The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

Skip to: [Printable Version (PDF)] [Bibliography] [Footnotes]
Finance and Economics Discussion Series: 2013-25 Screen Reader version

The Nature of Countercyclical Income Risk*

Fatih Guvenen*
Serdar Ozkan*
Jae Song*

Keywords:

Abstract:

This paper studies the nature of business cycle variation in individual earnings risk using a dataset from the U.S. Social Security Administration, which contains (uncapped) earnings histories for millions of anonymous individuals. The base sample is a nationally representative panel containing 10 percent of all U.S. males from 1978 to 2010. We use these data to decompose individual earnings growth during recessions into "between-group" and "within-group" components. We begin with the behavior of within-group shocks. Contrary to past research, we do not find the variance of idiosyncratic earnings shocks to be countercyclical. Instead, it is the left-skewness of shocks that is strongly countercyclical. That is, during recessions, the upper end of the shock distribution collapses--large upward earnings movements become less likely--whereas the bottom end expands--large drops in earnings become more likely. Thus, while the dispersion of shocks does not increase, shocks become more left skewed and, hence, riskier during recessions. Second, to study between-group differences, we group individuals based on several observable characteristics at the time a recession hits. One of these characteristics--the average earnings of an individual at the beginning of a business cycle episode--proves to be an especially good predictor of fortunes during a recession: prime-age workers that enter a recession with high average earnings suffer substantially less compared with those who enter with low average earnings (such "asymmetry" is not evident in expansions). Finally, we find that the cyclical nature of earnings risk is dramatically different for the top 1 percent compared with all other individuals--even relative to those in the top 2 to 5 percent.

JEL classification: E24, E32, J21, J31.


JEL Classification:

1 Introduction

From 2007 to 2009, U.S. male workers experienced an average decline in their annual labor earnings of 6.5 percent.1 While this figure represents the sharpest decline of any postwar recession, it is dwarfed by the dispersion of earnings growth rates across workers during the same recession: for example, a quarter of workers saw their labor earnings rise by 16 percent or more, one in ten saw a rise of 50 (log) percent or more, whereas another one in ten saw a fall of 60 (log) percent or more. Moreover, despite the 6.5 percent mean decline just noted, the worker with median earnings change actually experienced a slight rise--of 0.1 percent--during these two years.

The goal of this paper is to understand how this dispersion of fortunes varies over the business cycle. More specifically, we ask two questions. First, how does the distribution of idiosyncratic earnings shocks change over the business cycle? Second, are there any observable characteristics of a worker that can help us predict his fortunes during a business cycle episode? To answer these questions, we decompose earnings growth over the business cycle into a component that can be predicted based on the observable characteristics of individuals (prior to the episode) and a separate "residual" component that represents purely idiosyncratic shocks that affect individuals that are ex ante very similar. The first one represents the "between-group" (systematic) component of business cycle risk, whereas the second can be thought of as the "within-group" (idiosyncratic) component.

An important advantage of our analysis is the very rich dataset that we employ. Basically, our main panel dataset is a 10 percent random sample of all U.S. males with a Social Security number between the ages of 25 and 60 from 1978 to 2010. This dataset has three important advantages. First, earnings records in our dataset are uncapped (no top-coding), allowing us to study individuals with very high earnings.2 Second, the substantial sample size allows us to employ flexible nonparametric methods and still obtain extremely precise estimates.3 Third, thanks to their records-based nature, the data contain very little measurement error, which is a serious issue with survey-based micro datasets. One drawback is possible under-reporting (e.g., cash earnings), which can be a particular concern in the lower portion of the earnings distribution.

The panel aspect of our dataset allows us to use individuals' labor earnings and employment histories to construct observable characteristics as of the beginning of a business cycle episode. For example, we can ask whether individuals that entered a recession with high average earnings are affected differently during the recession relative to those that entered with low average earnings. How about individuals who were rising stars (i.e., had fast earnings growth rate) versus those whose careers were stagnant when the recession hit? And, how does age factor into any of these patterns? To answer these questions systematically, we group individuals along three observable dimensions at the time a business cycle episode begins: (i) age, (ii) pre-episode average earnings, and (iii) pre-episode earnings growth rate.

Figure 1: Countercyclical Variance or Countercyclical Left-Skewness?
1][t]0.5
Countercyclical Variance
Title: Figure 1: Countercyclical Variance or Countercyclical Left-Skewness?
Structure: There are two side-by-side panels. The left panel is labeled, Countercyclical Variance. The right panel is labeled, Countercyclical Left-Skewness.  Each panel has two distributions. The blue-dotted distribution is labeled, Expansion. The solid-red distribution is labeled, Recession. The y-axes are labeled, Density. The x-axes are labeled, Value of Persistent Innovations to an AR(1). The x-axis in the left panel ranges from -0.8 to 0.8 and there is a solid, blue, vertical line at zero. The x-axis on the right ranges from -0.6 to -0.5 and there are two lines. One line is solid, blue and vertical at zero, the other line is solid, red and vertical slightly left of zero. 
Trends: The expansion distribution in the left panel displays a smaller dispersion and is centered on the blue line; while, the recession distribution is slightly left of center. The expansion and recession distributions in the right panel display similar dispersions, with the recession distribution slightly left of center and being noticeably left skewed.
Main point: Two possible cyclical nature of idiosyncratic labor income risk are compared to each other.
1][t]0.5
Countercyclical Left-Skewness
Title: Figure 1: Countercyclical Variance or Countercyclical Left-Skewness?
Structure: There are two side-by-side panels. The left panel is labeled, Countercyclical Variance. The right panel is labeled, Countercyclical Left-Skewness.  Each panel has two distributions. The blue-dotted distribution is labeled, Expansion. The solid-red distribution is labeled, Recession. The y-axes are labeled, Density. The x-axes are labeled, Value of Persistent Innovations to an AR(1). The x-axis in the left panel ranges from -0.8 to 0.8 and there is a solid, blue, vertical line at zero. The x-axis on the right ranges from -0.6 to -0.5 and there are two lines. One line is solid, blue and vertical at zero, the other line is solid, red and vertical slightly left of zero. 
Trends: The expansion distribution in the left panel displays a smaller dispersion and is centered on the blue line; while, the recession distribution is slightly left of center. The expansion and recession distributions in the right panel display similar dispersions, with the recession distribution slightly left of center and being noticeably left skewed.
Main point: Two possible cyclical nature of idiosyncratic labor income risk are compared to each other.

Our main findings can be summarized as follows. First, we study the cyclical nature of idiosyncratic shocks, once observable factors are accounted for. Contrary to past research, we find that earnings shock variances are not countercyclical. However, uncertainty does have a significant countercyclical component, but it comes from the left-skewness increasing during recessions. That is, during recessions, the upper end of the earnings growth distribution collapses--large upward earnings movements become less likely--whereas the bottom end expands--large downward movements become more likely. The two possibilities--countercyclical variance versus left-skewness--are shown in Figure 1. Relative to the earlier literature that argued for increasing variance--which results in some individuals receiving larger positive shocks during recessions--our results are even more pessimistic: Downward risk tends to increase in recessions without an increasing chance of upward movements.

We then turn to the systematic component of business cycle risk. We find substantial between-group variation across individuals who differ in pre-episode average earnings. For example, when we sort prime-age (35-54) male workers based on their 2002-06 average earnings, those in the 10th percentile of this distribution experienced a drop in earnings during the Great Recession (2007-10) that was about 18 percent larger than that experienced by at the 90th percentile. In fact, the average percentage of earnings lost during this recession was almost a linear (upward-sloping) function of pre-recession average earnings all the way up to the 95th percentile (Figure 13). Interestingly, this good fortune of high-income workers did not extend to the very top: those in the top 1 percent, based on their 2002-2006 average earnings, experienced an average loss that was 21 percent worse than that of workers in the 90th percentile. Although these magnitudes are largest for the Great Recession, the same general patterns emerged in the other recessions too. For example, the 1980-83 double-dip recession is very similar to the Great Recession for all but the top 5 percentiles. But the large earnings loss for the top 1 percent was not observed during that recession at all. In fact, this appears to be a more recent phenomenon: The worst episode for the top 1 percent was the otherwise mild 2000-02 recession, when their average earnings loss exceeded that of those in the 90th percentile by almost 30 log points.

Our results on the business cycle behavior of top incomes complement and extend the findings in Piketty and Saez (2003) and, especially, in Parker and Vissing-Jørgensen (2010). In particular, these papers used repeated cross sections to construct synthetic groups of individuals based on their earnings level. They then documented the strong cyclicality of high earnings groups over the business cycle. With panel data, we are able to track the same individuals over time, which allows us to control for compositional change and measure how persistent the effects of such fluctuations are. Our results confirm the higher cyclicality of top earners and reveal the very high persistence of these fluctuations. For example, individuals who were in the 99.9th percentile as of 1999 experienced a 5-year average earnings loss between 2000 and 2005 that exceeded 50 log points. Similarly large persistent losses are found for the top income earners during the 5-year periods covering the Great Recession (2005-10) as well as the 1990-95 period.

The analysis in this paper is deliberately nonparametric, made possible by the large sample size. This approach allows us to present our main findings in the form of figures and easy-to-interpret statistics, which makes the results transparent. An alternative approach would impose a stylized stochastic process on labor earnings and parametrize it in a way to allow variation over the business cycle. In light of our current findings, that approach has an important drawback. Basically, earnings growth rates exhibit significant deviations from normality, in the form of very strong left-skewness and substantial leptokurtosis. Hence, to capture those features (let alone the variation in them over time and across individuals), the estimated earnings process would have to be very complicated, which would take away from the clarity afforded by the current approach.4 Our approach is similar to that of Dynarski and Gruber (1997), Moffitt and Gottschalk (2002), and Solon and Shin (2011), who focused on simple statistics for studying earnings dynamics.

1.0.0.1 Literature Discussion.

The cyclical patterns of idiosyncratic labor earnings risk have received attention from both macro and financial economists. In an infinite-horizon model with permanent shocks, Constantinides and Duffie (1996) showed that one can generate a high equity premium if idiosyncratic shocks have countercyclical variance. Storesletten et al. (2004) used a clever empirical identification scheme to estimate the cyclicality of shock variances.5 Using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), they estimated the variance of AR(1) innovations to be three times higher during recessions. Probably due to the small sample size, they did not, however, investigate the cyclicality of the skewness of shocks, nor did they allow for a factor structure as we do here. Moreover, note that the question of interest is "the cyclical changes in the dispersion of earnings growth rates," which involves triple-differencing. Answering such a question without a very large and clean dataset is extremely challenging. Our findings are more consistent with Mankiw (1986), who showed that one can resolve the equity premium puzzle if idiosyncratic shocks have countercyclical left-skewness--as found in the current paper.

The spirit of our analysis is similar to the literature that decomposed wage inequality trends into between-group and within-group components (among many others, Juhn et al. (1993), Lemieux (2006), and Autor et al. (2008)). But there are several notable differences. First, our focus is on growth rates rather than levels, which is feasible with the panel dimension of our dataset. Second, we focus on business cycle variation, whereas that literature examined secular trends. Third, relying on repeated cross sections, that literature had to confine itself to observable characteristics that were available in the cross section, such as gender, age, education, and, sometimes, industry. With longitudinal data, we are able to define groups of individuals based on their history, such as individuals with high versus low past average earnings and/or earnings growth rates.

There is also an interesting parallel between the conclusions of this paper and an early debate in the business cycle literature. In a provocative paper, Lilien (1982) showed that the dispersion of employment growth across sectors was countercyclical. He interpreted this finding as evidence that sectoral shifts caused the cyclical fluctuations in the unemployment rate. Abraham and Katz (1986) challenged this conclusion by showing that a factor structure in which different sectors loaded differently onto an aggregate factor could generate the same correlation between dispersion and unemployment, even though the driving force was an aggregate shock. In a similar vein, our results show that the well-documented countercyclicality of earnings inequality does not have to stem from the countercyclical variance of idiosyncratic shocks, but rather is due to a factor structure that expands inequality during recessions and contracts during expansions.

Finally, in a different strand of literature, Bloom et al. (2011) fit an AR(1) process to firm-level total factor productivity (TFP) time series and allow a fixed aggregate shock and fixed firm effect. They find that the residual of the AR(1) has a larger cross-sectional dispersion during recessions. While skewness also appears to be more negative, the difference is not statistically significant. In contrast to that paper, we do allow for a factor structure (loading factor on their aggregate shock) and allow the loading factor to vary with observables. Of course, we study individual labor earnings, whereas they focus on firm-level TFP, so the two sets of results are not necessarily inconsistent with each other.

2 The Data

We employ a unique, confidential, and very large panel dataset on earnings histories from the U.S. Social Security Administration records. For our baseline analysis, we draw a 10 percent random sample of U.S. males--covering 1978 to 2010--directly from the Master Earnings File (MEF) of Social Security records.6

2.0.0.1 The Master Earnings File.

The MEF is the main source of earnings data for the Social Security Administration and grows every year with the addition of new earnings information received directly from employers (Form W-2 for wage and salary workers).7 The MEF includes data for every individual in the United States who has a Social Security number. The dataset contains basic demographic characteristics, such as date of birth, sex, race, type of work (farm or non-farm, employment or self-employment), self-employment taxable earnings, and several other variables. Earnings data are uncapped (no top-coding) and include wages and salaries, bonuses, and exercised stock options as reported on the W-2 form (Box 1).8 For more information, see Panis et al. (2000) and Olsen and Hudson (2009). Finally, all nominal variables were converted into real ones using the Personal Consumption Expenditure (PCE) deflator with 2005 taken as the base year.

Figure 2: Number of Observations y Year
Title: Figure 2: Number of Observations y Year
Structure: This figure is a line graph with two lines. The y-axis is labeled, Number of Observations and ranges from 0 to 10,000,000. The x-axis is labeled, Year and ranges from 1970 to 2010. Above the panel is a note that says, Total Number of Observations: 165,521,759. The first line is a black-dotted line that represents all males aged 25-60. This line is upward sloping at a decreasing rate, with a starting point close to five million and an end point just shy of eight million. The second line is a red-dotted line that is increasing over time, but has smaller segments where the number of observations dips slightly; the result of sample criteria (participating in the labor market in a given year) being more stringent during recessions. This line has a starting point of around 3.7 million and an end point around 5.5 million.

2.0.0.2 Creating the 10 Percent Sample.

To construct a nationally representative panel of males, we proceed as follows. For 1978, a sample of 10 percent of U.S. males are selected based on a fixed subset of digits of (a transformation of) the Social Security Number (SSN). Because these digits of the SSN are randomly assigned, this procedure easily allows randomization. For each subsequent year, new individuals are added to account for the newly issued SSNs in the United States; those individuals who are deceased are removed (from that year forward). This process yields a representative sample of 10 percent of U.S. males every year.

For a statistic computed using data for (not necessarily consecutive) years  (t_{1},t_{2},...,t_{n}), an individual observation is included if the following three conditions are satisfied for all these years: the individual (i) is between the ages of 25 and 60, (ii) has annual wage/salary earnings that exceed a time-varying minimum threshold, and (iii) is not self-employed (i.e., has self-employment earnings less than the same minimum threshold). This minimum, denoted  Y_{\text{min},t}, is equal to one-half of the legal minimum wage times 520 hours (13 weeks at 40 hours per week), which amounts to an annual earnings of approximately $1,300 in 2005. This condition allows us to focus on workers with a reasonably strong labor market attachment and avoids issues with taking the logarithm of very low earnings levels. It also makes our results more comparable to the income dynamics literature where this condition is standard (see, among others, Abowd and Card (1989), Meghir and Pistaferri (2004), Storesletten et al. (2004), as well as Juhn et al. (1993) and Autor et al. (2008) on wage inequality). Finally, the MEF contains a small number of extremely high earnings observations each year. To avoid potential problems with outliers, we cap (winsorize) observations above the 99.999th percentile.

