The Federal Reserve Board eagle logo links to home page

The Decline of Drudgery and The Paradox of Hard Work1

Brendan Epstein2 and Miles S. Kimball3

NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/.


Abstract:

We develop a theory that focuses on the general equilibrium and long-run macroeconomic consequences of trends in job utility. Given secular increases in job utility, work hours per capita can remain approximately constant over time even if the income effect of higher wages on labor supply exceeds the substitution effect. In addition, secular improvements in job utility can be substantial relative to welfare gains from ordinary technological progress. These two implications are connected by an equation flowing from optimal hours choices: improvements in job utility that have a significant effect on labor supply tend to have large welfare effects.

Keywords: Labor supply, work hours, drudgery, income effect, substitution effect, job utility

JEL classification: E24, J22, O40


 


1  Introduction

In his 1930 essay, "Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren," Keynes predicted that a large increase in leisure would take place over the following century, but robust signs of such a leisure boom have failed to materialize. As shown in Figure (1), for a large set of OECD countries, from 1956 through 2009 aggregate (real) consumption per working-age population (ages 15-64) rose by 100% and more, while work hours per working-age population have been dramatically flat in comparison.4

It is not unreasonable to think, as Keynes did, that the extent to which consumption has increased, along with long-run growth in real wages, should have led to a prominent trend decline in work hours driven by the income effect overtaking the substitution effect. Indeed, there is good reason to think that income effects are substantial (see, for instance, Kimball and Shapiro 2008). Why are people still working so hard? And, what are the welfare effects of this paradox of hard work?

Figure 1: Work Hours Per Population (Left) and Private Consumption per Population (Right)

Figure 1: Left panel: difference between the natural logarithm of work
  hours per working age population (15-65) and its corresponding
  value in 1956. Right panel: difference between the natural
  logarithm of private consumption per working age population (15-65)
  and its corresponding value in 1956. Data are at yearly frequency.
  Consumption is taken from the Penn World Tables (pwt.sas). Hours
  per population are the product of hours worked per worker and the
  employment-to-population ratio. Hours worked per worker are from
  the Groningen Total Economy Database (which is maintained by the
  Conference Board, conference-board.org). Data on the working-age
  population (ages 15-64) and employment are from the OECD
  (stats.oecd.org). Countries: Australia, Canada, Euro (simple
  average of country-specific ratios over Austria, Belgium, Finland,
  France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland,
  and the United Kingdom), Japan and United States.  
  Left panel: difference between the natural logarithm of work
  hours per working age population (15-65) and its corresponding
  value in 1956. Right panel: difference between the natural
  logarithm of private consumption per working age population (15-65)
  and its corresponding value in 1956. Data are at yearly frequency.
  Consumption is taken from the Penn World Tables (pwt.sas). Hours
  per population are the product of hours worked per worker and the
  employment-to-population ratio. Hours worked per worker are from
  the Groningen Total Economy Database (which is maintained by the
  Conference Board, conference-board.org). Data on the working-age
  population (ages 15-64) and employment are from the OECD
  (stats.oecd.org). Countries: Australia, Canada, Euro (simple
  average of country-specific ratios over Austria, Belgium, Finland,
  France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland,
  and the United Kingdom), Japan and United States.

In principle there are four alternative, but not mutually exclusive, explanations through which the paradox of hard work can be rationalized (detailed just below). Of the set of explanations for the paradox of hard work, in this paper we focus on job utility. Economists have long understood that cross-sectional differences in job utility at a particular time give rise to compensating differentials. We develop a theory that focuses on a less-studied topic: understanding the long-run macroeconomic consequences of trends in job utility.

The four rationalizations of the paradox of hard work are as follows.

  1. Assuming that the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is large. However, empirical evidence suggests the contrary. Hall (1988) finds this elasticity to be approximately zero, Basu and Kimball (2002) find that plausible values are less than 0.7, and Kimball, Sahm, and Shapiro (2011) find a value of approximately 0.08.5
  2. An increasing ratio of effective marginal wages to consumption. This could be the result, for instance, of a reduction in the progressivity of the tax system, an intensification of competition for promotions within firms, and increasing educational debts.6
  3. Anything that keeps the marginal utility of consumption high. This could be, for example, because of habit formation, whether internal and external ("keeping up with the Joneses"), and from the introduction of new goods.7
  4. Anything that serves to keep the marginal disutility of work low. This can be, for instance, the result of technological progress in household production, non-separability between consumption and leisure (King, Plosser, and Rebelo (1988), Basu and Kimball (2002)), and jobs getting nicer.8

We propose an intertemporal framework for thinking about the causes and effects of secular increases in job utility, that is, of jobs getting nicer. Some of the questions that our framework provides answers to are the following.

In turn, the answers to these questions lead to two contributions to the macro and labor economics literatures. First, we show that secular improvements in job utility--the decline of drudgery--can induce work hours to remain approximately constant over time even if the income effect of higher wages on labor supply exceeds the substitution effect of higher wages. Therefore, the paradox of hard work is not necessarily evidence that the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is large, that preferences are strongly non-separable, or that preferences have some other feature such as habit formation. Second, we show that secular improvements in job utility can be very substantial in comparison to the welfare gains from ordinary (say, labor-augmenting) technological progress. These two implications are connected by an equation: improvements in job utility that have a significant effect on labor supply tend to have large welfare effects.

This paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 relates our work to the static theory of compensating differentials. Section 3 provides a general overview of our framework. Then, Section 4 discusses the variables we focus on and how our formulation maps into the real world. Sections 5 and 6 focus, respectively, on the optimization problems of individuals and firms. Section 7 deals with the economy's general equilibrium. Then, Section 8 addresses the welfare consequence of changes in job utility. Finally, section 9 concludes.


2  The Static Theory of Compensating Differentials

The natural point of reference for our analysis is the theory of compensating differentials, spelled out originally in the first ten chapters of Book I of "The Wealth of Nations" (Smith, 1776). A standard modern reference on compensating differentials is Rosen (1986).

2.1  Worker and Firm Choices

The solid line in the left panel of Figure 2 is a wage/job-utility frontier: jobs offering lower job utility will, in principle, compensate by offering higher real wages (in the figure $ W$ is the real wage and $ J$ is job utility). Thus, all else equal, individuals face a trade-off between these two variables. Conditional on individual preferences, a particular worker optimizes by choosing a feasible point on the (solid) frontier in the $ (W,J)$ plane.

The solid line in the right panel of Figure 2 is a job-utility/output frontier: in order to improve job utility firms must divert part of their resources away from the production of output ($ Y$). Given its idiosyncratic costs of job utility in terms of output, a particular firm optimizes by choosing a feasible point on the (solid) frontier in the $ \left( Y,J\right) $ plane.

Figure 2. Theory of Compensating Differentials. Left panel: real wage ($ W$) / job utility ($ J$) frontier faced by workers. Right panel: job utility / output ($ Y$) frontier faced by firms.

