-period lagged asset and bond returns. SEH stands for stochastic external habit, and SIH stands for stochastic internal habit.  TJ_T is the overall goodness-of-fit statistic that has  \chi^2(24) asymptotic distribution.  p-value is the probability value that  TJ_T exceeds the minimized sample value of the GMM criterion function. The sample period is from 1947:Q1 to 2002:Q4, quarterly frequency.

Model  \hat{\rho} s.e.  \hat{\rho}  \hat{\gamma} s.e.  \hat{\gamma}  \hat{\beta} s.e.  \hat{\beta}  TJ_T p-value
SEH -0.0030 0.0127 0.7721 0.1816 -0.2118 0.2340 46.8577 0.0035
SIH 0.3204 0.0467 -4.3254 0.6642 -0.0133 0.0040 43.7737 0.0081



Footnotes

* We thank Stephen Brown, Jean Helwege, Jingzhi (Jay) Huang, Martin Lettau, Michelle Lowry, Sydney Ludvigson, Dmitry Makarov, Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh, Marti Subrahmanyam, Joel Vanden, NYU seminar participants, conference participants of the 2005 Annual Trans-Atlantic Doctoral Conference at LBS, London, UK and 2005 AEA meetings in Philadelphia. Address correspondence to [email protected], phone: (202) 452-2981. The views expressed here are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the concurrence by other members of the research staff or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Return to Text
* Chief Risk Officer, Capula Investment Management LLP, London Return to Text
* Economist at the Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC 20551; [email protected] Return to Text
1. The emphasis of this paper is on time-series properties of aggregate market returns. There are a few recent papers that explore the impact of habits on the cross-section of asset returns; see, e.g., Van Binsbergen (2007), Santos & Veronesi (2010), and Heyerdahl-Larsen (2010). Return to Text
2. In the existing literature, the terms "habit shock" and "habit stock" are often used interchangeably, because the "habit stock" is viewed as a "preference shock". In this paper, we differentiate these two terms: the term "habit stock" refers to the habit level, whereas the term "habit shock" refers to the stochastic shock to the habit level. In a model with a deterministic habit, the habit level is determined entirely by consumption history. In a model of stochastic habit, the habit level is affected by its own shock, so that consumption history is not sufficient to determine the current habit level. Return to Text
4. Heaton also adopts a parametric form for the aggregate endowment process (estimated from data as part of a bi-variate vector autoregressive process), and addresses the issue of time aggregation of consumption data. Return to Text
5. Essentially, these two papers depart from the framework of Campbell & Cochrane (1999) who assume that the habit shock is perfectly negatively correlated with the consumption shock. Return to Text
6. Where confusion does not arise, we use the terms "habit shock" and "taste shock" interchangeably. Return to Text
7. We adopt the distributed lag specification to economize model parameters. The derivation of equations (7)-(8) are given in Appendix 7 when  \delta = 0. The Euler equation can be also derived explicitly when the distributed lag contains arbitrary weights. Return to Text
8. This first-order approximation is used here only for the purpose of developing intuition. The exact model is estimated and tested later in the empirical section. Return to Text
9. We thank Stijn Van Nieuwerburgh for pointing out to us that a simpler way of accounting for the sampling errors in the linear projection is to do a one-stage estimation. Eventually, we will report only one-stage estimation results. Currently, only some models have been estimated in one stage, and are used as a robustness check. Return to Text
10. More generally, the habit shock can be driven by both the consumption shock and the labor income shock. We will investigate this more general specification as well. Return to Text
11. In our empirical implementation, we use a version of the following specification:
\displaystyle u(s) = \left\{ \begin{array}{l} \frac{s^\gamma}{\gamma}, \,\, \gamma < 0, \,\, s > \underline{s} > 0, \\ \underline{u}(s), \,\, s \leq \underline{s}, \end{array} \right. (19)

where  \underline{u}(\cdot) is a function well-defined in  (-\infty, \underline{s}], strictly increasing and concave, with the properties that $ \underline{u}underline{s}) = uunderline{s}), \,\, \underline{u}'underline{s}) = u'underline{s}), \,\, \underline{u} (\underline{s}) = u(\underline{s}). $ Such modifications to the standard power utility specification do not affect the derivation of the Euler equations. With a sensible choice of  \underline{s}, they should not affect any substantive implications of the model either. Additional details about its implementation may be obtained from the authors upon request. Return to Text
13. We exclude shoes and clothing from expenditures on non-durables because we would like to abstract from any durability effect, which is contained in these series. The exclusion of shoes and clothing follows the paper of Blinder, et al. (1985), p.473. Return to Text
14. Using seasonally unadjusted data, Ferson & Harvey (1992) find that quarterly seasonality may induce "quarterly" habit persistence, in the sense that the habit level is determined by consumption lagged four quarters. We wish to abstract away from this effect. Return to Text
15. Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis (http://www.bea.gov). Return to Text
16. The parameter  1-\gamma is literally the relative risk aversion coefficient in NH, which is the same as the standard CCAPM. In the habit formation models (DEH or DIH), the relative risk aversion coefficient is  1-\gamma divided by the surplus consumption ratio. Throughout the paper, we use the terms risk-aversion parameter and curvature of the utility function interchangeably to describe the same parameter  1-\gamma or  \gamma . Return to Text
17. We also estimate the models using alternative values of  b,  \kappa, and  \rho . The qualitative conclusions remain the same. Return to Text
18. The models are forced to fit  K=1 risk premium using  M=5 instruments (one, two lags of consumption growth rates, and two lags of equity returns). There is only one free parameter. Thus, the minimized GMM objective function has a chi-square distribution with  KM-1 = 4 degrees of freedom. Return to Text
19. We also estimate the models using different long-term bonds, such as 5-year and 30-year Treasury bonds. The results are qualitatively similar. Return to Text
20. The models are forced to fit  K=2 risk premiums using  M=7 instruments (one, two lags of consumption growth rates, two lags of equity returns and two lags of bond returns). There is only one free parameter. Thus, the minimized GMM objective function has a chi-square distribution with  KM-1 = 13 degrees of freedom. Return to Text
21.  cay_t is measured as the cointegrating residual between log consumption, log asset wealth, and log labor income. See Lettau & Ludvigson (2001a) for more details. Return to Text
22. We did not include other popular forecasting variables like dividend-price ratio into our instrumental set because they are found to be driven away by the above variables  cay_t,\ RREL,\ \textup{and}\ SPEX. See Lettau & Ludvigson (2001a) for further details. Return to Text
23. See also Stock & Wright (2000) on the weak identification problem. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text