Figure 2 displays the number of individuals that satisfy these selection criteria, as well as the total number of individuals in each year. The sample starts with about 3.7 million individuals in 1978 and grows to about 5.4 million individuals by the mid-2000s. Notice that the number of individuals in the sample does not follow population growth one-for-one (black line marked with diamonds), because inclusion in the base sample also requires participating in the labor market in a given year (hence the slowdown in sample growth in the 2000s and the fall during the Great Recession).9

Further, Table A.1 in Appendix A reports key summary statistics for our sample. Similarly, Figure A.1 plots the levels of labor earnings that correspond to selected percentiles of the earnings distribution in each year. The lowest earnings that qualifies a male worker in the top 10 percent (e.g., above the 90th percentile) has been steady at approximately $98,000 since year 2000. In 2011, a worker must be making more than $297,000 to be in the top 1 percent. This threshold was highest in 2007 when it reached $318,000.

2.0.0.3 Recessionary vs. Expansionary Episodes.

The start date of a recession is determined as follows. If the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) peak of the previous expansion takes place in the first half of a given year, that year is classified as the first year of the new recession. If the peak is in the second half, the recession starts in the subsequent year.10 The ending date of a recession is a bit more open to interpretation for our purposes, because the NBER "troughs" are often not followed by a rapid fall in unemployment rates and a rise in individual wages. This can be seen in Figure 3. For example, whereas the NBER announced the start date of the expansion as March of 1991, the unemployment rate peaked in the summer of 1992. Similarly, while the NBER trough was November 2001, the unemployment rate remained high until mid-2003. With these considerations in mind, we settled on the following dates for the last three recessions: 1991-92, 2001-02, and 2008-10. We opt to treat the 1980-1983 period as a single recession, given the extremely short duration of the intervening expansion, the anemic growth it brought, and the lack of a significant fall in the unemployment rate (Figure 3). Based on this classification, there are three expansions and four recessions during our sample period.

As a complementary approach, in Section 6.3 we study business cycle variation by analyzing the co-movement of the earnings growth distribution with cyclical variables, such as the male unemployment rate, GDP per capita, and S&P500 returns.

Figure 3: U.S. Male Unemployment Rate, 1978-2011
Title: Figure 3: U.S. Male Unemployment Rate, 1978-2011 Structure: This figure plots a blue line that tracks the male unemployment rate. There are grey shaded regions representing NBER recessions. These regions are roughly as follows: 1979-80, 1981-82, 1990-91, 2001-02 and 2007-09. The y-axis plots the unemployment rate and ranges from 3 to 12. The x-axis plots the date, by month, from January 1978 to April 2011. 
Trends: During recessions, male unemployment spikes. The graphs highest reaching point surpasses 11% in 1982 and late 2009, early 2010. However, recession endings are often followed by a continued swell in unemployment, often reaching their peaks after the NBERs troughs.
Main point: This post-recession swelling in unemployment lead to the decision for the following dates for the previous three recessions: 1991-92, 2001-02 and 2008-10. 1980-83 is treated as a single recession due to the short duration of expansion between.

3 Earnings Risk over the Business Cycle: First Look

Before delving into the full-blown panel data analysis in the next section, we begin by providing a bird's-eye view of the business cycle patterns in earnings risk. Specifically, we exploit the panel dimension of the MEF dataset to document how the dispersion and skewness of the earnings growth distribution vary over the business cycle.11 ^{,}12

Figure 4: Top and Bottom Ends of the Earnings Growth Distribution
TRANSITORY
Title: Figure 4: Top and Bottom Ends of the Earnings Growth Distribution
Structure: This figure shows two panels with line graphs. The left panel is titled, Transitory and the right panel is titled, Persistent. The y-axes are labeled, Top and Bottom End of Distribution. The left y-axis ranges from 0.1 to 0.6 and the right x-axis ranges from 0.3 to 0.9. The x-axes are labeled, Year and both range from 1970 to 2010. In each case, there is a blue line (L90-50), representing the log differential between the 90th and 50th percentiles, and a red line (L50-10), representing the log differential between the 50th and 10th percentiles. There are shaded grey areas denoting recession periods.
Trends:  In both panels, the L50-10 line rises during recessions, implying an increased chance of a larger downward movement and the L90-10 line dips during recessions, implying a smaller chance of upward movements. 
Main point: These findings suggest that during recessions the top end compresses and the bottom end expands, relative to the median growth rate.
PERSISTENT
\includegraphics[width=0.92\columnwidth,height=0.29\textheight]{AFIG_Males_P9050_P5010_OF_5YR_CHANGE_IN_LOG_WAGE_FINAL}

It will be useful to distinguish between earnings growth over short and long horizons. To this end, in much of the following analysis, we examine 1-year and 5-year earnings growth rates and think of these as roughly corresponding to "transitory" and "persistent" earnings shocks. A more rigorous justification for this interpretation will be provided below.

The left panel of Figure 4 plots the evolution of the log differential between the 90th and 50th percentiles of (  y_{t+1}-y_{t}) distribution (hereafter L90-50), as well as the log differential between the 50th and 10th percentiles (L50-10). The first important observation is that the top and bottom ends of the shock distributions clearly move in opposite directions over the business cycle. In particular, L50-10 rises strongly during recessions, implying that there is an increased chance of larger downward movements during recessions. In contrast, the top end (L90-50) dips consistently in every recession, implying a smaller chance of upward movements during recessions. In other words, relative to the median growth rate, the top end compresses, whereas the bottom end expands during recessions. Similarly, the right panel of Figure 4 plots the corresponding graph for persistent (5-year) shocks. The striking co-movement of the L90-50 and L50-10 is clearly seen here (the correlation of the two series is -0.67), even more strongly than in the transitory shocks.

A couple of remarks are in order. First, the fact that L90-50 and L50-10 move in opposite directions implies that L90-10 (which is a measure of overall dispersion of shocks) changes little over the business cycle, because the fall in L90-50 (partially) cancels out the rise in L50-10. An alternative measure of shock dispersion--the standard deviation--is plotted in Figure 5 for both persistent and transitory shocks, which shows that dispersion does not increase much during recessions (notice the very small variation on the y-axis). Perhaps the only exception is the 2001-02 recession, during which time the transitory shock variance increases. In the coming sections, this point will be examined further and will be made more rigorously. This observation will provide one of the key conclusions of this paper, given how clearly it contradicts the commonly held belief that idiosyncratic earnings shock variances are strongly countercyclical (e.g., Storesletten et al. (2004)).

Figure 5: Standard Deviation of Transitory and Persistent Earnings Growth
Title: Figure 5: Standard Deviation of Transitory and Persistent Earnings Growth Structure: This figure is a line graph with two lines plotted. The y-axis is labeled, Standard Deviation and ranges from 0.4 to 0.9. The x-axis is labeled, Year and ranges from 1970 to 2010. A red line represents the standard deviation for five year periods. Below the red line, a blue line represents the standard deviation for one year periods. There are shaded grey areas denoting recession periods.
Trends: Both lines remain relatively flat over time. The one year standard deviation is always below the five year standard deviation.
Main point: This finding is contradictory to the widely held belief that idiosyncratic earnings shock variances are strongly countercyclical.
3.0.0.0.1 Trends in Volatility: A Brief Digression.

Second, looking at transitory shocks, L90-50 displays a clear downward trend during this time period. A fitted linear trend implies a drop of 11 log points from 1979 to 2010. The interpretation is that the likelihood of large upward movements has become smaller during this period. We see a similar, but less pronounced, trend in the L50-10, which indicates that the likelihood of large falls has also become somewhat smaller. Overall though, both the L90-10 and the standard deviation of earnings growth (Figure 5) display a clear downward trend. Notice that this conclusion is in contrast to the conventional wisdom since the 1990s that earnings shock variances have generally risen since the 1980s (Moffitt and Gottschalk (1995)). However, it is consistent with a number of recent papers that use administrative data (e.g., Sabelhaus and Song (2010) and others).13 In this paper, we will not dwell much on this trend, except when it is relevant for our analysis of the cyclical changes in earnings risk.

Figure 6: Skewness of Transitory and Persistent Earnings Growth
Title: Figure 6: Skewness of Transitory and Persistent Earnings Growth Structure: This figure is a line graph with two lines plotted. The y-axis is labeled, Skewness and ranges from -1 to 0. The x-axis is labeled, Year and ranges from 1970 to 2010. A red line represents the five year earnings growth. A black line represents the one year earnings growth. There are shaded grey areas denoting recession periods.
Trends: During recession periods the distributions become more negatively skewed. This is very pronounced in the one year distribution and this skewness was much more severe during the Great Recession. 
Main point: This suggests that the top end of the shock distribution compresses during recessions, while at the same time the bottom end expands.

We now return to the discussion of cyclical facts. The finding described above--that the top end of the shock distribution compresses during recessions, while at the same time the bottom end expands--suggests that one important cyclical change could be found in the skewness of shocks. Indeed, as seen in Figure 6, both the 1- and 5-year earnings growth distributions become more left-skewed (negative skewness increases) during recessions and the magnitude of change is large. Below, we return to this point and sharpen it by conditioning earnings changes on narrowly defined groups of individuals.


4 Panel Analysis

The analysis so far provided a general look at how earnings shocks vary over the business cycle. However, one can imagine that the properties of earnings shocks vary systematically with individual characteristics and heterogeneity: for example, young and old workers can face different earnings shock distributions than prime-age workers with more stable jobs. Similarly, workers at different parts of the earnings distribution could experience different types of earnings risks. The large sample size allows us to account for such variation without making any strong parametric assumptions.

4.1 A Framework for Empirical Analysis

Although in this paper, we will not commit to any particular parametric specification for the income process, it is useful to outline a general framework to fix ideas and define some notation. To this end, let  \widetilde{y}_{t}^{i} denote individual  i's log labor earnings in year  t, and let  \mathbf {V}_{t-1}^{i} denote a vector of (possibly time-varying) individual characteristics that will be used to group individuals as of period  t-1. Consider the following representation:

\displaystyle \widetilde{y}_{t}^{i} \displaystyle =g(\theta,h_{t})+\lambda_{t}+z_{t}^{i}+\varepsilon_{t}^{i} (1)
\displaystyle z_{t}^{i} \displaystyle =z_{t-1}^{i}+\eta_{t}^{i},    

where  g(\theta,h_{t}) is a flexible function of age ( h) that captures life cycle effects in log labor earnings,  \lambda_{t} denotes the aggregate shock, and the transitory and persistent shocks are drawn from  \varepsilon_{t}^{i}\sim H(\varepsilon\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i},\lambda_{t}) and  \eta_{t}^{i}\sim G(\eta\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i},\lambda_{t}) with zero conditional mean. (Later on, we shall discuss the ramifications of allowing for mean-reverting persistent shocks.)

Now define log labor earnings net of systematic lifecycle effects:  y_{t}^{i}\equiv\widetilde{y}_{t}^{i}-g(\theta,h_{t}). To study between- and within-group variation over the business cycle, we difference earnings in equation (1) for periods  t+k and  t, and modify it to introduce a factor structure:

\displaystyle y_{t+k}^{i}-y_{t}^{i} \displaystyle =\underset{{\color{blue}\text{factor structure}}}{\underbrace{f_{1}(\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})(\lambda_{t+k}-\lambda_{t})}}+\underset{{\color{blue}\text{stochastic component}}}{\underbrace{\left[(\eta_{t+k}+\eta_{t+k-1}+...+\eta_{t+1})\right]+(\varepsilon_{t+k}^{i}-\varepsilon_{t}^{i}).}} (2)

The specification in (2) allows for two different types of business cycle effects. First, the factor structure--captured by the introduction of the function  f_{1}--allows the conditional mean of earnings growth to vary systematically with the business cycle across different groups of workers. Second, both types of shocks have variances that can potentially vary with the business cycle in a way that is also different across groups of workers (as captured by  H and  G). In our implementation, we will consider a vector  \mathbf {V}_{t-1}^{i} that includes three time-varying observable individual characteristics: age, past average earnings, and past earnings growth rate as of period  t-1. An assumption that will be maintained in the analysis is that these characteristics vary slowly with time, so that  \mathbf{V}_{t}^{i}\approx\mathbf{V}_{t+k}^{i} for small  k.

This formulation allows the effects of aggregate shocks to be transmitted differently to groups that differ in their labor market characteristics at the time a recession hits or an expansion gets under way. Of course, even individuals within these finely defined groups will likely experience different earnings growth rates during recessions and expansions, which will be captured by the permanent and transitory shocks above. These capture the within-group variation in shocks, and we will also quantify the cyclical nature of such shocks. In the coming sections, we shall use this framework to interpret our findings.

4.2 Grouping Individuals into  \mathbf {V}_{t-1}^{i}

Let  t denote the generic time period that marks the beginning of a business cycle episode. We now describe how we group individuals based on their characteristics at time  t-1. Each individual is identified by three characteristics that can be used to form groups. Not every characteristic will be used in the formation of groups in every experiment.14

4.2.0.1 1. Age.

Individuals are divided into seven age groups. The first six groups are five-year wide (25-29, 30-34,..., 50-54) and the last one covers six years: 55-60.

4.2.0.2 2. Pre-episode Average Earnings.

A second dimension individuals differ along is their average earnings (and especially where they rank relative to others). For a given year  t, we consider all individuals who were in the base sample (i) in year  t-1 and (ii) in at least two more years between  t-5 to  t-2. For example, an individual who is 23 years old in  t-5 (and hence is not in the base sample that year) will be included in the final sample for year  t if he has earnings exceeding  Y_{\min} in every year between  t-3 and  t-1.

Furthermore, as noted above, we are interested in average earnings to see how a worker ranks relative to his peers. But even within the narrow age groups defined above, age variation can skew the rankings in favor of older workers. For example, between ages 25 and 29, average earnings grows by 35.4 percent in our sample, and between 30 and 34, it grows by 18.3 percent. So, unless this lifecycle component is accounted for, a 29-year-old worker in the first age group would appear in a higher earnings percentile than the same worker when he was 25. This variation would confound age and earnings differences.

To correct for this, we proceed as follows. First, using all earnings observations from our base sample from 1978 to 2010, we run a pooled regression of log raw earnings (  \widetilde{y}_{t,h}^{i}) on age and cohort dummies (without a constant) to characterize the age profile of log earnings. We then scale the age dummies (denoted with  d_{h}) so as to match the average log earnings of 25-year-old individuals used in the regression. Using these age dummies, we compute the average earnings between years  t-5 and  t-1 for the average worker of age  h in year  t. Then for a given worker  i of age  h in year  t, we first average his earnings from  t-5 to  t-1 (and set earnings below  Y_{\text{min},t} equal to the threshold) and then normalize it by the population average computed using the age dummies. This 5-year average (normalized) earnings is denoted with  \overline{Y}_{t-1}^{i}\equiv(\sum_{s=1}^{5}e^{\widetilde{y}_{t-s}^{i}})/(\sum_{s=1}^{5}e^{d_{h-s}}).15

4.2.0.3 3. Pre-episode Earnings Growth.

A third dimension is (recent) earnings growth. This could be an indicator of individuals whose careers are on the rise, as opposed to being stagnant, even after controlling for average earnings as done above. For this purpose, we compute  \Delta_{5}(y_{t-1})\equiv\left(y_{t-1}-y_{t-s}\right)/(s-1)), where  s is the earliest year after  t-6 in which the individual has earnings above the threshold.16

5 Within-Group (Idiosyncratic) Shocks

One focus of this analysis will be on simple measures of earnings shock volatility, conditional on individual characteristics. That is, fix a group of workers that have the same vector  \mathbf {V}_{t-1}^{i} at time  t. Computing the within-group variance, we get

var\displaystyle (y_{t+k}^{i}-y_{t}^{i}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i}) \displaystyle =\underset{k\text{ terms }}{\underbrace{\left(\sum_{s=1}^{k}\text{\text{var}}(\eta_{t+s}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})\right)}}+\underset{{\color{blue}2}\text{ terms}}{\underbrace{(\text{\text{var}}(\varepsilon_{t}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})+\text{\text{var}}(\varepsilon_{t+k}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i}))}}.    