Figure 2: Figure 2 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix.  Left Panel -
The solid line in the left panel is the real wage (W) /job-utility (J) frontier.  It is in the first quadrant and is concave about the origin, stretching between the vertical axis (the real wage) and the horizontal axis (job utility).  There are two points on this line, a and b, with a closer to the job-utility axis and b the wage axis. Movement along the frontier from point a to b indicates a tradeoff of higher real wages for less job-utility, a higher real wage is obtained at point b but b also involves lower job-utility than point a.  Such a movement would tend to reduce work hours. A dashed line exists in the graph, representing an outward shift of the wage/job-utility frontier away from the origin. The point a prime on the dashed line represents the new optimal choice on this frontier with both higher wages and higher job utility than the original choice represented by point a.  An arrow pointing northeast from point a on the solid line to point a prime on the dashed line indicates the shift from one frontier to the next. Right Panel - The solid line in the right panel is the job-utility (J) /output (Y) frontier.  It is in the first quadrant and is concave about the origin.  Here the vertical axis represents a measure of job utility and the horizontal axis represents output.  There are two points on this line, c and d, with c closer to the job-utility (vertical) axis and b the production axis.  Movement along the frontier from point c to d indicates a tradeoff of higher production for less job-utility in that a higher level of production occurs at point d but d also involves lower job-utility than point c.  
A dashed line exists in the graph, representing an outward shift of the job-utility/output frontier away from the origin. The point d prime on the dashed line represents the new optimal choice on this frontier with both higher job utility and higher output than the original choice, represented by point d.  An arrow pointing northeast from point d on the solid line to point d prime on the dashed line indicates the shift from one frontier to the next.

2.2  Movements Along the Frontiers

Suppose higher output and higher real wages came from movements along the solid frontiers ($ a$ to $ b$ in the left panel and $ c$ to $ d$ in the right panel). As argued in Kimball and Shapiro (2008), income effects on labor supply are substantial. So, the higher real wage implied by moving from point $ a$ to point $ b$ would tend to reduce work hours. In addition, if work hours are increasing in job utility, then lower job utility implied by moving from point $ a$ to point $ b$ also puts downward pressure on work hours.

2.3  Movements of the Frontiers

However, the frontiers themselves can shift (the dashed lines in Figure 2). As the economy's choice set expands, optimal choices can entail moving to points such as $ a^{\prime}$ and $ d^{\prime}$, in which case job utility, output, and real wages all rise, and increases in job utility emerge as potentially offsetting to income effects.

The theory we develop in this paper focuses attention on understanding the dynamic general equilibrium implications and endogenous foundations of such intertemporal changes in the economy's choice set. This understanding is complementary to the long-standing static, partial equilibrium microeconomic framework of compensating differentials.


3  The Social Planner's Perspective

There are no distortions in our model so the planning version of the economy is equivalent to a decentralized economy with perfect competition. Both perspectives are valuable, and we begin with the social planning perspective.

Consider individuals who obtain utility from consumption and non-work time. A standard assumption is that any time devoted to work always subtracts from utility. Our alternative assumption is that process benefits and process costs of work--what we call "job utility" --matter as well.

The problem that an idealized social planner would face helps summarize our overall framework. The social planner's problem involves choosing consumption, capital, work hours devoted to particular jobs, effort demands by a particular job (per hour of work), and amenities provided by a particular job in order to maximize a household's lifetime utility given firms' production structures and other standard constraints.

3.1  Baseline Assumptions

We consider a small open economy in which agents can freely borrow and lend at the exogenously determined real interest rate $ r$ (equal to $ \rho$, the rate at which all economic agents discount the future). Capital is freely mobile across firms and boarders. We assume that all benefits and costs to firms and workers other than the utility from leisure and consumption are proportional to work hours. These assumptions jointly guarantee that there will never be any disagreement between workers and firms about job parameters other than the wage. Furthermore, given fully mobile capital and the exogenous world interest rate, we can focus on steady state analysis since the absence of state variables implies that changes between steady states occur instantaneously. The model is cast in continuous time (we omit time indexes in order to avoid notational clutter).

3.2  Individuals and Firms

The economy is inhabited by $ i=1$,...,$ I$ firms all of which are producers of the same final good and a continuum of individuals whose mass is normalized to one. Households each have only one individual, so we will use the terms household and worker interchangeably.

Utility depends on consumption, the division of time into work time and non-work time, and job utility per hour of work. Job utility depends on effort, amenities, and job-enjoyment technology (we elaborate on all of these further below).

Firms produce output using capital and effective labor input (the product of hours, effort and labor-augmenting technology), and can vary in their real wage and job utility offerings.

3.3  Planning Problem

Table 1 below lays out our notation. In that notation, the planning problem is:

$\displaystyle \underset{C\text{, }H_{i}\text{, }E_{i}\text{, }A_{i}\text{, }K_{i}}{\max }\text{ }\int e^{-\rho t}\mathcal{U}(C,T-H, {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}J_{i}(E_{i},A_{i},\Psi_{i}))dt $
s.t.
$\displaystyle {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} Y_{i}(K_{i},Z_{i}E_{i}H_{i})+\Pi=C+\dot{K}-\delta K+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} A_{i}H_{i}$ ,
and
$\displaystyle {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}=H$.

For any variable $ X$, $ \dot{X}$ refers to its change over time.

Table 1: Variables adn Parameters

Variable/Parameter Description
Variable: UInstantaneous utility
Variable: JJob utility function
Variable: tDenotes time
Variable: CTotal consumption of final output
Variable: HTotal work hours
Variable: HiWork hours devoted to ith firm
Variable: Eiith firm effort demands
Variable: Aiith firm amenities provision
Variable: Yiith firm final output
Variable: Kiith firm capital use
Variable: Ziith firm labor-augmenting technology
Parameter: ρDiscount rate
Parameter: TTime endowment
Parameter: ΨiJob-enjoyment technology
Parameter: ΠNon-labor, non-interest income
Parameter: δDepreciation rate

4  From Planning Problem to Real World

Our objective is to deal with many real world features of jobs without adding too much to the complexity of our model. So, we have a broad interpretation of consumption, work hours, effort, amenities, and job utility that allows each to address multiple dimensions of the real world. For example, job-enjoyment technology is meant to capture both innovations in the nature of work proper and innovations in the nature of the work environment.

4.1  Consumption and Work Hours

4.1.1  Consumption

Consumption, $ C$, is meant to capture all the richness of how resources other than time affect life outside of working hours. For instance, a broad notion of consumption necessarily accounts for fringe benefits.

4.1.2  Work Hours

Work hours, $ H$, is meant to capture every way in which a person's job interferes with the quantity and enjoyment of non-work time and home production. For example, if an individual is unable to stop thinking about work issues while at home and this interferes with other activities at home, then that can be considered an effective reduction in leisure and hence an increase in $ H$. Also, consider time spent away from home due to work-related travel. Travel may boost the utility of non-work time if it provides pleasant and interesting experiences. However, work-related travel can also hamper the enjoyment of non-work time because of being away from friends and family. In either case, an adjustment to $ H$ may be warranted.

4.2  Job Utility

4.2.1  Effort

Effort, $ E$, is meant to capture all aspects of a job that generate proportionate changes in effective productive input from labor. Effort has many dimensions. For example, the intensity of a worker's concentration on a task while at his or her work station, the amount of time spent at the water cooler or in other forms of on-the-job leisure, own time spent cleaning and beautifying the work place, time spent in office parties or morale building exercises during work hours, and amount of time spent pursuing worker interests that have some productivity to the firm but would not be the boss's first priority, are all dimensions of effort.

4.2.2  Amenities

Amenities, $ A$, are job characteristics whose cost to the firm is in terms of goods. The real-world characterization of amenities is just as rich as the characterization of effort. For instance, amenities include the number of parking spots, the quality of air conditioning, and the quality and capacity relative to the number of employees of the office gym.9

4.2.3  Job-Enjoyment Technology

Job-enjoyment technology affects the mapping of effort and amenities into overall job utility. Therefore, changes in this technological component can be interpreted as capturing innovations in the nature of work proper, or innovations related to the work environment.