5.0.0.1 Transitory vs. Persistent Earnings Changes.

Two points can be observed from this formula. First, as we consider longer time differences (larger  k), the variance reflects more of the permanent shocks, as seen by the addition of the  k innovation variances and given that there are always two variances from the transitory component regardless of  k. For example, computing this variance over a five-year period that spans a recession (say, 1979-84 or 1989-94) would allow us to measure how the variance of permanent shocks changes during recessions. It will also contain transitory variances, but for two years that are not part of a recession (1979 and 1984, for example). Second, looking at short-term variance, say,  k=1, yields a formula that contains only one permanent shock variance and two transitory shock variances. So, as we increase the length of the period over which the variance is computed, the statistic shifts from being informative about transitory shock variances toward more persistent variation.

In the analysis below, we consider  k=1 and  k=5. The choice of  k=5--as opposed to a longer or a shorter period--is motivated by the fact that recessions last 2 to 3 years, so that by year  t+5 the unemployment rate will have declined from its peak and will, in most cases, be close to the pre-recession level (in year  t). This feature will facilitate the interpretation of our findings, as we discuss later. Below, we compute various group-specific statistics, including variances, to examine the nature of such variation.

Figure 7: Percentiles of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recession vs. Expansion
1][t]1
PERSISTENT CHANGE
Title: Figure 7: Percentiles of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recession vs. Expansion
Structure: This figure has two panels. The top panel is labeled, Persistent Change and the bottom is labeled, Transitory Change. The y-axis is labeled, Percentiles of five year-ahead earnings change, Conditional on Average Earnings over the last five years in the top panel and ranges from -1.5 to 1. In the bottom panel, the y-axis is labeled, Percentiles of One year-ahead earnings change, Conditional on Average Earnings over the last five years and ranges from -1 to 1. The x-axes are labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and range from 0 to 100. In each panel, there are six lines. Two represent the 90th percentile of five year average income. One black line is this 90th percentile before recession and the other blue line for this percentile before expansions. This is done for the 90th, 50th and 10th percentiles in each panel. 
Trends: In the top panel, all the expansion lines are above the recession lines. The 50th percentile remains roughly unchanged. The 90th and 10th percentiles look like mirror images. The 90th percentile has a slight parabola shape. It starts very positive, slowly decreases, reaching a point of inflection around the 80th percentile, on the x-axis, before starting to rise, again. The 10th percentile is generally the mirror image of 90th percentile. It starts very negative, slowly becomes less negative, reaching a point of inflection, also around the 80th percentile, before starting to decrease, again.  The bottom panel exhibits very similar behavior. The 50th percentile is starkly flat around zero, as it is in the top panel. Again, the 90th percentile shows a parabolic-like shape; the 10th percentile shows a negative parabolic-like shape. 
Main point: Individuals with the lowest levels of past average earnings face the largest dispersion of earnings shocks looking forward. Furthermore, during the recessions 90th and  10th percentiles shift down in similar amounts implying that distribution of earnings changes in both panels become more left skewed.
1][t]1
TRANSITORY CHANGE
Title: Figure 7: Percentiles of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recession vs. Expansion
Structure: This figure has two panels. The top panel is labeled, Persistent Change and the bottom is labeled, Transitory Change. The y-axis is labeled, Percentiles of five year-ahead earnings change, Conditional on Average Earnings over the last five years in the top panel and ranges from -1.5 to 1. In the bottom panel, the y-axis is labeled, Percentiles of One year-ahead earnings change, Conditional on Average Earnings over the last five years and ranges from -1 to 1. The x-axes are labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and range from 0 to 100. In each panel, there are six lines. Two represent the 90th percentile of five year average income. One black line is this 90th percentile before recession and the other blue line for this percentile before expansions. This is done for the 90th, 50th and 10th percentiles in each panel. 
Trends: In the top panel, all the expansion lines are above the recession lines. The 50th percentile remains roughly unchanged. The 90th and 10th percentiles look like mirror images. The 90th percentile has a slight parabola shape. It starts very positive, slowly decreases, reaching a point of inflection around the 80th percentile, on the x-axis, before starting to rise, again. The 10th percentile is generally the mirror image of 90th percentile. It starts very negative, slowly becomes less negative, reaching a point of inflection, also around the 80th percentile, before starting to decrease, again.  The bottom panel exhibits very similar behavior. The 50th percentile is starkly flat around zero, as it is in the top panel. Again, the 90th percentile shows a parabolic-like shape; the 10th percentile shows a negative parabolic-like shape. 
Main point: Individuals with the lowest levels of past average earnings face the largest dispersion of earnings shocks looking forward. Furthermore, during the recessions 90th and  10th percentiles shift down in similar amounts implying that distribution of earnings changes in both panels become more left skewed.

We begin with the cyclicality of idiosyncratic shocks, as measured by within-group variation in earnings growth rates. An important question is whether or not idiosyncratic shocks have countercyclical variances. To answer this question, we make use of the following graphical construct. In its most general form, we plot the quantiles of  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} for a given age group on the x-axis against the entire distribution of future earnings growth rates for that quantile on the y-axis:  \mathbb{F}(y_{t+k}-y_{t}\vert\overline{Y}_{t-1}).

Figure 8: Dispersion of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recession vs. Expansion
1][t]0.5
Persistent Change
Title: Figure 8: Dispersion of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recessions vs. Expansion
Structure: This figure shows two panels side-by-side of line graphs. The panel on the left is labeled, Persistent Change and the panel on the right is labeled, Transitory Change. The y-axis on the left is labeled, Standard Deviation of five year-ahead earnings change and ranges from 0 to 1.3. The y-axis on the right is labeled, Standard Deviation of One year-ahead earnings change and ranges from 0 to 1. The x-axes are labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and ranges from 0 to 1. Each line graph has two lines a red line representing the recession and a blue line representing the expansion. 
Trends: In both instances, the overall shape of the lines is parabolic, inflecting around the 80th percentile. In the left graph, the two lines, expansion and recession, track each other very closely. In the right graph, the two lines have a very slight gap, but follow the same shape.
Main point: Variances of both the transitory and persistent shocks do not change much between recessions and expansions.
1][t]0.5
Transitory Change
Title: Figure 8: Dispersion of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recessions vs. Expansion
Structure: This figure shows two panels side-by-side of line graphs. The panel on the left is labeled, Persistent Change and the panel on the right is labeled, Transitory Change. The y-axis on the left is labeled, Standard Deviation of five year-ahead earnings change and ranges from 0 to 1.3. The y-axis on the right is labeled, Standard Deviation of One year-ahead earnings change and ranges from 0 to 1. The x-axes are labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and ranges from 0 to 1. Each line graph has two lines a red line representing the recession and a blue line representing the expansion. 
Trends: In both instances, the overall shape of the lines is parabolic, inflecting around the 80th percentile. In the left graph, the two lines, expansion and recession, track each other very closely. In the right graph, the two lines have a very slight gap, but follow the same shape.
Main point: Variances of both the transitory and persistent shocks do not change much between recessions and expansions.

Figure 7 is the first use of this graphical construct and contains a lot of information that will be referred to in the rest of this section. The top panel displays P90, P50 (median), and P10 of the distribution of long-run changes,  y_{t+5}^{i}-y_{t}^{i}, (on the y-axis) for each percentile of  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} (on the x-axis). To compare recessions and expansions, we averaged each one of these percentiles separately over the four recessions (lines marked with "circles") and three expansions (solid blue lines) during our sample period.17 Similarly, because these figures look similar across age groups, to save space we also averaged across the age groups.

First, notice the variation in these percentiles as we move to the right along the x-axis. Interestingly, the following pattern holds in both recessions and expansions: At any point in time, individuals with the lowest levels of past average earnings face the largest dispersion of earnings shocks (  y_{t+k}-y_{t}) looking forward. That is, L90-10 is widest for these individuals and falls in a very smooth fashion moving to the right. Indeed, workers who are between the 70th and 90th percentiles of the  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} distribution face the smallest dispersion of shocks looking ahead. As we continue moving to the right (into the top 10 percent), the shock distribution widens again. Notice that the P10 and P90 of the  y_{t+5}^{i}-y_{t}^{i} distribution look like the mirror image of each other relative to the median, so the variation in L90-10 as we move to the right is driven by similar variations in P90 and P10 individually.

Turning to the bottom panel, the same graph is plotted now for  y_{t+1}-y_{t} (transitory shocks).18 Precisely, the same qualitative features are seen here, with low- and high-income individuals facing a wider dispersion of persistent shocks than those in the "safer" zones--between the 70th and 90th percentiles. Of course, the scales of both graphs are different: the overall dispersion of persistent shocks is much larger than that of transitory shocks, which is to be expected. To summarize, both graphs reveal very strong and systematic variation in the dispersion of persistent and transitory earnings shocks across individuals with different past earnings levels.19

Now we turn to two key questions of interest. First, what happens to idiosyncratic shocks in recessions? For example, are shock variances countercyclical? And second, how does any potential change in the distribution of idiosyncratic shocks vary across earnings levels (i.e., the cross-partial derivative)? In other words, do we see the shock distribution of individuals in different earnings levels being affected differently by recessions?

5.0.0.2 Are Shock Variances Countercyclical?

The existing literature has largely focused on the cyclicality of persistent shocks, so this is where we also start (top panel of Figure 7). First, note that both P90 and P10 shift downward by similar amounts from expansion to recession. (As can be anticipated from this, the L90-10 gap changes by very little over the business cycle, as we shall see momentarily.) Furthermore, following the same steps as the one used to construct these graphs, one can also compute the standard deviation of  y_{t+5}-y_{t} conditional on  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} during recessions and expansions, which is plotted in the left panel of Figure 8. The two graphs (for expansions and recessions) virtually overlap, over the entire range of pre-episode earnings levels. For transitory shocks (bottom panel), there is more of a gap, but the two lines are still quite close to each other.

Figure 9: Ratio of Shock Dispersion Measures: Recession over Expansion
Title: Figure 9: Ratio of Shock Dispersion Measures: Recession over Expansion
Structure: This figure shows a single panel line graph with five lines. The y-axis is labeled, Ratio of Dispersion Measures: Recessions over Expansion and ranges from 0.8 to 2. The x-axis is labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and ranges from 0 to 100. The four data lines are as follows: a red-dotted five year standard deviation ratio line, a black-dotted five year L90-10 ratio, a solid, black one year L90-10 ratio line and a solid, red one year standard deviation ratio line. The fifth line is a blue, dashed line labeled, Storesletten et al (2004)'s benchmark estimate: 1.75, which has a y-value of 1.75 across all x-values. 
Trends: Nearly all four data lines are bunched around a y-value of one. The solid, black one year L90-10 ratio line rises above the rest, to about 1.15 over the 10th-90th percentiles, but remains close to one at the beginning and end. The solid, red one year standard deviation ratio line alright rises slightly above the other lines, but not nearly as much as the solid, black line. 
Main point: The variance of persistent shocks and transitory shock are acyclical; do not change over the business cycle.

To make the measurement of countercyclicality more precise, Figure 9 plots the ratios of (i) standard deviations and (ii) L90-10s for recessions over expansions. For persistent shocks (lines marked with circles and squares), both the standard deviation and L90-10 measures are only about 2 percent higher in recessions than in expansions. In other words, while we find some evidence of countercyclicality, the magnitude is minuscule. For comparison, Storesletten et al. (2004) used indirect methods to estimate a standard deviation of 0.13 for innovations into a persistent AR(1) process during expansions and 0.21 for recessions. The ratio is 1.75 (marked on the figure for comparison) compared with the 1.02 we find in this paper. The figure also plots the same two ratios (L90-10 and standard deviations) for transitory shocks. Here we see a bit more movement relative to persistent shocks: the standard deviation is higher by about 4 percent (averaged across the x-axis) and L90-10 is higher by about 6 percent. These findings suggest that to the extent that recessions involve a larger dispersion of shocks, these are to be found in short-term shocks without much long-term effects. Having said that, these numbers are still very small compared with the values typically used in the literature.

A second question that was raised above was whether recessions affect the distribution of shocks differently in different parts of the earnings distribution. It is probably evident by now that the answer is, perhaps surprisingly, "no." This is seen in the three figures just discussed, but is most apparent in Figure 9, where the ratios are quite flat, especially for persistent shocks. Therefore, we conclude that when it comes to the variance of persistent shocks, different earnings groups are affected similarly by business cycle fluctuations.

5.1 Countercyclical (Left-)Skewness: A Tale of Two Tails

The obvious question now is: Do recessions have any effect on earnings shocks? The answer is yes, which could already be anticipated from Figure 7, by noting that while P90 and P10 move down together during recessions, P50 (the median of the shock distribution) remains extremely stable and moves down by only a little. This has important implications: L90-50 gets compressed during recessions, whereas L50-10 expands. In other words, for every earnings level  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i}, when individuals look ahead during a recession, they see a much smaller chance of upward movements (relative to an expansion), but a much higher chance of large downward movements. In fact, this result is not specific to using P90 or P10, but is pervasive across the entire distribution of future earnings growth rates. This can be seen in Figure 10, which plots the change in selected percentiles above (and including) the median from an expansion to a recession (top panel). The bottom panel shows selected percentiles below the median. Starting from the top, and focusing on the middle part of the x-axis, we see that P99 falls by about 30 log points from an expansion to a recession, whereas P95 falls by 20, P90 falls by 15, P75 falls by 6, and P50 falls by 5 log points, respectively. As a result, the entire upper half of the shock distribution gets squeezed toward the median. In other words, the half of the population who experience earnings change above the median now experience ever smaller upward moves during recessions. Turning to the bottom panel, we see the opposite pattern: P50 falls by 5 log points, whereas P25 falls by 9, and P10 falls by 20 log points, respectively. Consequently, the bottom half of the shock distribution now expands, with "bad luck" meaning even "worse luck" during recessions.

Figure 10: Cyclical Changes in the Percentiles of the Persistent Shock Distribution
Title: Figure 10: Cyclical Changes in the Percentiles of the Persistent Shock Distribution
Structure: There are two line graphs, one on top of the other. The y-axes are, Change in the Percentiles of Persistent Shocks: Recession Expansion. In the top graph, this axis ranges from -0.5 to 0.1, while in the bottom graph it ranges from -0.4 to 0.1. The x-axes are, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution with both graphs ranging from 0 to 100. In the top graph, there are five lines. In order from top to bottom on the y-axis: a blue line with squares represents the 50th percentile, a tan line with triangles represents the 75th percentile, a red line with circles represents the 90th percentile, a pink line with diamonds represents the 95th percentile and a turquoise line with triangles represents the 99th percentile. On the bottom graph in order from top to bottom on the y-axis: a blue line with squares represents the 50th percentile, a green line with X's represents the 25th percentile and a black line with stars represents the 10th percentile. 
Trends: All the lines have negative y-values. The most negative values tend to be from the 99th percentile followed by the 90th percentile. The 50th percentile line is the least negative and all the other percentile lines fall somewhere between. In particular, focusing on the middle part of the x-axis,
we see that 99th percentile falls by about 30 log points from an expansion to a recession, whereas 95th percentile falls by 20, 90th percentile falls by 15, 75th percentile falls by 6, and 50th falls by 5 log points, respectively. Turning to the bottom panel, we see the opposite pattern: 50th percentile falls by 5 log points, whereas 25th percentile falls by 9, and 10 the percentile falls by 20 log points, respectively.
Main point: The entire top half of the shock distribution is being compressed towards the median, while the entire bottom half of the distribution is expanding.