Innovations in the Nature of Work Proper  Innovations in the nature of work proper come in many forms. For example, working in groups, establishing clear guidelines about what is expected from the worker, allowing workers to have greater discretion in the way projects are carried out, developing creative ways to give workers feedback on their performance (including constructive criticism techniques rather than, say, yelling at the worker about what he or she is doing wrong), improving the organizational structure of the firm in terms of who does what, how they do it and when they do it, and allowing individuals greater flexibility in determining the time during which work is carried out all count historically as innovations in the nature of work proper.

Innovations in the Nature of the External Work Environment  Innovations related to the external work environment come in many forms as well. In particular, think of the advent of air conditioning, the distribution, design, and allocation of physical work space (such as cubicalization or open office environments), the provision of on-site childcare, exercise, and laundry facilities, and the institution of measures to reduce the incidence of sexual harassment.

4.2.4  Interpretation of the Job Utility Function

The job utility function $ J_{i}$ itself is the optimum over many possible ways of doing things. For example, consider two production techniques, as shown in Figure 3 in $ \left( E,J\right) $ space. Production technique 1, yielding $ \mathcal{J}_{i}^{1}$, results in relatively higher job utility at lower levels of effort, while production technique 2, yielding $ \mathcal{J}_{i}^{2} $, results in relatively higher job utility at higher levels of effort. Then, $ J_{i}$ is the upper envelope (bold) of these two techniques. The analytical framework that we develop is robust to such non-concavities in job-utility functions.

Figure 3: The Job-Utility Function, $ J_{i}$, as the Upper Envelope of the Two Different Production Techniques $ \mathcal{J}_{i}^{1}$ and $ \mathcal{J}_{i}^{2}$

Figure 3: Figure 3 consists of a single graph. The vertical axis is labeled J (jobs) and the horizontal axis is labeled E (enjoyment). There are two lines on the graph, labeled J sub 1 and J sub 2. Both lines are concave about the origin. Line J_1 represents the outcome of Productive Technique 1 which yields relatively higher job utility at lower levels of effort.  Compared to line J sub 2, line J sub 1 is higher on the y-axis and closer to the origin on the x-axis.  Line J_2 represents the outcome of Productive Technique 2 which yields higher job utility at relatively higher levels of effort, so it is lower on the y-axis and further to the right on the x-axis relative to line J_1.  The lines cross once, about two-thirds of the way through each line past the apex.  The lines are each bold until they cross, and are of lesser thickness where one line extends between the other line and the origin.  The bold segment of each line represents achieving the highest levels of utility on the two production functions.  This line is not perfectly concave about the origin but, instead, dips inward toward the point where J sub 1 and J sub 2 cross.

4.2.5  Reducing the Number of Dimensions for the Arguments of Job Utility

The function $ J_{i}=\mathcal{J}_{i}\left( \mathcal{E}_{i},\mathcal{A} _{i},\Psi_{i}\right) $ maps $ \mathcal{E}_{i}$, $ \mathcal{A}_{i}$, and $ \Psi_{i}$ into the hourly utility associated with being at work. $ \mathcal{E}_{i}$ is a vector describing all dimensions of what the average hour of work is like that affects productivity (aspects of effort, including the fraction of time spent in each different activity at work). $ \mathcal{A} _{i}$ is the amenities counterpart to this. Recall that $ \Psi_{i}$ is job-utility technology. $ \mathcal{E}_{i}$ and $ \mathcal{A}_{i}$ are determined optimally by firms.

The reduced form job utility function comes from maximizing over these vectors, subject to keeping effort-related productivity and the cost of amenities the same, that is,

$\displaystyle J_{i}\left( E_{i},A_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) =$ $\displaystyle \underset{\mathcal{E} _{i}\text{, }\mathcal{A}_{i}}{\max}\{\mathcal{J}_{i}\left( \mathcal{E} _{i},\mathcal{A}_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) \} $

s.t.

$\displaystyle E_{i}=E_{i}\left( \mathcal{E}_{i}\right)$   , 
$\displaystyle A_{i}=p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}}\cdot\mathcal{A}_{i}$,

where $ p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}}$ is a vector of real amenity prices. So, the number $ E_{i}$--hourly effort per worker--gives effective productive input from an hour of labor before multiplication by labor-augmenting technology, while the number $ A_{i}$ summarizes the expenditure on amenities per hour of work.10

We allow for $ J_{i}$ to be either positive or negative and we allow for the possibility that job utility is increasing in effort at relatively small levels of effort, but we assume it must be decreasing in effort at relatively high levels of effort if only because physical and mental exhaustion eventually push $ J_{i}$ toward $ -\infty$ (otherwise there would be no upper limit to feasible $ E_{i}$).11 We also assume that $ \partial J_{i}/\partial A_{i}>0$ and $ \partial J_{i}/\partial\Psi_{i}$.


5  The Household

5.1  Optimization

We now focus on the decentralized version of the representative worker's optimization problem. We show that this problem can be broken into three optimization subproblems that jointly answer the following question: Once job utility is accounted for, what are the key determinants of labor supply?

5.1.1  Main Problem

Given financial wealth $ M$ and job opportunities, the worker chooses consumption $ C$, total work hours $ H$, work hours devoted to each job $ H_{i}$, to maximize utility

$\displaystyle \underset{C,\text{ }H,\text{ }H_{i}}{\max}\text{ }\int e^{-\rho t}(U\left( C\right) +\Phi\left( T-H\right) + {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}J_{i})dt\text{,} $

s.t.

$\displaystyle \dot{M}=rM+\Pi+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} W_{i}H_{i}-C$ , (1)
$\displaystyle {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}=H$,

and

$\displaystyle H_{i}\geq0$.

Overall flow utility comes from consumption utility $ U$, utility from off-the-job leisure $ \Phi$, $ W_{i}$ is the real wage offered by the $ i$th job, which the worker takes as given. We assume that $ U^{\prime}>0$, $ U^{\prime \prime}<0$, $ \Phi^{\prime}>0$, and $ \Phi^{\prime\prime}<0$. The choice of job is represented simply as the choice of whether to devote strictly positive work hours to any one job in particular. Here, we assume that utility is additively separable between consumption $ C$ and all the dimensions of labor. (A companion paper relaxes that assumption, and yields broadly similar results as those we obtain in the present paper).

5.1.2  Optimization Subproblems

The current-value Hamiltonian associated with the worker's problem is

$\displaystyle \mathcal{H}$ $\displaystyle =U\left( C\right) +\Phi\left( T-H\right) + {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}J_{i}$    
  $\displaystyle +b(H- {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i})+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} \mu_{i}H_{i}+\lambda(rM+\Pi+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} W_{i}H_{i}-C)$ .    

This maximization problem can be broken down into four optimization subproblems:

$\displaystyle \max$ $\displaystyle \mathcal{H}$ $\displaystyle =$ $\displaystyle \underset{C}{\max}\left\{ U\left( C\right) -\lambda C\right\} +\lambda\left( rM+\Pi\right)$    
  $\displaystyle +$ $\displaystyle \underset{H}{\max}\{\Phi\left( T-H\right) +bH\}$    
  $\displaystyle +$ $\displaystyle \underset{H_{i}}{\max}\{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} \mu_{i}H_{i}+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}(\underset{=B_{i}}{\underbrace{J_{i}+\lambda W_{i}}})-b {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}\}$ .    

Above, $ \lambda$ is the costate variable giving the marginal value of real wealth; the Euler equation is $ \dot{\lambda}=\rho-r=0$. $ b$ is the multiplier on the work-hours constraint. $ \mu_{i}$ is the multiplier on the nonnegativity constraint for hours at each possible job.12 Finally, $ B_{i}$ denotes the marginal hourly net job benefits associated with a job of type $ i$. The four optimization subproblems nested within maximization of the current-value Hamiltonian are:(1) the consumption decision; (2) job choice; (3) the decision about work hours for each job; and (4) the overall hours decision.

In the additively separable case here we normalize $ J_{i}$ and $ \Phi$ so that $ \Phi^{\prime}\left( T\right) =0$.13 Given this normalization, $ J_{i}>0$ means that a worker would be willing to spend at least some time on a job even if unpaid, should that be the only job available. On the other hand, $ J_{i}<0$ means that a worker would never do such a job unless paid.

Choice of Consumption  As shown in the left panel of Figure 4, the solution to the first optimization sub-problem, $ \underset{C}{\max}\left\{ U\left( C\right) -\lambda C\right\} $ , is to choose consumption to satisfy the first order condition $ U^{\prime}=\lambda$.

Figure 4: Household Solution to Choice of Consumption, $ C$, and Total Work Hours, $ H$

Figure 4: Figure 4 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix.  

Left Panel - The solid line in the left panel is the λ /consumption (C) frontier, labeled by U'(C).  The line is in the first quadrant and is convex away from the origin, stretching between the vertical axis, λ (the costate variable giving the marginal value of real wealth), and the horizontal axis, C (consumption).  A point λ exists on the vertical axis with a dotted line extending to line U'(C) parallel to the horizontal axis.  A point C also exists on the horizontal axis. A dotted line extends out vertically from point C to line U'(C), which meets the other dotted line at a marked but unlabeled point on line U^' (C).  This point represents the determination of the optimal choice of consumption (C).

Right Panel - The solid line in the right panel is the labor-hours supply function, labeled as ɸ’(T-H).  The labor-hours supply function is thus a function of the time endowment less total work hours.  This line is concave about the vertical axis and is the shape of the lower-right quadrant of the unit circle with the origin about the coordinate (0,1). The horizontal axis is labeled H (hours) and the vertical axis B (net job benefits). A point B exists on the vertical axis with a dotted line parallel to the horizontal axis extending from point B to the curve ɸ’(T-H).  A point H exists on the horizontal axis with a dotted line extending vertically to the point at which the dotted line extending from point B intersects ɸ’(T-H). An additional point T, representing the time endowment, exists on the horizontal axis such that T > H. A dashed line extends vertically from T and marks the outer bound of the labor-hours supply function.

Choice of Jobs and Hours at Each Job  Job choice involves surveying all possible job types and choosing the job or jobs with the highest $ B_{i}$. At an optimum $ B=\underset{i}{\text{ }\max}$ $ B_{i}$. It follows that if total work hours are spread across more than one job type it must be the case that each job with positive hours for the individual is offering the same level of (hourly marginal net) job benefits--although they need not be offering the same combination of real wage and job utility. Formally, the level of hourly net job benefits for all jobs with strictly positive hours is $ B=\underset{i}{\max}B_{i}$. We elaborate on the fraction of time devoted to each job later.

Choice of Overall Work Hours  Combining the job choice with the choice of work hours at each job, optimization requires $ H_{i}=0$ if $ J_{i}+\lambda W_{i}<b$ and $ J_{i}+\lambda W_{i}=b$ when $ H_{i}>0$. This implies that $ b=B$: the marginal benefit of overall work hours is equal to the marginal benefit of hours at the job with the highest job benefits. Therefore, total work hours should be chosen to satisfy $ \Phi^{\prime}=B$. In words, at the optimal level of work hours, the marginal utility from off-the-job leisure is equal to job benefits $ B$ of the most attractive job. Thus, the right panel of Figure 4 shows the determination of the optimal choice of $ H$. Note that the labor-hours supply function is $ \Phi^{\prime}$, and the equivalent to a market clearing price for work hours is job benefits $ B$. (We postpone discussion of the determination of the general equilibrium value of $ B$ to Section 7.).

5.2  Implications

Three questions follow immediately. First, how do long-run changes in work hours depend on job utility? Second, assuming there is more than one viable employment opportunity available (that is, assuming more than one firm is able to offer the highest job benefits), how does the worker decide to allocate work hours between jobs? Third, how do short-run changes in work hours depend on job utility?

5.2.1  Implications for Long-Run Labor Supply

Kimball and Shapiro (2008) argue that income effects on labor supply are likely to be substantial. They then look at what that would imply for the Frisch (marginal value of wealth held constant )labor supply elasticity if income and substitution effects on labor supply cancel out. But, our framework allows for work hours to remain relatively constant even if the income effect dominates the substitution effect. Consider the effects when consumption and real wages rise.

Recall that $ B=\lambda W_{i}+J_{i}$, and that as shown in the right panel of Figure 4, work hours are increasing in $ B$. If the income effect dominates the substitution effect, then $ \lambda W_{i}$ is decreasing ($ W_{i}$ is growing, but $ \lambda$ is declining in line with increases in consumption), which. All else equal that makes $ B$--and therefore work hours--decrease as well.

But if job utility, $ J_{i}$, is rising sufficiently, then the income effect can be counterbalanced by the increase in $ J_{i}$ along with the increase in $ W_{i}$ that blunts the fall of $ \lambda W_{i}$ in $ \lambda W_{i}+J_{i}$.

There is another surprising implication. Even if $ \lambda W_{i}\rightarrow0$ because the income effect overwhelms the substitution effect (that is, because $ \lambda\rightarrow0$ more quickly than $ W_{i}$), work hours will tend to some constant $ \bar{H}>0$ as long as job utility $ J_{i}$ tends to some constant $ \bar{J}_{i}>\Phi^{\prime}\left( 0\right) $. That is, even if people face quickly declining marginal utility for additional consumption, a positive asymptote for work hours can exist if there are jobs people enjoy as much as the marginal non-work activity they would otherwise fill out their days with.

5.2.2  Implications for Job Choices

If two jobs have both the same wages and the same job utility, the division of time between them can only be pinned down by general equilibrium forces. But, when two jobs have the same net job benefits but different combinations of wages and job utility, the endogenous determination of $ \lambda$ can lead to a determinate interior optimum based on worker optimization alone. Suppose $ B_{1}=B_{2}$ with $ J_{2}>J_{1}$ and $ W_{1}>W_{2}$. That is, job 1 is higher paid than but job 2 is more pleasant. Let $ \chi$ be the fraction of total work hours that the worker devotes to working for firm $ 1$. At an interior optimum for a worker

$\displaystyle B_{1}=\lambda W_{1}+J_{1}=\lambda_{2}W_{2}+J_{2}=B_{2}$ ,

so $ \lambda=\frac{J_{2}-J_{1}}{W_{1}-W_{2}}$.Given the labor-hours supply function, the optimal level of work hours satisfies $ H=T-\Phi^{^{\prime} -1}\left( B\right) $. Substituting into the worker's budget constraint implies that

$\displaystyle C=\left( T-\Phi^{^{\prime}-1}\left( B\right) \right) \cdot\left( \chi W_{1}+\left( 1-\chi\right) W_{2}\right) +rM+\Pi$ ,

which after rearrangement yields

$\displaystyle \chi=\frac{1}{W_{1}-W_{2}}\left( \frac{U^{\prime}\left( \lambda\right) -rM-\Pi}{T-\Phi^{\prime-1}\left( B\right) }-W_{2}\right) \text{.} $

It follows that for any given marginal value of wealth and job benefits, higher exogenous wealth is associated with greater work hours being devoted to jobs with higher job utility and lower wages. Alternatively, at any given set of wages and equilibrium job benefits, the higher $ \lambda$ is the more work hours are devoted to jobs with the highest wages.