From this analysis, a couple of conclusions can be drawn. First, idiosyncratic risk is countercyclical. However, this does not happen by a widening of the entire distribution (e.g., variance rising), but rather a shift toward a more left-skewed shock distribution. Although this is evident from the top end compressing and bottom end expanding, one can compute measures of skewness to document this. With higher order moments, one has to be careful about extreme observations. These are not likely to be outliers as with survey data, but even if they are genuine observations, we may want to be careful that a few observations do not affect the overall skewness measure. For this purpose, we use "Kelley's measure" of skewness, which relies on the quantiles of the distribution and is robust to extreme observations (Figure 11 ). It is also very straightforward to interpret, as we shall see in a moment. It is computed as the relative difference between the upper and lower tail inequalities: (L90-50 - L50-10)/L90-10. A negative number indicates that the lower tail is larger than the upper tail, and vice versa for a positive number.

Figure 11: Skewness of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recession vs. Expansion
Title: Figure 11: Skewness of the Earnings Growth Distribution: Recession vs. Expansion
Structure: This figure shows one line graph with five lines. The y-axis is labeled, Kelly's Skewness Measure and ranges from -0.4 to 0.1. The x-axis is labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and ranges from 0 to 100. The five lines are labeled as follows: a pink line with diamonds is labeled, 1-Yr: Recession, a blue line with triangles is labeled, 1-Yr: Expansion, a black line with squares is labeled, 5-Yr: Expansion, a red line with circles is labeled, 5-Yr: Recession, and a green line with stars is labeled, 5-Yr: Recession (alternative). Trends: All five lines exhibit a similar pattern. They begin between 0 and .01 on the y-axis. The lines then follow a concave shape, with some lines, such as the one year recession line, the five year recession line and the five year recession alternative line, showing more concavity. The lines begin to rebound, generally, from the 70th to the 100th percentile on the x-axis, but still remain in the negatives. 
Main point: The distribution of shocks become significantly more negatively left skewed during recessions, for both transitory and persistent shocks.

Turning to Figure 11, first, notice that individuals in higher earnings percentiles face a more negatively skewed shock distribution, consistent with the idea that the higher an individual's earnings is, the more it has room to fall. Second, and more importantly, this negative skewness increases during recessions for both transitory and persistent shocks. For example, for individuals at the median of the  \overline {Y}_{t-1} distribution, Kelley's measure for persistent shocks averages -0.14 during expansions. This number has a simple interpretation. It says that the dispersion of shocks above P50 accounts for 43 percent of overall L90-10 dispersion. Similarly, dispersion below P50 accounts for the remaining 57 percent (hence  (43\%-57\%)/100\%=-0.14) of L90-10. In recessions, however, this figure falls to -0.30, indicating that L90-50 accounts for 35 percent of L90-10 and the remaining 65 percent is due to L50-10. This is a substantial shift in the shape of the persistent shock distribution over the business cycle. The change in the skewness of transitory shocks is similar, if somewhat less pronounced. It goes from -0.14 down to -0.25 at the median. As seen in Figure 11, the increased left-skewness during recessions is pervasive--it takes place across the entire earnings distribution with similar magnitudes (with the exception of very low-income individuals).

Figure 12: Histogram of Title: Figure 12: Histogram of y(t+1)- y(t): U.S. Data 1995-96 vs. 2008-09
Structure: This figure shows two panels, side-by-side. The first panel, labeled, Densities: Recession vs. Expansion, shows two overlaid histograms. The second panel, labeled, Gap: Recession Expansion, is a line graph that shows the difference between the two overlaid histograms in panel one. The y-axis in the left panel is labeled, Density and ranges from 0 to 4. The y-axis in the right panel is labeled, Density Gap and ranges from -1 to 0.6. The x-axes are labeled, y(t+1)- y(t) and range from -1 to 1. In the left panel, a red histogram represents the 2008-09 recession year and a blue-dashed line represents the 1995-96 expansion year. In the right panel, a sold, blue line has the label, Wage growth density gap: 2008-09 minus 1995-96. Trends: In the overlaid distribution, the recession's negative tail is expanded outward, slightly, relative to the expansion year. Oppositely, the recession's positive tail is contracted inward, slightly, relative to the expansion year. Towards the peak of the histograms, just to the left of zero, the 1995-96 histogram is slightly left leaning. These differences are apparent in the left graph. As x approaches zero, the density gap is increasing, reaching a peak of about 0.1, before falling sharply just before zero, to a low exceeding -0.8. Past zero, the value of the difference increases, dramatically, to approximately 0.4, between 0 and 0.2 on the x-axis. The value of the difference then falls sharply, to a low of around -0.1 at around 0.2 on the x-axis, before rising slowly towards zero for the remaining x-values. 
Main point:  This indicates that recessions are times when it becomes less likely for anybody to experience large upward earnings changes, whereas the risk of falling off the income ladder becomes significantly higher.: U.S. Data 1995-96 vs. 2008-09
1][t]0.5
Densities: Recession vs. Expansion
 Title:Figure 12: Histogram of y(t+1)- y(t): U.S. Data 1995-96 vs. 2008-09 Structure: This figure shows two panels, side-by-side. The first panel, labeled, Densities: Recession vs. Expansion, shows two overlaid histograms. The second panel, labeled, Gap: Recession - Expansion, is a line graph that shows the difference between the two overlaid histograms in panel one. The y-axis in the left panel is labeled, Density and ranges from 0 to 4. The y-axis in the right panel is labeled, Density Gap and ranges from -1 to 0.6. The x-axes are labeled, y(t+1)- y(t) and range from -1 to 1. In the left panel, a red histogram represents the 2008-09 recession year and a blue-dashed line represents the 1995-96 expansion year. In the right panel, a sold, blue line has the label, Wage growth density gap: 2008-09 minus 1995-96. Trends: In the overlaid distribution, the recession's negative tail is expanded outward, slightly, relative to the expansion year. Oppositely, the recession's positive tail is contracted inward, slightly, relative to the expansion year. Towards the peak of the histograms, just to the left of zero, the 1995-96 histogram is slightly left leaning. These differences are apparent in the left graph. As x approaches zero, the density gap is increasing, reaching a peak of about 0.1, before falling sharply just before zero, to a low exceeding -0.8. Past zero, the value of the difference increases, dramatically, to approximately 0.4, between 0 and 0.2 on the x-axis. The value of the difference then falls sharply, to a low of around -0.1 at around 0.2 on the x-axis, before rising slowly towards zero for the remaining x-values. 
Main point:  This indicates that recessions are times when it becomes less likely for anybody to experience large upward earnings changes, whereas the risk of falling off the income ladder becomes significantly higher.
1][t]0.5
Gap: Recession - Expansion
 Title:Figure 12: Histogram of y(t+1)- y(t): U.S. Data 1995-96 vs. 2008-09 Structure: This figure shows two panels, side-by-side. The first panel, labeled, Densities: Recession vs. Expansion, shows two overlaid histograms. The second panel, labeled, Gap: Recession - Expansion, is a line graph that shows the difference between the two overlaid histograms in panel one. The y-axis in the left panel is labeled, Density and ranges from 0 to 4. The y-axis in the right panel is labeled, Density Gap and ranges from -1 to 0.6. The x-axes are labeled, y(t+1)- y(t) and range from -1 to 1. In the left panel, a red histogram represents the 2008-09 recession year and a blue-dashed line represents the 1995-96 expansion year. In the right panel, a sold, blue line has the label, Wage growth density gap: 2008-09 minus 1995-96. Trends: In the overlaid distribution, the recession's negative tail is expanded outward, slightly, relative to the expansion year. Oppositely, the recession's positive tail is contracted inward, slightly, relative to the expansion year. Towards the peak of the histograms, just to the left of zero, the 1995-96 histogram is slightly left leaning. These differences are apparent in the left graph. As x approaches zero, the density gap is increasing, reaching a peak of about 0.1, before falling sharply just before zero, to a low exceeding -0.8. Past zero, the value of the difference increases, dramatically, to approximately 0.4, between 0 and 0.2 on the x-axis. The value of the difference then falls sharply, to a low of around -0.1 at around 0.2 on the x-axis, before rising slowly towards zero for the remaining x-values. 
Main point:  This indicates that recessions are times when it becomes less likely for anybody to experience large upward earnings changes, whereas the risk of falling off the income ladder becomes significantly higher.

To understand how different this conclusion is from a simple countercyclical variance formulation, recall Figure 1, which plots the densities of two Normal random variables: one with zero mean and a standard deviation of 0.13 (expansion) and a second one with a mean of -0.03 and a standard deviation of 0.21 (recession; both numbers from Storesletten et al. (2004)). As seen here, the substantial increase in variance and small fall in the mean imply that many individuals will receive larger positive shocks in recessions than in expansions under this formulation. For comparison, the left panel of Figure 12 plots the empirical densities of earnings growth from the U.S. data, comparing the 1995-96 period to the worst year of the Great Recession (2008-09). To highlight how the density changes, the right panel plots the difference between the two densities. As seen here, the probability mass on the right side shifts from large positive shocks to more modest ones; on the left side, it shifts from small negative shocks to even larger negative ones. Thus, recessions are times when it becomes less likely for anybody to experience large upward earnings changes, whereas the risk of falling off the income ladder becomes significantly higher.

Interestingly, in one of the earliest papers on cyclical changes in earnings risk, Mankiw (1986) postulated that in recessions, a fraction  \lambda of individuals all draw the same negative shock, which adds up to  -\mu. So, ex ante, each person views a recession as a state where, with probability  \lambda, their individual earnings will drop by  -\mu/\lambda. Thus, negative shocks are concentrated among a subset of individuals in recessions. This structure induces a left-skewness of the same sort discovered in our analysis here, unlike the countercyclical variance structure proposed by Constantinides and Duffie (1996) and others.20

5.1.0.1 An Alternative Parametric Approach.

The approach in this paper has been non-parametric, which was made feasible with the very large sample size. However, an alternative approach that has been used in the literature relies on fitting a separate AR(1) process to each individual's time series of earnings (see, e.g., Bloom et al. (2011)). We have implemented different versions of this method as well. In the most general case, we first ran the following regression:

\displaystyle \tilde{y}_{t,h}^{i}=\beta^{i}\times(\overline{y}_{t}^{A}-\overline{y}^{A})+\left[a^{i}+b^{i}h+c^{i}h^{2}\right]+\xi_{t,h}^{i}, (3)

to account for a factor structure (first term; where  \overline{y}_{t}^{A} is average log earnings) and an individual-specific life cycle component (terms in square brackets). We then fit an AR(1) to the residual earnings,  \xi_{t,h}^{i}, and studied the cyclical properties of the estimated innovation series. This analysis yielded the same substantive conclusions as those reported in this paper. For completeness, we report these results below in Appendix C. As seen there, the skewness of these innovations mirrors that reported in Figure 6 almost exactly.


5.2 What Role Does Unemployment Play?

How much of the countercyclicality of left-skewness is due to the fact that unemployment rises in recessions, so more individuals experience large negative earnings changes, because they are part-year unemployed? In this section, we address this question.

Recall that the MEF dataset does not contain information on labor hours or unemployment. However, providing an upper bound on the potential effects of unemployment is still possible. To begin with, notice that unemployment (or non-employment) can affect our results through two separate channels. First, workers that are full-year non-employed are excluded from the sample in that year. This creates a truncation at the bottom end of the earnings growth distribution, whose severity varies over the business cycle. Second, many individuals who are unemployed part of the year are still included in our sample as long as their full-year earnings remains above  Y_{\text{min}}. Incidentally, both of these assumptions are precisely the same ones made in the bulk of existing literature on income risk. But it is useful to discuss whether and, if so, how they might be affecting our results, especially the findings on skewness.

5.2.0.1 The Effect of Part-Year Unemployment.

First, a key observation that repeatedly came up in the previous discussion is that the countercyclicality of left-skewness is due to equal parts of (i) the compression of positive earnings growth changes toward the median and (ii) the expansion of negative earnings growth rates toward the bottom end (clearly seen in figures 4, 7, 10, and 12). The compression at the top is unlikely to be related to unemployment. So even if the bottom half were to remain unchanged, skewness would be more negative during recessions due to the compression at the top alone.21

Table I.a: Incidence of Unemployment over the Business Cycle, Prime-Age Males
CPS data Year: CPS data x>0 (wks) CPS data x>13 CPS data x>26
1979 10.5 4.4 1.5
1984 11.4 6.3 2.8
1989 10.0 4.7 1.8
1994 9.5 5.2 2.3
1999 6.0 3.0 1.1
2004 6.5 3.6 1.4
2005 6.7 3.6 1.4
2010 10.4 6.6 3.2
avg.  t 8.3 3.9 1.5
avg.  t+5 9.4 5.4 2.4

\begin{spacing} % latex2html id marker 631 {0.65000000000000002} \emph{\scriptsize Note:}{\scriptsize {} The left panel reports the incidence of unemployment with duration exceeding $x$\ weeks. The first column in the right panel reports the fraction of individuals who are full year non-employed in $t+1$\ (denoted $N$) conditional on being employed in $t$\ (denoted }\emph{\scriptsize E}{\scriptsize ). The last column shows the opposite transition. }\end{spacing}


Table I.b: Incidence of Unemployment over the Business Cycle, Prime-Age Males
SSA data Period: SSA data  E\rightarrow N SSA data  N\rightarrow E
1979-83 5.1 4.4
1983-90 4.1 3.8
1990-92 3.8 2.7
1992-00 3.1 2.8
2000-02 3.7 2.3
2002-07 3.2 2.7
2007-10 4.5 2.3
Expansion 3.5 3.1
Recession 4.3 2.9

\begin{spacing} % latex2html id marker 653 {0.65000000000000002} \emph{\scriptsize Note:}{\scriptsize {} The left panel reports the incidence of unemployment with duration exceeding $x$\ weeks. The first column in the right panel reports the fraction of individuals who are full year non-employed in $t+1$\ (denoted $N$) conditional on being employed in $t$\ (denoted }\emph{\scriptsize E}{\scriptsize ). The last column shows the opposite transition. }\end{spacing}

Second, the countercyclicality of left-skewness is very apparent in 5-year earnings changes. Because the duration of recessions is less than five years, (the incidence of) unemployment is only slightly higher in  t+5 than in  t. For example, using data from the Current Population Survey (Integrated Public Use Microdata Series--IPUMS), we compute the fraction of 35-54 year-old males that experiences an unemployment spell longer than  x weeks in a given year, for  x=0,13, and 26 weeks. The left panel of Table I reports the results for key years in our analysis.

Consider spells longer than 13 weeks (third column). Only 5.4 percent of prime-age males are in this group in year  t+5 (averaging over 1984, 1994, 2004, and 2010). Now let us assume that (i) none of these individuals spent any time in unemployment in year  t and (ii) their actual wages and hours remained the same in  t and  t+5 while they were employed. Then, for these individuals unemployment reduces their annual earnings by at least 25 log points between  t and  t+5. So this would appear as a negative earnings shock of 25+ log points. Similarly, the average incidence in year  t is 3.9 percent, so by the same computation, these individuals will appear as having received a positive shock of 25+ log points between  t and  t+k. So the net effect on skewness depends on the gap:  5.4-3.9=1.5 percent of individuals who get more negative shocks than positive in year  t+k. If we assume for the moment that these individuals are evenly spread across the  \overline {Y}_{t-1} distribution, it would amount to a 1.5 percent net change of the sample within each quantile. This is a very small number considering that the entire bottom half of the shock distribution is expanding during recessions (and, of course, the entire upper end is compressing). The same computation can be repeated for  x=0 or  x=26 weeks, with very similar results.22

As an alternative way to investigate the sensitivity of our results, we repeat the computation of skewness, but this time using  t=1980,1990, and 2000 and excluding the Great Recession. With this timing, year  t+5 is well into the expansion, so the incidence of unemployment of 13 weeks or longer is only 0.4 percent higher in  t+5 compared with  t. Figure 11 (line marked with stars) plots Kelley's skewness averaged over these three recessions. Even with the Great Recession excluded and unemployment almost unchanged, skewness becomes significantly more negative during these three recessions.

Overall, this analysis suggests that the direct effect of unemployment is likely to be small for the results on skewness.23 The cyclical changes in unemployment for prime-age males is simply too small to account for the countercyclicality of skewness, which is observed across the entire range of past earnings levels and earnings growth rates.

5.2.0.2 Excluding Zeros (Full-Year Non-employed).

A second and separate issue relates to our exclusion of full-year non-employed individuals. If anything, this assumption is truncating the actual downside risk in recessions and is understating the countercyclicality of skewness. This can be seen as follows. Using our sample, we compute the fraction of individuals that are in the sample in year  t but not in  t+1 for every year of the sample. Then for each business cycle episode, we report the average figure in the right panel of Table I. Not surprisingly, we are dropping more individuals from the sample in each recession (given that the likelihood of full-year non-employment rises). On average we are dropping 4.3 percent of individuals from our sample in year  t+1 during recessions and 3.5 percent during expansions. If these excluded individuals were included (for example, by assigning them a nominal earnings level, say, $100 in that year), this would register as a large earnings drop in recessions and increase the left-skewness in recessions. At the same time, because the change over the business cycle is small, the effect would also be small.


6 Between-Group (Systematic) Business Cycle Risk

We now turn to the factor structure, or between-group, component of earnings risk. The goal here is to understand the extent to which earnings growth during a business cycle episode can be predicted by available observable characteristics prior to the episode.

It is useful to begin with equation (2) to compute the mean log earnings change conditional on characteristics as of  t-1:

\displaystyle \mathbb{E}(y_{t+k}^{i}-y_{t}^{i}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i}) \displaystyle =f_{1}(\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})(\lambda_{t+k}-\lambda_{t})+\underset{=0}{\underbrace{\mathbb{E}(\eta_{t+k}+\eta_{t+k-1}+...+\eta_{t+1}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})}}    
  \displaystyle +\underset{=0}{\underbrace{\mathbb{E}(\varepsilon_{t+k}^{i}-\varepsilon_{t}^{i}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})}}. (4)

Taking the means within each group eliminates both permanent and transitory shocks (since they average zero by assumption), yielding

\displaystyle \mathbb{E}(y_{t+k}^{i}-y_{t}^{i}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})=f_{1}(\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})(\lambda_{t+k}-\lambda_{t}). (5)

Equation (5) provides a simple expression for between-group variation in earnings growth. Between any two periods  t and  t+k, each group has a different loading factor  f_{1}(\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i}) on the aggregate shock  (\lambda_{t+k}-\lambda_{t}). The key object of interest is  f_{1}, whose shape will tell us about the factor structure of earnings changes over the business cycle.24

6.0.0.1 Caution: Mean Reversion Ahead.

The derivation of equation (5) relies on the assumption that earnings changes do not exhibit mean reversion. However, if  z_{t} is in fact a mean-reverting process and  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} is one of the conditioning variables,  f_{1} will be a decreasing function of  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} in the absence of any factor structure, simply because of mean reversion.25 So if the estimated  f_{1} shows any sign of upward slope (overcoming this potential downward bias), this would be a strong indication of a factor structure.

6.0.0.2 An Alternative Measure of Factor Structure: Incorporating Zeros.

One drawback of the  f_{1} measure is that the left-hand side of equation (5) can only be computed using individuals whose earnings are positive in year  t and  t+k (so that log earnings is finite). As noted above, the fraction of individuals that are excluded varies over the business cycle. Although the average number of such individuals is not very large, it varies systematically with  \overline {Y}_{t-1}, which could be important to take into account. Thus, we also construct a modified measure for the left-hand side of (5): We use all individuals that belong to  \mathbf {V}_{t-1}^{i} to compute the average earnings in  t and in  t+k and then take the logs of these averages to compute

\displaystyle f_{2}(\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})\equiv\mathbb{\log E}(Y_{t+k}^{i}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})-\mathbb{\log E}(Y_{t}^{i}\vert\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i}). (6)

This measure now includes both the intensive margin and the extensive margin of earnings changes between two periods.26 It will be our preferred measure in this section. In Appendix B, we also compare it with the results with  f_{1} and discuss the differences between the two measures more fully.


6.1 Variation Between  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} Groups

Figure 13: Growth in Log Average Earnings during Recessions, Prime-Age (35-54) Males
Title: Figure 13: Growth in Log Average Earnings during Recessions, Prime-Age (35-54) Males
Structure: This single-panel figure is a line graph with four lines. The y-axis is labeled, Changes in Log Average Income During Recession and ranges from -0.35 to 0.1. The x-axis is labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and ranges from 0 to 100. The lines are as follows: a red line with circles represents 1979-83, a blue-dashed line represents 1990-92, a solid, green line represents 2000-02 and a black line with squares represents 2007-10. 
Trends: The 1990-92, 2000-02 and 2007-10 recession lines all, initially, have sharp drops, that begin rebounding by about the first or second percentiles. However, the 2007-10 y-intercept is about 0.18 lower than the other two. The 1979-83 recession line shows a dramatic drop over the entire 10th percentile. Starting from around 0.4 and arriving at around -0.15 by the 10th percentile on the x-axis. From there, the lines tend to trend upward, but the 1979-83 and 2007-10 recession lines are much more negative than the 1990-92 and 2000-02 lines. By the top percentile group (90 and above), the 2000-02 and 2007-10 lines show sharp decreases of around 0.28 and 0.18, respectively. 
Main point: For the majority of individuals below the 90th percentile, earnings loss during recessions decreases almost linearly with the pre-recession average earnings level. For the very high-income individuals, more recent recessions have shown substantial earnings losses, unlike previous recessions.

We estimate  f_{2}(\overline{Y}_{t-1}^{i}) for each recession and expansion and separately for each of the six age groups defined above. As we show in Appendix B, the four age groups between ages 35 and 54 behave very similarly to each other over the business cycle. Motivated by this finding, from this point on we combine these individuals into one group and refer to them as "prime-age males." We also combine the first two age groups into one and refer to them as "young workers" (ages 25 to 34). For brevity, we focus on prime-age males in this paper and present the results for young workers in Appendix B.

6.1.1 Recessions

Figure 13 plots the  f_{2} function for prime-age males for the four recessions during our sample period. For the Great Recession (black line with squares),  f_{2} is upward sloping in an almost linear fashion and rises by about 17 log points between the 10th and 90th percentiles. So, workers with pre-recession average earnings in the 10th percentile saw their earnings decline by about 25 log points during the recession, compared with a decline of only 8 log points for workers in the 90th percentile.27 Clearly, this factor structure leads to a significant widening of earnings inequality over much of the distribution. However, this good fortune of high-income individuals does not extend to the very top:  f_{2} first flattens beyond the 90th percentile and then for the top 1 percent, it actually falls very steeply. Specifically, those in the top 1 percent experienced an average loss of 27 log points compared with 12.5 log points for those in the second highest percentile. One conclusion we draw is that individuals near the 90th percentile of the average earnings distribution (about $100,000 per year) as of 2006 have suffered the smallest loss of any earnings group.

Turning to the other major recession in our sample--the 1979-83 episode-- f_{2} looks very similar to the Great Recession period between the 10th percentile and about the 95th percentile, with the same linear shape and a slightly smaller slope. However, for individuals with very low average earnings (below the 10th percentile), the graph is downward sloping, indicating some mean reversion during the recession.28 Also, and perhaps surprisingly, there is no steep fall in earnings for the top 1 percent during this recession--in fact, these individuals experienced the highest earnings growth of all income groups during this recession. Overall, however, for the majority of workers, the 1979-83 recession was very similar to--slightly milder than--the Great Recession, in terms of both its between-group implications and its average effect. Of course, the former contains two actual recessions and lasts one extra year, which shows the severity of the latter.

As for the other two recessions during this period, both of them feature modest falls in average earnings--about 3 log points for the median individual in these graphs. The 1990-92 recession also features mild but clear between-group differences, with  f_{2} rising linearly by about 7 log points between the 10th and 90th percentiles.29 The 2000-02 recession overlaps remarkably well with the former up to about the 70th percentile and then starts to diverge downward. In particular, there is a sharp drop after the 90th percentile. In fact, for the top 1 percent, this recession turns out to have the worst outcomes of all recessions--an average drop of 33 log points in two years!

Inspecting the behavior of  f_{2} above the 90th percentile reveals an interesting pattern. For the first two recessions in our sample period, very high-income individuals fared better than anybody else in the population, whereas for the latest two recessions, there has been a remarkable reversal of these fortunes and the highest-income workers suffered the most.

Figure 14: Growth in Log Average earnings during Expansions, Prime-Age Males
Title: Figure 14: Growth in Log Average earnings during Expansions, Prime-Age Males Structure: This single-panel figure is a line graph with three lines. The y-axis is labeled, Change in Log Average Income During Expansion and ranges from -0.1 to 0.4. The x-axis is labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and ranges from 0 to 100. The lines are as follows: a red line with circles represents 1983-1990, a blue line with squares represents 1992-2000 and a green line with diamonds represents 2002-2007. 
Trends: All three lines show a parabolic shape. The y-intercepts start for 1983-1990, 1992-2000 and 2002-2007 are roughly 0.2, 0.45 and 0.1, respectively. The lines then show sharp decline over the 10th percentile and a steady decline until all three lines converge, roughly around the 55th percentile. There is then an increase until the top percentile for the 1983-1990 and 2002-2007 lines. The 1992-2000 line also shows an increase, but there is a very sharp decline in the top percentile. 
Main point: This suggests that the individuals above the median of average past income distribution have experienced the faster earnings growth. For the workers below the median, 1992-2000 expansion is most favorable to low income workers.

To sum up our findings for prime-age males, there is a very clear systematic pattern to average earnings growth during recessions. For the substantial majority of individuals below the 90th percentile, earnings loss during a recession varies (specifically, decreases) almost linearly with the pre-recession average earnings level. The slope of this relationship also varies with the severity of the recession: the severe recessions of 1979-83 and 2007-10 saw a gap between the 90th and 10th percentiles in the range of 15 log points, whereas the milder recessions of 1990-92 and 2000-02 saw a gap of 4-7 log points. Second, the fortunes of very high-income individuals require a different classification, one that varies over time: more recent recessions have seen substantial earnings losses for high-income individuals, unlike anything seen in previous ones. Below we will further explore the behavior of the top 1 percent over the business cycle.

6.1.2 Expansions

Figure 14 plots the counterpart of the  f_{2} function during expansions. Broadly speaking, during expansions  f_{2} displays either a U-shape or a hockey stick shape, which is in stark contrast to the pervasive upward-sloping figure that emerges during recessions.

For prime-age males, there is a clear pattern for workers that enter an expansion with average earnings above roughly the 70th percentile: the  f_{2} function is upward sloping, indicating further spreading out of the earnings distribution at the top during expansions. For workers below the median, income behavior has varied across expansions. The 1990s expansion has been the most favorable, with a strong mean reversion raising the incomes of workers at the lower end relative to the median. The other two expansions show little factor structure in favor of low-income workers--the function is quite flat, indicating that earnings changes have been relatively unrelated to past earnings.

The pronounced U-shape pattern in the 1990s can be viewed as a stronger version of what Autor et al. (2006) called "wage polarization" during this period. Basically, these authors compared the percentiles of the wage distribution at different points in time and concluded that the lower and higher percentiles grew more during the 1990s than the middle percentiles. Figure 14 goes one step further by following the same individuals over time and showing that it is precisely those individuals whose pre-1990s earnings were lowest and highest that experienced fastest growth during the 1990s.

Figure 15: Growth in Log Average earnings: Expansions vs. Recessions, All Workers
Title: Figure 15: Growth in Log Average earnings: Expansions vs. Recessions, All Workers
Structure: This single-panel figure is a line graph with two lines. The y-axis is labeled, Mean Log Income Change During Episode and ranges from -0.1 to 0.35. The x-axis is labeled, Percentiles of past 5-Year Average Income Distribution and ranges from 0 to 100. There is one blue line with circles representing expansion and one red line with squares representing recession. 
 Trends: The expansion line shows a very distinct U shape, with a slight dip in the top percentile. The expansion line is almost entirely above the recession line, except between the 50th and 80th percentile where the lines meet at around -0.04 on the y-axis. The recession line starts slightly above zero for the lowest percentile and then declines to about -0.7 before rising steadily, but still remains below zero throughout. Towards the top percentiles, there is a sharp decline, with the top percentile at around -0.15. 
Main point: This indicates the main cyclical impact of the business cycles is felt below the median, which expands during recessions and compresses during expansions.
Note: The recession graph has been scaled upward by 6.5 log points to be tangent to the Expansion graph.

6.1.3 Putting Recessions and Expansions Together

To summarize these patterns, Figure 15 aggregates  f_{2} across all age groups and combines separate recessions and expansions. As seen here, a U-shape emerges during expansions--indicating a compression of the earnings distribution at the bottom and expansion at the top. In contrast, recessions reveal an upward-sloping figure, indicating a widening of the entire distribution except at the very top (above the 95th percentile). Thus, the main cyclical impact of business cycles is felt below the median, which expands during recessions and compresses during expansions. The same pattern also emerges at the top--inside the top 10 percent of the earnings distribution.

Put together, these factor structures seen in Figure 15 explain how the earnings distribution expands in recessions and contracts in expansions (resulting in countercyclical earnings inequality) without within-group (idiosyncratic) shocks having countercyclical variances.

6.2 Rising Stars versus Stagnant Careers

We now control for three characteristics simultaneously: age,  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i}, and  \Delta_{5}(y_{t-1}^{i}). Because the 1979-83 period does not allow us to construct the pre-episode growth rate, we drop it from the analysis of this section.

We first sort individuals within an age group according to their  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} and  \Delta_{5}(y_{t-1}^{i}) (independently in each dimension) and compute 50- and 40-quantile thresholds, respectively. We use these thresholds to assign each individual into groups formed by the intersection of age, pre-episode average earnings (indexed by  j), and earnings growth (indexed by  p) categories. To give an idea about the bounds of a typical group, for the analysis of the Great Recession, one such group will consist of individuals who (i) were between the ages of 35 and 39 in year 2006, (iii) earned average annual earnings (  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i}) between $32,033 and $33,455 from 2002 to 2006, and (iii) experienced an annual earnings growth rate between 1.30 percent and 1.49 percent per year from 2002 to 2006. Clearly, this is a very finely defined group of individuals. For each of these 2000 cells, we compute the average labor earnings:  y_{t}^{j,p} and  y_{t+k}^{j,p}.30 We then regress

\displaystyle y_{t+k}^{j,p}-y_{t}^{j,p}=\sum_{j=1}^{50}\alpha_{j}d_{\overline{Y}}^{j}+\sum_{p=1}^{40}\gamma_{p}d_{\Delta y^{i}}^{p}+u_{t}^{j,p}, (7)

where  d_{\overline{Y}}^{j} is a dummy variable that equals one if the group on the left hand side belongs in the  j^{\text{th}} quantile of the  \overline {Y}_{t-1} distribution and zero otherwise. The dummy  d_{\Delta y^{i}}^{p} is defined analogously for the quantiles of  \Delta_{5}(y_{t-1}^{i}). The 90 dummies are estimated via ordinary least squares.