Also, note that in the event that more than two jobs have the same net job benefits, any but the extreme of these set of jobs-the one with the highest wage and lowest job utility and the one with the lowest wage and highest job utility-is equivalent from the worker's perspective to a convex combination of time devoted to the extreme jobs. So, in the absence of fixed costs of going to work the analysis for $ i>2$ jobs is essentially the same as for two jobs. (If there are fixed small costs per job, the worker might slightly prefer an in-between job and would never choose three jobs).

5.2.3  Implications for Short-Run Labor Supply

At any given level of job benefits $ B$, having a more pleasant, lower-paying job will result in a lower (Frisch) labor supply elasticity. To see this, rewrite $ B=\lambda W_{i}+J_{i}$ as $ \lambda(W_{i}\left( 1-\zeta_{i}\right) )$, where $ \zeta_{i}\equiv-J_{i}/\lambda W_{i}$ is the fraction of the wage that is a compensating differential. Defining the elasticity of work hours with respect to $ B$ by $ \bar{\eta}=\frac{\Phi^{\prime}(T-H)}{H\Phi ^{\prime\prime}(T-H)}$ , then $ d\ln H=\bar{\eta}d\ln B$ so that holding everything constant except wages $ d\ln B=d\ln W_{i}/\left( 1-\zeta _{i}\right) $. So, with $ J_{i}$ and $ \lambda$ held constant,

$\displaystyle \eta_{i}=\frac{d\ln H}{d\ln W_{i}}=\frac{d\ln H}{d\ln B_{i}}\frac{d\ln B_{i} }{d\ln W_{i}}=\frac{\bar{\eta}}{\left( 1-\zeta_{i}\right) } $

is the Frisch elasticity of labor supply. Thus, the higher job utility is, the lower is labor supply elasticity with respect to temporary changes in the real wage.

The results about multiple jobs in Section 5.2.2 suggested that as economies become richer, workers are likely to switch to jobs with higher job utility. Therefore, if $ \bar{\eta}$ as determined by the curvature of $ \Phi$ stays relatively constant as an economy gets richer, the volatility of work hours will fall relative to the volatility of temporary changes in the real wage. Cross-sectionally, and more speculatively, workers employed in jobs that they "hate" should have a higher Frisch labor supply elasticity if the relevant curvature of $ \Phi$ is similar across workers in these different jobs.


6  Firms

In the decentralized version of the optimization problem for firms, the firms are price takers in the product market. Each firm's production function takes as inputs capital and effective labor input (the product of hours, effort, and labor-augmenting technology). The firm rents capital at an exogenous rental rate (determined by the international real interest rate). The hourly cost of labor is captured by the inclusive wage: the sum of the real wage and the hourly cost of amenities. The solution to the firm's cost minimization problem implies that its cost function can be stated as a function of the rental rate of capital and the effective wage: the ratio of the inclusive wage to effective labor productivity (the product of effort and labor-augmenting technology). Minimization of the effective wage is the focus of the firm's optimization subproblems.

6.1  Cost Minimization

Consider a representative providing a job with job-enjoyment technology $ \Psi_{i}$. The firm's production function is $ Y_{i}=K_{i}^{\alpha}\left( Z_{i}E_{i}H_{i}\right) ^{1-\alpha}$, where capital's share $ \alpha\in\left( 0,1\right) $ and other variables are as defined earlier. Let $ R$ denote the rental rate of capital, which is exogenous to the firm. (There are no adjustment costs, so $ R=r+\delta$).

For any output level $ \bar{Y}_{i}$ a firm's cost minimization problem involves choosing capital $ K_{i}$, and total work hours $ H_{i}$, to minimize total cost $ RK_{i}+\mathcal{W}_{i}H_{i}$ subject to $ K_{i}^{\alpha}\left( Z_{i} E_{i}H_{i}\right) ^{1-\alpha}=\bar{Y}_{i}$ . $ \mathcal{W}_{i}$ is the inclusive wage:

$\displaystyle \mathcal{W}_{i}=W_{i}+A_{i}$.

That is, in payment for their labor, workers receive the real wage $ W_{i}$ (which includes fringe benefits), and as indirect payment--through job utility--amenities $ A_{i}$.

The solution to the firm's costs minimization problem is standard. The firm's total cost is a function of the desired level of output, $ Y_{i}$, the rental rate of capital, $ R$, and the effective wage, $ \omega_{i}$. The effective wage $ \omega_{i}$ is equal to the inclusive wage per labor effectiveness: $ \omega_{i}=\mathcal{W}_{i}/\left( Z_{i}E_{i}\right) $. Thus, the firm's cost function is

$\displaystyle \mathcal{C}\left( \omega_{i},R,Y_{i}\right) =R^{\alpha}/((\alpha^{\alpha }\left( 1-\alpha\right) ^{1-\alpha})\omega_{i}^{1-\alpha}Y_{i} )$ . (2)

6.2  Optimization Subproblems for Firms

The rental rate of capital is exogenous, but the effective wage is a function of the real wage, effort, and amenities, all of which are choice variables: How should the firm analyze its decision? First, unless the firm is going to shut down, the firm must choose the effective wage so that the firm offers are at least as high as equilibrium job benefits. Then, two nested subproblems follow. The first subproblem involves the choice of amenities. Then, given the optimal choice of amenities, the firm faces a decision about the real wage and effort. The solution to both of these nested subproblems can be summarized in terms of tangency conditions.

6.2.1  The Central Optimization Subproblem: Minimizing the Effective Wage

Given equation (2) , any operating firm should minimize its effective wage subject to its constraints:

$\displaystyle \underset{\mathcal{W}_{i}\text{, }E_{i}}{\min}\text{ }\omega_{i} =\mathcal{W}_{i}/\left( Z_{i}E_{i}\right) $

s.t.

$\displaystyle \underset{=B_{i}}{\underbrace{\lambda\left( \mathcal{W}_{i}-A_{i}\right) +J_{i}\left( E_{i},A_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) }}\text{ }\geq B\text{.} $

In solving this optimization subproblem firms take the marginal value of wealth $ \lambda$, the rental rate of capital $ R$, and equilibrium job benefits $ B$, as given. However, both the real wage $ W_{i}$, and amenities $ A_{i}$, are choice variables. We will assume additive separability in job utility between effort and amenities:

$\displaystyle J_{i}\left( E_{i},A_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) =F_{i}\left( E_{i},\psi_{i} ^{E}\right) +G_{i}\left( A_{i},\psi_{i}^{A},p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}}\right)$    , (3)

where $ \psi_{i}^{E}$ captures innovations in the nature of work proper and $ \psi_{i}^{A}$ captures innovations in the nature of the work environment. We will write $ \Psi_{i}=(\psi_{i}^{E},\psi_{i}^{A},p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}})$.

6.2.2  First Nested Subproblem: Choice of Amenities

By the definitions of the inclusive and effective wages

$\displaystyle \lambda W_{i}=\lambda\left( \mathcal{W}_{i}-A_{i}\right) $

so $ \lambda W_{i}=\lambda\left( \omega_{i}Z_{i}E_{i}-A_{i}\right) $ . Substituting this last equation into the firm's problem of meeting the market level of $ B$ so it can attract workers (which must bind at the optimal solution) it follows that

$\displaystyle \lambda\omega_{i}Z_{i}E_{i}$ $\displaystyle +$ $\displaystyle \underset{=J_{i}\left( E_{i},A_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) }{\underbrace{F_{i}(E_{i},\psi_{i}^{E} )+G_{i}(A_{i},\psi_{i}^{A},p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}})}}\text{ }-\text{ }\lambda A_{i}=B\text{.} $

This implies the nested subproblem:

$\displaystyle \underset{A_{i}}{\max}$ $\displaystyle G(A_{i},\psi_{i}^{A},p_{\mathcal{A}_{i} })-\lambda A_{i}\text{.} $

Thus, the choice of amenities should satisfy the tangency condition $ \partial G_{i}/\partial A=\lambda$. This optimality condition is shown graphically in $ \left( A,G\right) $ space in the left panel of Figure 5.