First, in Appendix B, we show that the additional control for  \Delta_{5}(y_{t-1}^{i}) has virtually no effect on the results of the previous section when we only conditioned on  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i} (see Figure A.8). Second, the main finding is that pre-episode earnings growth has a significant effect on future growth. This is shown in Figure 16, which plots average earnings growth during expansions (blue line with circle markers) and recessions (red line with square markers). While mean reversion is apparent in both cases, the gap between the two graphs is smallest in the middle and expands at both ends. This is clearly seen in the right panel, which plots the annualized gap between expansions and recessions. The implication is that workers with the highest and lowest earnings growth rates prior to an episode do better during expansions than recessions. This is related to the fact documented earlier that the top of the earnings shock distribution collapses during recessions. Consequently, the earnings growth rate of those individuals whose earnings would have grown faster during expansions actually slows down during a recession.31

Figure 16: Growth in Log Average Earnings by Quantiles of Recent Growth Rate
1][t]0.5
Expansion vs. Recession
Title: Figure 16: Growth in Log Average Earnings by Quantiles of Recent Growth Rate
Structure: This figure has two line graphs side-by-side. The left panel is labeled, Expansion vs. Recession and the right panel is labeled, Expansion Minus Recession. The y-axis on the left panel is labeled, Mean of y(t+k)- y(t): During an Episode and ranges from -0.05 to 0.05. The y-axis on the right panel is labeled, Mean of y(t+k)-y(t): Expansion Minus Recession and ranges from -0.005 to 0.035. The x-axes are labeled as quantiles of log income growth in the last five years and range from 0 to 100. The left panel has two lines. A blue line with circles represents expansion and a red line with squares represents recession. In the right panel, there is a single black line with circles. 
Trends: In the left panel, two lines show similar behavior between 0 and 60 on the x-axis. Both lines trend downward, though the red line starts at a lower value, leveling off by around the 20-30 on the x-axis. They both remain at approximately zero until the 60 on the x-axis. From here, the blue line continues to remain level before dipping at around 85 on the x-axis. The red line begins a downward trend starting from around 60 on the x-axis. In the right panel, the line exhibits a small rise between 0 and 10. It then starts a U shaped trend, declining between 10 and 30, before leveling off at around 0 on the y-axis. At just past 50, the line begins a steady upward rise, eventually reaching as high as 0.03 on the y-axis.
Main point: The implication is that workers with the highest and lowest earnings growth rates prior to an episode do better during expansions than recessions.
1][t]0.5
Expansion Minus Recession
Title: Figure 16: Growth in Log Average Earnings by Quantiles of Recent Growth Rate
Structure: This figure has two line graphs side-by-side. The left panel is labeled, Expansion vs. Recession and the right panel is labeled, Expansion Minus Recession. The y-axis on the left panel is labeled, Mean of y(t+k)- y(t): During an Episode and ranges from -0.05 to 0.05. The y-axis on the right panel is labeled, Mean of y(t+k)-y(t): Expansion Minus Recession and ranges from -0.005 to 0.035. The x-axes are labeled as quantiles of log income growth in the last five years and range from 0 to 100. The left panel has two lines. A blue line with circles represents expansion and a red line with squares represents recession. In the right panel, there is a single black line with circles. 
Trends: In the left panel, two lines show similar behavior between 0 and 60 on the x-axis. Both lines trend downward, though the red line starts at a lower value, leveling off by around the 20-30 on the x-axis. They both remain at approximately zero until the 60 on the x-axis. From here, the blue line continues to remain level before dipping at around 85 on the x-axis. The red line begins a downward trend starting from around 60 on the x-axis. In the right panel, the line exhibits a small rise between 0 and 10. It then starts a U shaped trend, declining between 10 and 30, before leveling off at around 0 on the y-axis. At just past 50, the line begins a steady upward rise, eventually reaching as high as 0.03 on the y-axis.
Main point: The implication is that workers with the highest and lowest earnings growth rates prior to an episode do better during expansions than recessions.


6.3 Broadening the Definition of Business Cycles

So far in the analysis, we have viewed business cycles as consisting of recessionary and expansionary episodes. But some important macroeconomic variables do not perfectly synchronize with these episodes. For example, as also mentioned earlier, unemployment peaked in 1993 and 2003--two years that are part of expansions. Similarly, the stock market experienced a significant drop in 1987, again during an expansion. With these considerations in mind, this section explores the robustness of our results to alternative indicators of business cycles.


Table II.a: Cyclicality of Earnings Growth, Prime-Age Males with Dependent variable: f_{2}^{j} 1978-2009
   \DeltaGDP  R_{t,t+1}^{\text{S}}  \Delta U
 x  \rightarrow  j: P99.9 3.07 0.43 -4.76
 x  \rightarrow  j: P99 1.45 0.20 -2.42
 x  \rightarrow  j: P90 1.48 0.06 -1.17
 x  \rightarrow  j: P75 0.75 0.06 -1.22
 x  \rightarrow  j: P50 1.04 0.09 -1.77
 x  \rightarrow  j: P25 1.63 0.14 -2.80
 x  \rightarrow  j: P10 1.85 0.17 -3.22
std. dev.(x) 2.10 16.80 1.23

\begin{spacing}{0.65000000000000002} \emph{\scriptsize Note:}{\scriptsize {} Each cell reports the $\beta^{j}$ estimated for individuals in earnings group $j$\ and for business cycle variable $x$. $R_{t,t+1}^{s}$\ is the annual realized return on the S\&P500 index (data obtained from Robert Shiller's website at Yale University). All regression coefficients are significant at 0.1 percent level when the regressor is the GDP growth or change in unemployment rate and are significant at 1 percent for stock returns.}\end{spacing}


Table II.b: Cyclicality of Earnings Growth, Prime-Age Males with Dependent variable: f_{2}^{j} 1985-2009
 \DeltaGDP  R_{t,t+1}^{\text{S}}  \Delta U  
 x  \rightarrow  j: P99.9 4.55 0.46 -6.87
 x  \rightarrow  j: P99 2.09 0.22 -3.34
 x  \rightarrow  j: P90 1.70 0.06 -1.21
 x  \rightarrow  j: P75 0.75 0.05 -1.13
 x  \rightarrow  j: P50 1.09 0.08 -1.74
 x  \rightarrow  j: P25 1.78 0.14 -2.86
 x  \rightarrow  j: P10 2.06 0.16 -3.34
std. dev.(x) 1.81 17.78 1.10

\begin{spacing}{0.65000000000000002} \emph{\scriptsize Note:}{\scriptsize {} Each cell reports the $\beta^{j}$ estimated for individuals in earnings group $j$\ and for business cycle variable $x$. $R_{t,t+1}^{s}$\ is the annual realized return on the S\&P500 index (data obtained from Robert Shiller's website at Yale University). All regression coefficients are significant at 0.1 percent level when the regressor is the GDP growth or change in unemployment rate and are significant at 1 percent for stock returns.}\end{spacing}

For a given quantile  j of  \overline {Y}_{t-1}, we regress the change between  t and  t+1 in log average earnings ( f_{2}^{j}) on alternative measures of business cycles, denoted with  x:

\displaystyle f_{2}^{j}(t,t+1)=\alpha^{j}+\beta^{j}x+\epsilon_{t}.

We consider three choices for  x: (log) growth rate in GDP per capita, the annual return on the U.S. stock market (as measured by the S&P500 index), and the annual change in the male unemployment rate (denoted  \Delta U). Table III displays the estimated  \beta^{j}s for several key quantiles and for two time periods: the full sample (1978 to 2009) and one that excludes the double-dip recession (1985 to 2009).

Several observations are worth noting. First, cyclicality is U-shaped across earnings quantiles, regardless of the business cycle variable chosen. This is consistent with the conclusion of Section 6.1 above, summarized in Figure 15. It is also consistent with Parker and Vissing-Jørgensen (2010)'s analysis using repeated cross sections and synthetic earnings groups. Second, cyclicality increases post-1985, especially at the very top of the earnings distribution and especially when business cycles are measured by GDP growth or the unemployment rate. Cyclicality is pretty flat in the middle of the earnings distribution (e.g., between P25 and P75) and increases slightly at the bottom end. Third, the co-movement of the earnings growth of top earners with GDP growth and stock returns is quite striking. For example, post-1985 a 1 percentage point rise in the male unemployment rate has been accompanied with an average earnings decline of 6.87 percent for individuals that were in P99.9 before the shock. Similarly, a 1 percentage point slowdown in GDP/capita growth implies a 4.55 percent decline in the earnings of the same individuals.32 For comparison, the corresponding numbers for individuals with median earnings is 1.08 and -1.77.


6.4 The Top 1 Percent

Figure 17: Earnings Growth, 1- and 5-Year, Top 1 percent of Prime-Age Males
1][t]1
Log 1-Year Growth in Mean Earnings ( f_{2})
Title: Figure 17: Earnings Growth, 1- and 5- Year, Top 1 percent of Prime-Age Males
Structure: This figure has two panels stacked one above the other. Both panels are line graphs with four lines. The top panel is labeled, Log 1-Year Growth in Mean Earnings (f2) and the bottom panel is labeled, Log 5-Year Growth in Mean Earnings (f2). The y-axis on the top panel is labeled, Log 1-Year Change in Mean Income Level and ranges from -0.4 to 0.2. The y-axis on the bottom panel is labeled, Log 5-Year Change in Mean Income Level and ranges from -0.5 to 0.5. The x-axes are labeled, Year and range from 1980 to 2010 in the top panel and 1980 to 2005 in the bottom. Each panel display the same five lines and they are as follows: a black line with circles represents P99.95, a green line with triangles represents P99.75, a red line with squares represents P99.45 and a blue line with diamonds represents P99.05. 
Trends: In both panels the lines all follow a similar trend. In the top panel, the lines show sharp dips, far below the zero-line, in the mid-1980s, mid-1990s, 2000-02 and 2006-08. However, during these periods the black line, representing P99.95, shows the sharpest dips. Conversely, during peaks, this line tends to rise above the rest. In the bottom panel, there are sharp dips below the zero line in the late 1980s, early 1990s, late 1990s to early 2000 and 2004. Again, in this panel, the black line is noticeably below the other lines throughout the timeframe. 
Main point: This indicates that cyclicality increases strongly with the level of earnings.
1][t]1
Log 5-Year Growth in Mean Earnings ( f_{2})
Title: Figure 17: Earnings Growth, 1- and 5- Year, Top 1 percent of Prime-Age Males
Structure: This figure has two panels stacked one above the other. Both panels are line graphs with four lines. The top panel is labeled, Log 1-Year Growth in Mean Earnings (f2) and the bottom panel is labeled, Log 5-Year Growth in Mean Earnings (f2). The y-axis on the top panel is labeled, Log 1-Year Change in Mean Income Level and ranges from -0.4 to 0.2. The y-axis on the bottom panel is labeled, Log 5-Year Change in Mean Income Level and ranges from -0.5 to 0.5. The x-axes are labeled, Year and range from 1980 to 2010 in the top panel and 1980 to 2005 in the bottom. Each panel display the same five lines and they are as follows: a black line with circles represents P99.95, a green line with triangles represents P99.75, a red line with squares represents P99.45 and a blue line with diamonds represents P99.05. 
Trends: In both panels the lines all follow a similar trend. In the top panel, the lines show sharp dips, far below the zero-line, in the mid-1980s, mid-1990s, 2000-02 and 2006-08. However, during these periods the black line, representing P99.95, shows the sharpest dips. Conversely, during peaks, this line tends to rise above the rest. In the bottom panel, there are sharp dips below the zero line in the late 1980s, early 1990s, late 1990s to early 2000 and 2004. Again, in this panel, the black line is noticeably below the other lines throughout the timeframe. 
Main point: This indicates that cyclicality increases strongly with the level of earnings.

We now take a closer look at top earners. To understand the differences and similarities within the top 1 percent, we divide this group into 10 quantiles and focus on the 1st, 5th, 8th, and 10th quantiles. We refer to each quantile by the middle point: P99.05, P99.45, P99.75, and P99.95 (the top 0.1 percent).

The top panel of Figure 17 plots the annual change using the  f_{2} measure for each of these quantiles. First, notice that the four groups move quite closely to each other until the late 1980s, after which point a clear ranking emerges: higher quantiles become more cyclical than lower ones. In particular, individuals in higher quantiles have seen their earnings plummet in recessions relative to lower quantiles, but did not see their earnings bounce back more in the subsequent expansion, which would have allowed them to catch up. In fact, during expansions, the average earnings in each group grew by similar amounts.

The implication is that these "differential losses" during recessions across earnings quantiles are also very persistent (bottom panel of Figure 17): individuals who were in P99.95 as of 1999 saw their earnings fall by an average of 50 log points between 2000 and 2005! Similarly large losses were experienced by the same quantile as of 1988 (from 1989 to 1994) and 2003 (from 2004 to 2009). By comparison, the 5-year loss for individuals in P99.05 ranges from 10 to 20 log points in the same three recessions. Thus, cyclicality increases strongly with the level of earnings. This conclusion is consistent with the findings in Parker and Vissing-Jørgensen (2010), who used repeated cross sections to study the same question. That paper also found that the differential cyclicality of earnings at the top has increased after the mid-1980s, as we find in this paper.33

7 Conclusions

This paper has studied between- and within-group variation in earnings changes over the business cycle. Using a very large panel dataset with little measurement error, it has documented three sets of empirical facts.

Our first set of findings concerns the cyclical nature of idiosyncratic shocks. During recessions, the upper end of the shock distribution collapses--that is, large upward wage movements become much less likely--whereas the bottom end expands--i.e., large drops in earnings become much more frequent. Moreover, the center of the shock distribution (i.e., the median) is very stable and moves very little compared with either tail.34 What does change (more significantly) is the behavior of the tails, which swing back and forth in the same direction over the business cycle. These swings in the tails, therefore, lead to cyclical changes in the skewness, but not so much in overall dispersion. We conclude that recessions are best viewed as a small negative shock to the median and a large negative shock to the skewness of the idiosyncratic earnings shock distribution, with little change in the variance.

Second, we examined the systematic component of business cycle risk. Pre-episode average earnings turns out to be an excellent predictor of a worker's earnings growth during business cycle episodes. We find that during recessions earnings growth is a monotonically increasing function of past earnings. In other words, workers who entered recessions with lower average past earnings experienced larger losses on average compared to workers with higher average past earnings. Clearly, this factor structure leads to a significant widening of earnings inequality over much of the distribution. As for the expansions, earnings growth is a U-shaped function of past earnings. Put together, these factor structures explain how earnings inequality is countercyclical without within-group (idiosyncratic) shocks having countercyclical variances. (Of course, the countercyclical left-skewness also contributes to countercyclical earnings inequality.)

Third, the one deviation we find from these simple patterns is a remarkable non-linearity for individuals who enter a recession with extremely high earnings--those in the top 1 percent of the earnings distribution. During the last two recessions, these individuals have experienced enormous and persistent earnings losses (about 30 log points), which dwarfs the losses of individuals even with slightly lower earnings. In fact, individuals who entered the last three recessions in the top 99.9th percentile of the earnings distribution had earnings levels five years later that were at least 50 log points lower than their pre-recession levels.

Overall, these empirical findings have important implications for how we think about earnings risk over the business cycle. The traditional approach to modeling recession risk consists of a (negative) aggregate shock and a positive shock to the variance of idiosyncratic shocks. Our results suggest that this simple view is seriously inadequate. Instead, they turn our focus to the countercyclical variation in the third moment (skewness) of idiosyncratic shocks as central to understanding how the fortunes of ex ante similar individuals fare during recessions. Even the change in mean earnings (which we think of as an aggregate shock) is seriously affected and driven by the change in skewness. In addition, the factor structure results imply that business cycle risk is not entirely a surprise or a shock, but it has a component that can be predicted based on information available to both individuals and economists at the beginning of business cycle episodes.