Figure 5: Solution to a Representative Firm's Optimization Subproblems

Figure 5: Figure 5 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix.  
Left Panel - The x-axis is labeled A (amenities) and the y-axis is a function of amenities, labeled G(A).  A solid line exists on the left panel that is concave in a southeastern direction toward the x-axis.  There is a point A_i on the x-axis and  G_i on the y-axis.  A dotted vertical line extends from point  A_i and a corresponding dotted horizontal line extends from G_i.  These lines meet at a point at which the slope of the curved solid line is equal to λ.  A dashed line with constant slope λ exists on the panel that is tangent to the curved solid line at the point at which the solid line has slope λ, which is also where the dotted lines extending from A_i and G_i intersect each other and the solid line. This point represents the optimal choice of amenities (A) that satisfies the tangency condition  〖dG〗_i/dA= λ.

Right Panel - The x-axis is labeled E (hourly effort per worker) and the y-axis is labeled J ̅ (the net job utility function).  This function can be expressed as Equation 5, which can be interpreted as the firm’s isocost line where B is job benefits, Z_i is labor-augmenting technology, ω_i is the wage, and E_i is effort demands. A solid curved line J_i exists on the right panel that is concave towards the origin and crosses the x-axis. This line traces out all effort and job-utility combinations that are consistent with any given effective wage. There is a point E_i that exists on the x-axis and  J ̅_i on the y-axis.  A dotted vertical line extends from point  E_i and a corresponding dotted horizontal line extends from J ̅_i.  These lines intersect with the given isocost line J_i at a point at which J_i has a slope of -λZ_i ω_i.  A dashed line with a constant slope of -λZ_i ω_i also crosses J_i at this intersection and simultaneously intersects the y-axis at point B.  This dashed line is one of three with varying slopes that intersect the y-axis at a point B.  B represents equilibrium job benefits and following from equation (5), this is the level of utility that would be achieved with zero effort.  A dashed line with a steeper slope of  -λZ_i 〖ω''〗_i exists in the panel that starts at point B on the y-axis and crosses the x-axis between the origin and point E_i.  This line is not tangent to the solid isocost line〖 J〗_i, indicating that the firm can achieve a better effective wage than 〖ω''〗_i.  The third dashed line has the flattest slope of   -λZ_i 〖ω'〗_i and remains above the line J_i, indicating that the wage 〖ω'〗_i is not feasible given the firm’s net job utility function.  It follows that  〖ω''〗_i >ω_i>〖ω'〗_i .

It is helpful to define

$\displaystyle S\left( \lambda,\psi_{i}^{A}\right) \equiv$ $\displaystyle \underset{A_{i}}{\max }\left\{ G(A_{i},\psi_{i}^{A},p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}})-\lambda A_{i}\right\} \text{,} $

the individual surplus received from the firm's optimal choice of amenities. Note that $ S_{\lambda}<0$ by the envelope theorem. Thus, the lower the marginal value of wealth (intuitively, the richer a worker is), the greater the surplus from amenities.

6.2.3  Second Nested Subproblem: Choice of Effort

Given the optimal choice of amenities, the firm's problem of minimizing the effective wage reduces to a second nested subproblem:

$\displaystyle \underset{W_{i}\text{, }E_{i}}{\min}\text{ }\omega_{i}=\frac{\mathcal{W}_{i} }{Z_{i}E_{i}} $

s.t.

$\displaystyle \lambda\omega_{i}Z_{i}E_{i}+\underset{\bar{J}_{i}\left( E_{i},\lambda ,\Psi_{i}\right) }{\underbrace{F(E_{i},\psi_{i}^{E})+S\left( \lambda ,\psi_{i}^{A}\right) }}$  $\displaystyle =B$, (4)

where $ \bar{J}_{i}$ is the net job utility function (net of the costs of amenity provision measured in utils). Rearranging,

$\displaystyle B-\lambda Z_{i}\omega_{i}E_{i}=\bar{J}_{i}\left( E_{i},\lambda,\Psi _{i}\right)$ (5)

and the objective is to find a feasible value of $ \bar{J}_{i}$ corresponding to the lowest $ \omega_{i}$. In $ \left( E,\bar{J}\right) $ space the left-hand side of equation (5) traces out all effort and job-utility combinations that are consistent with any given effective wage: the firm's isocost lines shown as downward sloping lines in the right panel of Figure 5. In that same panel the job utility function is shown as a concave curve. The firm's objective is to find the tangency that yields an isocost line with the intercept at $ B$ and minimum downward (absolute value) slope that touches the job utility curve.

In other words, given $ B$, the solution to the firm's optimization subproblem is implicitly captured by the isocost line that has the flattest (algebraically greatest) feasible slope. Feasibility is determined by the firm's net job utility function, which captures all net job utility and effort combinations that a firm is able to offer. As seen in the right panel of Figure 5, $ \omega_{i}^{\prime\prime}>\omega_{i}>\omega_{i}^{\prime}$ and $ \omega_{i}$ is the firm's optimal effective wage: it can do better than $ \omega_{i}^{\prime\prime}$, and although $ \omega_{i}^{\prime}$ is preferred to $ \omega_{i}$, the former is not feasible given the firm's net job utility function.

Given $ A_{i}$ and $ S\left( \lambda,\psi_{i}^{A}\right) $, once the optimal $ E_{i}$ and $ \omega_{i}$ are pinned down, it is straightforward to back out the optimal $ W_{i}$ using the definition of the effective wage and the value of $ J_{i}$ given the definition of net job utility.

6.2.4  Why Effort is Unpleasant at the Optimum

Despite the fact that job utility can be increasing in effort for some part of the range, the tangency condition shown in the right panel of Figure 5 implies that effort will be unpleasant at the optimum. Indeed, at the optimum:

$\displaystyle \frac{\partial\bar{J}_{i}}{\partial E_{i}}=-\lambda Z_{i}\omega_{i} =\frac{\partial J_{i}}{\partial E_{i}}\implies\frac{\partial J_{i}}{\partial E_{i}}E_{i}=-\lambda\left( W_{i}+A_{i}\right) \text{.} $

Then, $ \lambda>0$ and $ E_{i}>0$ imply that for positive wages (and nonnegative amenities), at the optimal choice of effort $ \partial J_{i}/\partial E_{i}<0$. That is, the optimal choice of effort occurs where job utility is decreasing in effort.

In other words, since effort is productive it would make no sense to limit effort when additional effort is also pleasant. Effort should be increased until additional effort is painful enough that it counterbalances the extra productivity.


7  Equilibrium

The next question is: How are equilibrium job benefits and the marginal value of wealth determined?

7.1  Job Benefits

From any firm's point of view the firm-specific effective wage, $ \omega_{i}$, must equal the prevailing market value of $ \omega$ for the firm to have positive output. Perfect competition in the product market implies that, in equilibrium, each firm's marginal cost is equal to the price of final output--which is normalized to 1. Given the cost function in equation % latex2html id marker 5285 $ \left( \ref{cost function}\right) $ that means firms with positive output must have

$\displaystyle 1=\left( R^{\alpha}/(\alpha^{\alpha}\left( 1-\alpha\right) ^{1-\alpha })\right) \omega_{i}^{1-\alpha}\text{,} $

which implies

$\displaystyle \underset{=\omega_{i}}{\underbrace{\frac{W_{i}+A_{i}}{Z_{i}E_{i}}}\text{ } }=\text{ }\underset{=\omega}{\underbrace{\left( \frac{\alpha^{\alpha}\left( 1-\alpha\right) ^{1-\alpha}}{R^{\alpha}}\right) ^{1/\left( 1-\alpha\right) }}}\text{.} $

Figure 6 extends the intuition from Figure 5 to this case in which, as far as a representative firm is concerned, the slope of an isocost line $ -\lambda Z_{i}\omega$ is exogenously determined. Because cost minimization must hold, optimality continues to require being at a point of tangency between the net job utility function and an isocost line. Amenities $ A_{i}$ are determined as earlier.