1.0


Bibliography

"On the Covariance Structure of Earnings and Hours Changes," Econometrica, March 1989, 57 (2), 411-45.
Abraham, Katharine G. and Lawrence F. Katz
"Cyclical Unemployment: Sectoral Shifts or Aggregate Disturbances?," Journal of Political Economy, 1986, 94 (3), 507-22.
Autor, David H., Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney
"The Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market," American Economic Review, May 2006, 96 (2), 189-194.
Autor, David, Lawrence Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney
"Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists," Review of Economics and Statistics, 2008, 90 (2), 300-23.
Balleer, Almut and Thijs van Rens
"Skill-Biased Technological Change and the Business Cycle," CEPR Discussion Papers No 8410 2011.
Bloom, Nicholas, Max Floetotto, Nir Jaimovich, Itay Saporta-Eksten, and Stephen J. Terry
"Really Uncertain Business Cycles," Working Paper, Stanford University 2011.
Bonhomme, Stephane and Laura Hospido
"Earnings Inequality in Spain," Working Paper, CEMFI 2012.
Bönke, Timm, Matthias Giesecke, and Holger Lüthen
"Dynamics of Earnings in Germany: Evidence from Social Security Records," Working Paper, Freie Universtat Berlin 2011.
Castro, Rui and Daniele Coen-Pirani
"Why Have Aggregate Skilled Hours Become So Cyclical Since the Mid-1980s?," International Economic Review, 2008, 49 (1), 135-184.
Congressional Budget Office
"Recent Trends in the Variability of Individual Earnings and Family Income," Washington, DC 2008.
Constantinides, George M. and Darrell Duffie
"Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Consumers," The Journal of Political Economy, 1996, 104 (2), 219-240.
Dynan, Karen, Douglas W. Elmendorf, and Daniel E. Sichel
"The Evolution of Household Income Volatility," Technical Report, Federal Reserve Board 2007.
Dynarski, Susan and Jonathan Gruber
"Can Families Smooth Variable Earnings?," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1997, 1, 229-284.
Gottschalk, Peter and Minh Huynh
"Are Earnings Inequality and Mobility Overstated? The Impact of Non-Classical Measurement Error," Review of Economics and Statistics, 2010, 92 (2), 302-315.
Guvenen, Fatih, Fatih Karahan, Serdar Ozkan, and Jae Song
"A User's Guide to Idiosyncratic Income Risk," Working Paper, University of Minnesota 2012.
Haider, Steven J. and Gary Solon
""Life-Cycle Variation in the Association between Current and Lifetime Earnings.," American Economic Review, 2006, 96 (4), 1308-1320.
Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M Murphy, and Brooks Pierce
"Wage Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill," Journal of Political Economy, June 1993, 101 (3), 410-42.
Kopczuk, Wojciech, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song
"Earnings Inequality and Mobility in the United States: Evidence from Social Security Data Since 1937," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2010, 125 (1).
Lemieux, T.
"Increasing residual wage inequality: Composition effects, noisy data, or rising demand for skill?," American Economic Review, 2006, 96 (3), 461-498.
Lilien, David M.
"Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment," Journal of Political Economy, 1982, 90 (4), 777-793.
Mankiw, N. Gregory
"The equity premium and the concentration of aggregate shocks," Journal of Financial Economics, September 1986, 17 (1), 211-219.
Meghir, Costas and Luigi Pistaferri
"Income Variance Dynamics and Heterogeneity," Econometrica, 2004, 72 (1), 1-32.
Moffitt, Robert A. and Peter Gottschalk
"Trends in the Variances of Permanent and Transitory Earnings in the U.S. and Their Relation to Earnings Mobility," Boston College Working Papers in Economics 444, Boston College July 1995.
and
"Trends in the Transitory Variance of Earnings in the United States," The Economic Journal, 2002, 112, C68-C73.
Olsen, Anya and Russell Hudson
"Social Security Administration's Master Earnings File: Background Information," Social Security Bulletin, 2009, 69 (3), 29-46.
Panis, Constantinjn, Ronald Euller, Cynthia Grant, Melissa Bradley, Christine E. Peterson, Randall Hirscher, and Paul Stinberg
SSA Program Data User's Manual, Baltimore, MD: Social Security Administration, 2000.
Parker, Jonathan A. and Annette Vissing-Jørgensen
"The Increase in Income Cyclicality of High-Income Households and Its Relation to the Rise in Top Income Shares," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2010, 41 (2), 1-70.
Piketty, Thomas and Emmanuel Saez
"Income Inequality in the United States: 1913-1998," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2003, 118 (1), 1-39.
Sabelhaus, John and Jae Song
"The Great Moderation in Micro Labor Earnings," Journal of Monetary Economics, 2010, 57, 391-403.
Saez, Emmanuel
"Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States," Working Paper, University of California at Berkeley March 2012.
Schulhofer-Wohl, Sam
"Heterogeneity and Tests of Risk Sharing," Technical Report, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 2011.
Solon, Gary and Donggyun Shin
"Trends in Men's Earnings Volatility: What Does the Panel Study of Income Dynamics Show?," Journal of Public Economics, 2011, 95, 973-982.
Storesletten, Kjetil, Chris I. Telmer, and Amir Yaron
"Cyclical Dynamics in Idiosyncratic Labor Market Risk," Journal of Political Economy, June 2004, 112 (3), 695-717.

1.25

APPENDIX:
NOT FOR PUBLICATION

A. Data Appendix


Table A.1: Summary Statistics of the Base Sample
Year Median earnings (in constant 2005 dollars) Mean earnings (in constant 2005 dollars) Change in log average earnings per person x100 Change in log earnings, averaged over workers x100 Average age Number of observations
1978 39,488 47,938 -- -- 39.4 3,640,877
1979 38,971 46,207 -0.94 1.10 39.3 3,797,417
1980 37,571 44,636 -1.69 -3.11 39.2 3,901,959
1981 37,908 44,785 0.08 2.00 39.2 4,011,200
1982 36,644 44,160 -2.13 -3.26 39.1 3,977,428
1983 36,431 44,276 -0.35 0.58 39.1 4,020,508
1984 36,847 45,760 1.21 6.53 38.9 4,090,461
1985 37,009 46,772 1.55 4.40 38.9 4,243,207
1986 37,100 48,062 1.06 3.68 38.9 4,311,235
1987 36,788 47,661 -0.09 1.78 38.9 4,423,615
1988 36,329 48,480 1.14 3.85 38.9 4,552,623
1989 35,614 46,572 -1.50 0.62 39.0 4,670,531
1990 35,207 46,262 -0.66 1.06 39.2 4,723,153
1991 34,451 45,766 -0.78 -1.30 39.3 4,768,475
1992 34,688 47,193 0.78 2.98 39.5 4,772,714
1993 34,660 47,471 0.11 3.33 39.7 4,829,933
1994 34,230 44,816 -2.44 2.00 39.8 4,904,776
1995 34,281 45,645 1.08 3.85 40.0 5,000,660
1996 34,863 46,730 0.94 3.88 40.2 5,045,831
1997 35,874 48,898 2.19 6.38 40.5 5,134,125
1998 37,351 51,348 2.20 7.06 40.7 5,198,954
1999 37,900 52,846 1.58 4.43 40.9 5,284,142
2000 38,525 55,030 2.06 4.35 41.1 5,366,942
2001 39,011 55,283 -0.09 1.93 41.3 5,376,439
2002 38,412 52,894 -2.61 -2.36 41.4 5,316,402
2003 38,187 53,145 0.01 0.55 41.6 5,303,052
2004 38,372 53,366 0.16 2.16 41.7 5,329,934
2005 38,196 53,586 0.23 2.12 41.8 5,359,877
2006 38,456 54,536 0.93 3.30 41.9 5,390,061
2007 38,526 55,322 0.67 2.44 41.9 5,405,122
2008 37,930 53,889 -1.67 -1.03 42.0 5,400,167
2009 36,984 51,946 -3.86 -6.64 42.1 5,238,303
2010 36,934 52,567 -0.04 1.25 42.1 5,161,313

\begin{spacing}{0.80000000000000004} \emph{\footnotesize Note:}{\footnotesize {} All statistics are computed for the base sample with the exception of column 3, which is computed as the change in log average earnings per non-self-employed (male) person. }\end{spacing}


Table A.2: Further Statistics of the 10 Percent Sample Annual Wage and Salary Earnings
Year Mean (log) Std. Dev. (log) Skewness (log) Max. Earnings \dagger
1978 10.431 0.861 -0.762 5,629,944
1979 10.420 0.834 -0.798 3,043,686
1980 10.378 0.843 -0.785 3,900,245
1981 10.386 0.850 -0.832 3,191,016
1982 10.353 0.869 -0.756 3,164,862
1983 10.337 0.891 -0.747 3,350,164
1984 10.354 0.899 -0.709 5,649,401
1985 10.363 0.907 -0.677 5,997,900
1986 10.368 0.929 -0.630 5,518,408
1987 10.355 0.922 -0.644 8,836,576
1988 10.352 0.937 -0.599 10,323,465
1989 10.328 0.929 -0.647 7,963,985
1990 10.316 0.939 -0.659 8,436,263
1991 10.303 0.941 -0.585 7,671,863
1992 10.322 0.943 -0.513 11,382,868
1993 10.328 0.951 -0.507 9,824,403
1994 10.317 0.934 -0.566 7,380,117
1995 10.326 0.939 -0.536 7,761,374
1996 10.344 0.941 -0.532 10,145,898
1997 10.384 0.934 -0.465 11,928,487
1998 10.433 0.925 -0.434 14,686,511
1999 10.450 0.929 -0.420 18,190,317
2000 10.468 0.936 -0.400 32,008,754
2001 10.479 0.951 -0.429 17,144,706
2002 10.449 0.956 -0.504 13,885,282
2003 10.443 0.968 -0.499 14,023,289
2004 10.443 0.965 -0.502 15,811,530
2005 10.442 0.967 -0.492 16,138,366
2006 10.452 0.972 -0.484 18,897,685
2007 10.455 0.982 -0.476 20,177,930
2008 10.443 0.973 -0.452 16,907,029
2009 10.407 0.979 -0.460 12,541,077
2010 10.414 0.974 -0.384 13,983,100

\begin{spacing} % latex2html id marker 1596 {0.80000000000000004} \emph{\footnotesize Note:}{\footnotesize {} The sample is truncated at the 99.999th percentile. This condition eliminates about 40 to 60 individuals per year (corresponding to 400 to 600 males in the U.S. economy). $\dagger$The maximum earnings reported in the last column corresponds to the truncation point.}\end{spacing}

Figure A.1: Selected Percentiles of Labor Earnings Distribution over Time
\includegraphics[height=0.36\textheight]{AFIG_Males_PERCENTILES_WAGE_FINAL}

Tables A.1 and A.2 report some key summary statistics for the base sample used in the paper. Figure A.1 plots selected percentiles of the earnings distribution over the sample period. Panis et al. (2000) and Olsen and Hudson (2009) contain more detailed descriptions of the MEF dataset.

A..1 Comparison to CPS Data

Figure A.2 plots the log differential between the 90th and 50th percentiles of the labor earnings distribution, as well as the log differential between the 50th and 10th percentiles (hereafter abbreviated as L90-50 and L50-10, respectively). A couple of remarks are in order. First, it is useful to compare this figure to the Current Population Survey (CPS) data, which has been used extensively in the previous literature to document wage inequality trends. An important point to keep in mind is that studies that used the CPS have typically focused on hourly wage inequality, whereas our dataset only contains information on annual (wage and labor) earnings. With this difference in mind, note that Autor et al. (2008, Figure 3) report a level of L90-50 of 55 log points in 1978, which rises by about 30 log points until 2005. In this paper, the level of L90-50 is 72 log points (most likely higher because of the dispersion in labor supply) and rises by about 28 log points until 2005, a result very similar to Autor et al. (2008)'s numbers. In both datasets, the rise in L90-50 is secular and is remarkably stable over three decades.35 Thus, even though the difference between hourly wage and annual earnings matters for the levels, it has little effect on the secular trend during this period.

Figure A.2: Top and Bottom Ends of Labor Earnings Distribution
\includegraphics[height=0.4\textheight]{AFIG_Males_P9050_P5010_LaborIncome_10pct}

Second, turning to the bottom end, the CPS data show slightly different patterns, depending on whether one uses CPS March weekly wages or May/ORG hourly data. But the general pattern is a rapidly widening L50-10 gap from 1978 to 1987, which then stays flat or declines, depending on the dataset. In our case, the rise in L50-10 happens between 1979 and 1983, and then it stays relatively flat until 2000, after which time it starts rising again. It seems safe to conjecture that labor supply heterogeneity could be more important at the bottom end and could account for some of the gap between the two datasets. Another source of the difference could be the under-reporting of earnings in our administrative dataset or over-reporting in the CPS. Some papers on measurement error adopt this latter interpretation (e.g., Gottschalk and Huynh (2010)). Notice also that the level of L50-10 is much higher in our sample--about 125 log points in 1978 compared with 65 log points in the CPS, which again can be explained by a combination of labor supply heterogeneity and under- or over-reporting.36 Overall, the two datasets reveal the same pattern at the top end, while having similar but slightly different behavior at the bottom.


A..2 Evolution of Inequality: Cross-Sectional Data

In this section we document some facts about the evolution of cross-sectional inequality. In particular, inequality is clearly countercyclical, and this is due to an expansion of inequality at both the top end and bottom end. This analysis does not require the panel dimension; it is presented here for completeness and comparison to the existing work.

It is useful to distinguish between the changes in top and bottom end inequality. To this end, we plot the 1-year change in L90-50 and L50-10 in Figure [*]. To reduce short-term mean reversion in inequality, the solid lines plot the 2-year difference in each inequality measure (divided by two), which is smoother. This differencing eliminates the secular trend and allows us to focus on the cyclical change in inequality.

First, notice the cyclical movement in the bottom-end inequality, rising in every one of the four recessions and falling (into the negative territory) subsequently. The increases in the 1980-83 and 2001-02 recessions are especially pronounced, as is the fall during the 1990s. The change in the top-end inequality is also cyclical, rising during the 1980-83 and 1991-92 recessions. Compared with the bottom-end inequality, though, L90-50 rises virtually throughout the period. Overall, the combination of these two pieces shows that overall inequality (L90-10) itself is countercyclical.

Figure A.3: Change in Top and Bottom Ends Earnings Inequality
\includegraphics[height=0.36\textheight]{AFIG_Males_CHANGE_IN_P9050_P5010_WAGE_FINAL}


B. Between-Group Variation: Alternative Measures

B..1 The Great Recession, All Age Groups

Figure A.4: Growth in Log Average Earnings during the Great Recession (2007-10)
\includegraphics[height=0.36\textheight]{FIG_dJMP_WAGES_REPAGENT_2007RECESSIONS_AGE_GROUPS_DETAIL}

B..2 Between-Group Variation Over the Cycle, Young Males

Figure A.5: Growth in Log Average Income during Recessions, Young (25-34) Males


\includegraphics[height=0.36\textheight]{FIG_dJMP_WAGES_REPAGENT_4RECESSIONS_YOUNG_MALES}
Figure A.6: Growth in Log Average Income during Expansions, Young Males
\includegraphics[height=0.36\textheight]{FIG_dJMP_WAGES_REPAGENT_3EXPANSIONS_YOUNG_MALES}

B..3 An Alternative Measure of Factor Structure:  f_{1}

Figure A.7: Average Growth in Log Earnings during Recessions ( f_{1}), Prime-age Males


\includegraphics[height=0.36\textheight]{FIG_dJMP_WAGES_NOZEROS_4RECESSIONS_PRIME_AGED_MALES}

We now construct the alternative measure of average earnings growth,  f_{1}, described in the main text (Section 6). Recall that  f_{1} differs from  f_{2} in two important ways. First,  f_{1} excludes individuals with zero earnings in either year  t or year  t+k. Because the probability of full-year non-employment rises in recessions most strongly for low-income individuals, dropping them will tend to increase  f_{1} below the median relative to  f_{2}. Second, because  f_{1} is based on the average of log earnings, whereas  f_{2} is based on the log of average earnings, the latter will tend to be higher within quantiles that have a wider dispersion of earnings growth rates (due to Jensen's inequality). So, we would expect this force to raise  f_{2} relative to  f_{1} below the median level of  \overline {Y}_{t-1} where the variance of shocks is higher, as well as at the very top end for the same reason.

Figure A.7 plots  f_{1} for each of the four recessions. A quick comparison to Figure 13 shows that the two measures reveal the same qualitative patterns. The clear upward-sloping factor structure is there for all recessions. Quantitatively, the slope is somewhat smaller--a difference of 10 log points between the 90th and 10th percentiles during the Great Recession versus 17 log points under  f_{2}. Inspecting the two graphs shows that the difference mainly comes from the steeper drop in  f_{2} between the 20th and 1st percentiles, probably due to the increased chance of unemployment in this range mentioned above. Between the 20th and 90th percentiles, the two graphs look very similar. The other recessions show slopes that are also slightly lower than before. Another difference to note is that under  f_{1}, the 1980-83 recession looks less favorable to individuals in the top 10 percent--their earnings growth pattern resembles the recent recessions more closely. This suggests that the strong performance of this group revealed by  f_{2} was affected by some large gains at the right tail, which dominated the mean earnings measure for these groups in 1983.

Overall, the two measures are quite comparable. In the main text, we focus on  f_{2} so as to capture the total earnings risk, which includes the risk of long-term unemployment rising during recessions.

B..4 Jointly Controlling for  \overline {Y}_{t-1} and  \Delta Y_{t-1}

Figure A.8: Comparing  f_{2}(\overline {Y}_{t-1}) (From Figure 13) to  f_{2}\left (\overline {Y}_{t-1}\vert\Delta Y_{t-1}\right )
\includegraphics[height=0.35\textheight]{FIG_dJMP_WAGES_REPAGENT_4RECESSIONS_PRIME_AGED_MALES_CONTROLLING_FOR_DELTA}

B..5 Cyclicality of Top 1 Percent Using  f_{1}

Figure A.9 plots the counterpart of Figure 17 using a different measure of earnings growth ( f_{1}). The same pattern discussed in Section 6.4 is visible here with an even larger 5-year loss for all individuals in the top 1 percent.

Figure A.9: 5-Year Earnings Growth, Top 1 Percent of Individuals
1][t]1
Average 1-Year Change in Log Earnings ( f_{1})
\includegraphics[height=0.4\textheight]{FIG_1YR_MEAN_CHANGE_IN_LOG_INCOME_P99X_NEW}
1][t]1
Average 5-Year Change in Log Earnings ( f_{1})
\includegraphics[height=0.4\textheight]{FIG_5YR_MEAN_CHANGE_IN_LOG_INCOME_P99X_NEW}


C. A Fully Parametric Approach

In this section, we use an alternative approach to quantify the cyclicality of idiosyncratic shocks. We begin by running the following regression:

\displaystyle \tilde{y}_{t,h}^{i}=\beta^{i}\times(\overline{y}_{t}^{A}-\overline{y}^{A})+\left[a^{i}+b^{i}h+c^{i}h^{2}\right]+\xi_{t,h}^{i}, (8)

where  \beta^{i} is the key individual-specific parameter that measures how sensitive an individual's earnings is to business cycle fluctuations. The latter is captured by the movements in log average labor earnings,  \overline{y}_{t}^{A}, which is normalized by its time series average  \overline{y}^{A} so as to have zero mean over time.37 Here,  f_{1}(\mathbf{V}_{t-1}^{i})\equiv\beta^{i} and  \lambda_{t}\equiv\overline{y}_{t}^{A} and the life cycle component allows for an individual-specific quadratic polynomial. Finally,  \xi_{t}^{i} is the residual that corresponds to our notion of idiosyncratic shocks. In the second stage, we fit an AR(1) to each individual's  \{\xi_{t,h}^{i}\} sequence,
\displaystyle z_{t,h}^{i}=\rho^{i}z_{t-1,h-1}^{i}+\eta_{t,h}^{i},
to obtain individual-specific innovations or "idiosyncratic shocks," denoted by  \eta_{t,h}^{i}. The goal of this section is to understand the business cycle behavior of the distribution of these shocks.
Figure A.10: AR(1) Innovations to Individual Earnings: Skewness vs Standard Deviation
\includegraphics[height=0.4\textheight]{FIG_TIMESERIES_SKEWNESS}

The advantage of the specification in (8) is that by making the factor  \lambda_{t} observable and the loading term fixed over time, it allows us to estimate this regression separately for each individual using a time series of his earnings. To ensure a sufficiently large number of observations for each individual regression, we focus on a subsample of cohorts that are between the ages of 25 to 28 in 1978. These individuals have exactly 33 yearly observations between the ages of 25 and 60 during our sample period (which may involve years with zero annual earnings). In addition, to ensure at least a moderately strong labor market attachment, we require an individual to have earnings above the minimum threshold during at least 2/3 of the sample period--22 years. From this pool, we select a random subsample of 100,000 individuals to conduct the analysis in this section (hence there are as many regressions).

So, how is equation (8) estimated? We include observations with zero earnings into this regression by setting them equal to  Y_{\text{min},t}. Consequently, the distribution of  y_{t}^{i} is very non-symmetric due to occasionally large drops to  \log(Y_{\text{min},t}). We conducted a Monte Carlo study, which suggested that a quantile regression for the median was more robust and yielded much less bias for the estimated parameters.38 Therefore, we estimated equation (8) via a quantile regression for the median.

Figure A.10 plots the (cross-sectional) standard deviation and skewness of the estimated innovations over time. A potentially important confounding factor in this analysis is the following. Because the sample is balanced and contains four cohorts with very similar ages, the figures over time can be alternatively interpreted as evolutions over the life cycle. With this in mind, it seems more appropriate to focus on high frequency changes in these moments and de-emphasize the longer-term patterns (such as the U-shape in the standard deviation).

With this caveat noted, we turn to Figure A.10, which plots the skewness of the  \eta_{t}^{i} distribution. There are three large dips--in 1990, 2002, and 2009--coinciding with the last three recessions. This is very similar to what we found before (cf. Figure 6).39 There is no dip for the 1980-83 recession, although skewness continuously falls during that period. As noted earlier, however, because the sample is younger during that recession, life cycle factors could be dominating the business cycle variation in those years.

One drawback of this analysis is that we can track only a handful of cohorts with very similar ages over time (since we need to run the regression in (3) with a sufficiently long time series). Thus, age effects are confounded with time effects, which makes us less comfortable about drawing strong conclusions. Partly due to this concern and for sake of brevity, we did not include these results in the paper.



Footnotes

* For useful comments and discussions, we thank Sumit Agarwal, Paul Beaudry, Martin Browning, Nick Bloom, George Constantinides, Steve Davis, Per Krusell, Jonathan Parker, Jonathan Heathcote, Luigi Pistaferri, Martin Schneider, Joshua Gallin, as well as seminar and conference participants at various institutions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Social Security Administration or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Return to Text
* University of Minnesota and NBER; [email protected] Return to Text
* Federal Reserve Board; [email protected] Return to Text
* Social Security Administration; [email protected] Return to Text
1. The source for all reported statistics is authors' calculations from the Social Security Administration data described below. Return to Text
2. Kopczuk et al. (2010) also employ SSA datasets with uncapped earnings (after 1978), whereas Haider and Solon (2006), Schulhofer-Wohl (2011), Bonhomme and Hospido (2012, Spain), and Bönke et al. (2011, Germany) used datasets with earnings capped at the Social Security contribution limit. Return to Text
3. To give some idea about the size of the sample, the bulk of our analysis is conducted with a sample that has about 4.5 million individuals in each year for a total of 165 million individual-year observations during this period. Return to Text
4. We are estimating such an econometric process for earnings in Guvenen et al. (2012), but do not examine business cycle risk in that paper. Alternatively, if we were to fit a simple parametric process to the data, it would miss these key features and could bias our results in unpredictable directions. Return to Text
5. They observed that if shocks are persistent and countercyclical, then, at a given age, cohorts that have lived through more recessions should have a larger cross-sectional dispersion of earnings than those who have not. Return to Text
6. Our focus on males is motivated by the fact that this group had a relatively stable employment rate and labor supply during this period. In contrast, female labor participation increased substantially during this period. Because our dataset contains only labor earnings but no hours information, including women in the analysis would have introduced an important confounding factor, which we wished to avoid. Return to Text
7. Although the MEF also contains earnings information for self-employed individuals, these data are top-coded at the taxable limit until 1994. Because of this, we do not use these data in this paper. In an earlier version, we conducted all the analysis using total labor earnings (and included self-employed individuals) and found no difference in our substantive conclusions. Return to Text
8. Our earnings measure does not include deferred compensation, such as through 401(k), 403(b), and 457(b) plans, because information on these plans is not available consistently throughout the period. Return to Text
9. Appendix A contains a more detailed comparison of inequality trends revealed by the base sample to those found in the Current Population Survey (CPS) data. Return to Text
10. In fact, two of the recessions we study start in the first quarter (1980 and 2001) and one starts in the fourth quarter (2007), so the classification of these is clear. Only one recession starts in the third quarter of 1990, and we shift the starting date to 1991 as per the rule described. Return to Text
11. In the text, we alternatively refer to earnings growth as "earnings change," and with a mild abuse of language, as "earnings shocks" to prevent monotonicity. Return to Text
12. Although some recent studies have also examined the properties of earnings growth from panel data, these papers focused on secular trends rather than cyclical behavior (Dynan et al. (2007), Congressional Budget Office (2008), Sabelhaus and Song (2010), and Solon and Shin (2011)). Return to Text
13. Moreover, Solon and Shin (2011) investigate the robustness of the finding from the PSID that the annual earnings growth volatility trends up over time. They show that whether self-employment is included in the measure of labor earnings makes a big difference: focusing on wages and salaries reveals no rise in variance, whereas including farm and business income implies a rise of 15 log points in the variance. Return to Text
14. One observable characteristic that has often been used in the literature on wage inequality is educational attainment. The MEF does not contain any information on education, so we cannot use it in our analysis. Having said that, papers that investigated the cyclicality of the skill premium (i.e., between-education-group differences) found only a modest correlation with the business cycle. For example, both Castro and Coen-Pirani (2008, Table 2) and Balleer and van Rens (2011, Table 1) report a correlation of skill premium with GDP and productivity close to zero (ranging from -0.15 to 0.20). Therefore, this omission is probably not an important shortcoming of our analysis. Return to Text
15. We have also experimented with an alternative measure of average earnings that weighs each observation inversely with its distance from year  t-1, to further group together individuals whose earnings were similar at more recent dates. To this end, for a given  t, define the weight  w_{t,s}^{i}=(6-s)1\{\widetilde{Y}_{t-s}^{i}\geq Y_{\text{min},t}\}, which is zero for ineligible observations and declines with  s otherwise. Using these weights to construct the average earnings made almost no change to the results reported here. Return to Text
16. Information on detailed Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes is available, so, in principle, we could further classify individuals based on their 3- or 4-digit industry. Our preliminary results indicated that little was gained by this step, so we did not pursue this approach. Return to Text
17. For 5-year changes, recession years can be defined in a number of ways, since many 5-year periods cover a given recession. We have experimented with different choices and found them to make little difference to the substantive conclusions drawn here. The reported results are for a simple definition that includes one 5-year change for each recession that starts one year before the recession begins. Specifically, the recession graph averages over four 5-year periods starting in  t=1979, 1989, 1999, and 2005 (since this is the latest possible 5-year change covering the Great Recession). Expansions average over all 5-year changes that do not coincide with a recession year--that is, periods starting in  t=1983, 1984, 1993, 1994, and 2002. Return to Text
18. For one-year changes, recession years are those with  t= 1980, 1981, 1982, 1990, 1991, 2000, 2001, 2007, 2008, and 2009. The remaining years are considered as expansion years. Return to Text
19. This finding clearly contradicts one of the standard assumptions in the income dynamics literature--that the variance of earnings shocks does not depend on the current or past level of earnings. We explore these implications in a separate ongoing project. Return to Text
20. An interesting question is whether there are cyclical changes in moments beyond the third (skewness), for example, in the fourth moment--the kurtosis. Although the answer is yes--the kurtosis is lower in recessions compared with expansions--the differences are quite modest. We omit those results for brevity. They are available upon request from the authors. Return to Text
21. Notice also that in this scenario, the variance of shocks would go down in recessions, and thus the variance would be procyclical. Return to Text
22. In addition, the case described here relies on some unlikely assumptions. For example, the probability of unemployment is a strongly decreasing function of past income, so the change in incidence among individuals with  \overline{Y}_{t-1}\in P90 will be much smaller than the 1.5 percent average figure. Yet, the shift to negative skewness among that group is as large as among workers who have  \overline{Y}_{t-1}\in P50 as well as  \overline{Y}_{t-1}\in P30 (see Figure 10). Return to Text
23. Of course, unemployment will and does affect the level of variance. Return to Text
24. To be more precise,  f_{1} should have a time subscript, since we will allow it to vary over time. However, to keep the notation clean, we will suppress the subscript in this paper. Return to Text
25. To see this, let us assume that  z_{t+1}=\rho z_{t}+\eta_{t+1} and notice that  \mathbb{\partial E}(z_{t+k}^{i}-z_{t}^{i}\vert\overline{Y}_{t-1}^{i})=\partial\mathbb{E}(\eta_{t+k}+\rho\eta_{t+k-1}+...+\rho\eta_{t+1}^{k-1}\vert\overline{Y}_{t-1}^{i})+\partial\mathbb{E}\left((\rho^{k}-1)z_{t}\vert\overline{Y}_{t-1}^{i}\right). The first expectation will be zero as before. However, the partial derivative of the second term will be negative, given that  z_{t} is increasing in  \overline {Y}_{t-1}^{i}. Return to Text
26. It is also more directly comparable to recent work that used cross-sectional data to quantify the cyclicality of earnings by constructing average earnings for synthetic groups, such as the top 1 percent, 10 percent, and so on (e.g., Parker and Vissing-Jørgensen (2010) and Saez (2012)). Return to Text
27. Recall that the earnings measure used in these computations,  y_{t}, is net of earnings growth due to life cycle effects as explained in Section 4. This adjustment shifts the intercept of the  f_{2} function downward, which should be considered when interpreting the reported earnings growth figures. Return to Text
28. We conjecture that this has more to do with the fact that for the 1979-83 recession, we were limited to using only earnings in 1978 to form groups (rather than taking 5-year averages as we did for other periods), which led to a higher degree of mean reversion than would otherwise have been the case. Return to Text
29. These two recessions last half as long as the other two longer recessions, so the slope of these graphs should be interpreted in this context. However, normalizing total earnings growth (the vertical axis in these graphs) by the duration of each recession is not necessarily a satisfactory solution, because even during longer recessions, the largest earnings falls have been concentrated within one- or two-year periods (2008-09, for example). Return to Text
30. Because the two variables can be correlated, there is no presumption that every cell will contain the same number of observations (unlike the previous experiment with a single characteristic). Therefore, we drop cells that have less than 30 percent of the maximum number of observations. Return to Text
31. Incidentally, controlling for past earnings growth has virtually no effect on the relationship between the quantiles of average earnings and future earnings growth documented above. Thus, further conditioning does not alter the relationship documented so far. These figures are available upon request. Return to Text
32. The corresponding figures for the whole sample period are 4.76 percent and 3.07 percent, respectively. Return to Text
33. Recall that  f_{2} averages each group's earnings before taking the logs, which could be affected by few very large earnings levels. Alternatively, we can construct  f_{1} which is the mean of log earnings changes, which is less sensitive to this problem. We include the resulting graph in Appendix B, which shows the same qualitative patterns documented here, and reveals even larger losses for the top income groups--a loss of about 60 log points for individuals in P99.95 in each of the last three recessions. Return to Text
34. This last fact is related to an important feature of our data that we decided not to focus on in this paper: basically, earnings changes are extremely leptokurtic. That is, most earnings changes from year to year are very small, but once in a while there is a substantial change in earnings. Consequently, in a given year, most observed earnings changes are small and change little from recessions to expansions, which gives the distribution its very stable center. Return to Text
35. Fitting a quadratic polynomial to the L90-50 reveals a very small negative curvature, indicating an ever so slight slowdown in the rate of increase of inequality at the top. Return to Text
36. In our sample, the average wage earnings at the 10th percentile is $8,520 per year. If an individual works 52 weeks a year at a wage of $5.85 per hour (legal minimum wage in 2007), he has to work 28 hours per week, which does not appear to be an unreasonable figure. Return to Text
37. To compute  \overline{y}_{t}^{A} for a given year, we include all males between the ages of 25 and 60, including those with zero earnings. The first difference of this series was reported in column 4 of Table A.1. Return to Text
38. Results are available from the authors upon request. Return to Text
39. In fact, the last three dips in that figure for the transitory shocks also take place exactly in 1990, 2002, and 2009. Return to Text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to Text