Given the values of $ \lambda$, $ Z_{i}$, and $ \omega$, the firm faces, the left panel of Figure 6 shows optimal effort requirements, $ E_{i}$, and net job utility, $ \bar{J}_{i}$. These determine the optimal real wage $ W_{i} =\omega/Z_{i}E_{i}-A_{i}$, and job utility $ J_{i}$.

Figure 6: Determination of Total Work Hours Under Perfect Competition

Figure 6: Figure 6 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix. Figure 6 extends the intuition from Figure 5 to the case in which the slope of the isocost line -λZ_i ω is exogenously determined for the representative firm.  Optimality is achieved at the point of tangency between the net job utility function (J ̅_i) and an isocost line.

Left Panel - The solid line in the left panel represents net job utility, labeled by J ̅_i.  This line is concave about the origin and crosses the horizontal axis. The horizontal axis is labeled E (employment) and the vertical axis is labeled J ̅  (job utility). There exists a point E_i on the horizontal axis with a dotted line extending vertically from E_i to meet the solid line J ̅_i.
There also exists a point J ̅_i on the vertical axis with a dotted line extending horizontally from J ̅_i to the same point on the solid line J ̅_i as the other dotted line extending from E_i. There exists a point B on the vertical axis such that point B > point J ̅_i.  Point B marks the y-intercept of a dashed line with slope -λZ_i ω.  In addition, a dotted line extends from point B parallel to the x-axis and intersects the solid line in the right panel, which is labeled ɸ’(T-H). The dashed line of slope -λZ_i ω is tangent to the job utility function J ̅_i at the same point at which the two dotted lines extending from points J ̅_i and E_i intersect the utility function.

Right Panel - This panel shows the determination of total work hours, H.  The vertical axis is labeled B for job benefits and a dotted horizontal line extending from the left panel crosses the vertical axis and intersects the solid line labeled by ɸ’(T-H).  A point H exists on the horizontal axis (also labeled H for work hours) with a dotted line extending vertically, parallel to the vertical axis, to intersect the function ɸ’(T-H) at this same point.  This function is represented by a curve that is concave about the vertical axis and is the shape of the lower-right quadrant of the unit circle with the origin about the coordinate (0,1). An additional point T, representing the time endowment, exists on the horizontal axis such that T > H. A dashed line extends vertically from T and marks the outer bound of the labor-hours supply function.

The intersection of the firm's isocost line with the horizontal axis now determines equilibrium job benefits $ B$. Given this equilibrium level of $ B$, the right panel of Figure 6 shows the determination of total work hours, $ H$. This logic can be expressed by the functions $ E_{i}=E_{i}\left( \omega\lambda Z_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) $ and $ B_{i}=B_{i}\left( \omega\lambda Z_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) $. Note that the firm that is able to offer the highest job benefits is the firm that implicitly sets the economy's equilibrium level of job benefits.

7.2  The Marginal Value of Wealth

7.2.1  The Labor Earnings Functions

In general equilibrium, our open-economy framework has $ r=\rho$, and $ C=rM+\Pi+H {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} \chi_{i}W_{i}$, where $ \chi_{i}$ is the fraction of total work hours that the individual devotes to firm $ i$. (Thus, $ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} \chi_{i}=1$.). Let $ \mathbb{W}= {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} \chi_{i}W_{i}$ denote the wage averaged across jobs. Given the individual's first-order condition for consumption, a labor-earnings demand function ($ LE^{D}$) can be defined as follows:

$\displaystyle \mathbb{W}H=U^{\prime-1}\left( \lambda\right) -rM-\Pi=LE^{D}$ . (6)

Since $ W_{i}=Z_{i}\omega E_{i}-A_{i}$, a labor-earnings supply function ($ LE^{S}$) can be defined in this way:

$\displaystyle \mathbb{W}H= {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} \left( Z_{i}\omega\cdot E_{i}\left( \omega\lambda Z_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) -A_{i}\left( \lambda,\psi_{i}^{A},p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}}\right) \right) \cdot H_{i}\left( B\left( \omega\lambda Z_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) \right) =LE^{S}$ , (7)

where once again we have made use of the definition of the average wage.

7.2.2  Graphing Labor-Earnings Demand and Labor-Earnings Supply

Labor-Earnings Demand   $ U^{\prime}\left( \cdot\right) $ is decreasing in $ C$. Therefore, equation % latex2html id marker 5351 $ \left( \ref{LE_D}\right) $ implies a negative relationship between $ \lambda$ and labor-earnings demand as measured by $ \mathbb{W}H$. Thus, in $ (\mathbb{W}H,\lambda)$ space the labor-earnings demand function is downward sloping.

Labor-Earnings Supply  For labor-earnings supply consider first the case in which only clones of firm $ i$ exist. Then, $ LE^{S}$ is given by

$\displaystyle \mathbb{W}H=\left[ Z_{i}\omega\cdot E_{i}\left( \omega\lambda Z_{i},\Psi _{i}\right) -A_{i}\left( \lambda,\psi_{i}^{A},p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}}\right) \right] \cdot H_{i}\left( B\left( \omega\lambda Z_{i},\Psi_{i}\right) \right)$    .

Showing that in $ (\mathbb{W}H,\lambda)$ space labor-earnings supply is downward sloping requires answering the following three questions.

(a) What does a change in $ \lambda$ imply for amenities? Suppose that the marginal value of wealth $ \lambda$ rises to $ \lambda^{\prime }$. Then, as shown in the left panel of Figure 7, amenities decrease. This means that the surplus from amenities received by individuals, $ S\left( \lambda,\psi_{i}^{A}\right) $, declines, which--as shown in the right panel of Figure 7--induces a downward shift in the net job utility function in $ \left( E,\bar{J}\right) $ space.

Figure 7: Derivation of Labor-Earnings Supply Curve

Figure 7: Figure 7 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix. 

Left Panel - The solid line in the left panel represents the labor-earnings supply curve.  This line is initially upward slowing but is then downward sloping, and is concave about the horizontal axis, which is labeled A for amenities.  There exists two points on the horizontal axis labeled by 〖A'〗_i and A_i such that 〖A'〗_i < A_i and there is an arrow beneath the axis pointing towards the origin, or from A_i to 〖A'〗_i.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from these two points upward to meet the solid line. The vertical axis is labeled G(A).  There exists two points on the vertical axis labeled by 〖G'〗_i and G_i such that 〖G'〗_i < G_i and there is an arrow next to the vertical axis pointing towards the origin, or from G_i to〖 G'〗_i.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from 〖G'〗_i and G_i horizontally to meet the solid line at the same points at which the dotted lines from 〖A'〗_i and A_i, respectively, intersect the solid line.  At both of these points, which are at the coordinates (〖G'〗_i, 〖A'〗_i) and (G_i, A_i), are straight, dashed lines which are each tangent to the solid line.  The dashed tangent line at (〖G'〗_i, 〖A'〗_i) is labeled with a slope of λ' and the tangent line at (G_i, A_i) has a slope of λ.  When the marginal value of wealth λ rises to λ', then amenities decrease.

Right Panel - There are two solid lines in the right panel.  They represent the net job utility function that shifts downward from J ̅_i=F+S to J ̅_i=F+S', where S is the surplus from amenities received by individuals that is decreased to S' when the marginal value of wealth λ rises to λ'.  Both lines are concave about the origin and cross the horizontal axis, with  J ̅_i=F+S' closer to the origin. There exists two points on the horizontal axis, E (employment) labeled by 〖E'〗_i and E_i such that 〖E'〗_i > E_i and there is an arrow beneath the axis pointing away from the origin, or from E_i to 〖E'〗_i.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from these two points upward to meet the respective solid line, J ̅_i=F+S and J ̅_i=F+S^'. The vertical axis is labeled J ̅  (job utility). There exists two points on the vertical axis labeled by J ̅'_i and J ̅_i such that  J ̅_i > J ̅'_i and there is an arrow next to the axis pointing towards the origin, or from J ̅_i to J ̅'_i.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from these two points horizontally to meet the respective solid line, J ̅_i=F+S and J ̅_i=F+S^'. Also on the vertical axis, there exist two points, B and B' such that B<B^', or job benefits rise from B to〖 B〗^'.  A dashed line extends from each of these points that is tangent to the corresponding isocost line, J ̅_i=F+S and J ̅_i=F+S^', at the points (J ̅_i, E_i) and (J ̅'_i, 〖E'〗_i).  The dashed line extending from B has a slope of -λZ_i ω and the line from B^' has a slope of -λZ_i ω', where ω stands for the effective wage and Z is for labor-augmenting technology.

(b) What does a change in $ \lambda$ imply for the isocost lines? The right panel of Figure 7 shows that higher $ \lambda^{\prime}$ implies a steeper isocost line, which in turn leads to a decline in net job utility and a rise in effort. Also, although the change can seem ambiguous, job benefits rise to $ B^{\prime}$, which leads to higher work hours.14 $ dB/d\lambda>0$ means that the $ H$ in $ \mathbb{W}H$ goes up.

(c) How do real wages factor in? If all firms are identical $ \mathbb{W}$ is trivially equal to $ W_{i}$. The analysis behind Figure 7 showed that the result of higher marginal value of wealth includes lower amenities, $ A_{i}$, and higher effort, $ E_{i}$. $ \omega$ is unchanged, and since $ W_{i}=Z_{i}\omega E_{i}-A_{i}$

$\displaystyle dW_{i}/d\lambda=Z_{i}\omega dE_{i}/d\lambda-dA_{i}/d\lambda>0$ .

Taken together, the answers to these three questions imply that labor-earnings is increasing in $ \lambda$ so that $ LE^{S}$ is upward sloping in $ (\mathbb{W}H,\lambda)$ space.

Determination of the Marginal Value of Wealth  Figure 8 shows $ LE^{D}$ and $ LE^{S}$, and the determination of equilibrium $ \lambda$ and labor earnings $ \mathbb{W}H$ when all firms are identical.

Figure 8: Equilibrium Labor Earnings and the Marginal Value of Wealth Using Labor-Earnings Supply and Demand

Figure 8: Figure 8 consists of a single graph.

The horizontal axis is labeled WH for labor earnings.  A point WH exists on the horizontal axis with a dotted line extending vertically to the intersection of LE^D and LE^S, the labor-earnings demand and supply functions, respectively.  The labor-earnings supply function, LE^S, is represented by an upward sloping solid line that is concave towards the vertical axis.  The labor-earnings demand function, LE^D, is represented by a downward sloping solid line that is concave away from the origin.  

The vertical axis is labeled λ for the marginal value of wealth. A point λ exists on the vertical axis with a dotted line extending horizontally to the intersection of LE^D and LE^S.  The labor-earnings supply and demand functions intersect at the point (WH, λ).

What about the determination of the marginal value of wealth and labor earnings when firms with a range of wage/effort combinations are operational? For simplicity, consider the case of two types of firms indexed by $ i=1,2$, which, as noted in Section 5.2.2, can be thought of as the relevant extremes.

Suppose these two types of firms have job utility functions given by $ J_{1}=\mathcal{J}_{1}$ and $ J_{2}=\mathcal{J}_{2}$ as depicted in Figure 3. Then, what is relevant is the upper envelope of these job utility functions. For a sufficiently low marginal value of real wealth, say $ \lambda^{\prime}$, firm 1 is able to offer the highest marginal net job benefits and type 2 firms do not operate. For a higher marginal value of real wealth, say, $ \lambda^{\prime\prime}>\lambda^{\prime}$ both type 1 and type 2 firms are able to offer the same marginal net job benefits and workers allocate hours across firms according to the logic in Section 5.2.2. Finally for even higher marginal values of real wealth such as, say, $ \lambda^{\prime\prime\prime}>\lambda^{\prime\prime }$ type 2 firms are able to offer the highest marginal net job benefits, and type 1 firms are unable to operate.

Market equilibrium can be shown in the labor-earnings supply and demand diagram. $ LE^{D}$ is a simple extension what we derived above. In particular, labor-earnings demand is described by

$\displaystyle \lambda=U^{\prime}\left( rM+\Pi+\left( \chi_{1}W_{1}+\left( 1-\chi _{1}\right) W_{2}\right) H\right)$    ,

where $ \chi_{1}$ is the fraction of total work hours devoted to firms of type 1. The appropriate version of labor-earnings supply is slightly different than that considered earlier. For sufficiently low values of $ \lambda$ only firms of type 1 operate and the associated real wages, marginal net job benefits, and work hours are relatively low. Therefore, in terms of labor-earnings supply, low values of $ \lambda$ are associated with low labor earnings.

At the critical value $ \lambda^{\prime\prime}$ noted above both types of firms are operational. Figure 9 shows an equilibrium in which both types of firms are operational. Wages, marginal net job benefits, and hours are higher than under $ \lambda^{\prime}$-and therefore so are labor earnings. However at $ \lambda^{\prime\prime}$ any level of labor earnings within a certain range is an equilibrium, implying a perfectly elastic portion of the labor-earnings supply curve. In this region, an increase in non-labor income that shifts $ LE^{D}$ out leads to allocations of more hours toward the more pleasant job without changing $ \lambda$.

Finally, for higher values of $ \lambda$ only firms of type 2 are operational. This is associated with higher wages, marginal net job benefits, and hours. Thus, in terms of labor-earnings supply high values of $ \lambda$ are associated with high values of labor earnings.

Figure 9: Labor Earnings Supply and Demand With Two Firms

7.3  Implications

Our framework allows us to address several interesting questions. For instance: How does a firm's overall technology matter for its competitiveness? What are the effects of changes in technology (whether changes in labor-augmenting technology or job-enjoyment technology) on labor earnings and the marginal value of wealth? Which changes in technology are consistent with higher real wages and trendless labor hours if the income effect outweighs the substitution effect?

In the Appendix, we show the following. First, within our framework, differences in job-enjoyment technology between firms can counterbalance differences in labor-augmenting technology, and vice versa. In particular, a firm falling behind in labor-augmenting technological progress can keep up its ability to attract workers even with lower wages if its job enjoyability technology advances sufficiently. Second, within our framework, a permanent increase in labor augmenting technology, a permanent positive innovation in the nature of work proper, or a permanent positive innovation in the nature of the work environment can each lead simultaneously to higher labor earnings, a lower marginal value of real wealth, and trendless or nearly trendless work hours.

In essence, then, anything that "regular" technology can do, job enjoyability technology can do as well. To the extent that higher job utility matters for competitiveness, it is even plausible that firms might set what would otherwise be above-optimal effort requirements in order to induce workers themselves to think of ways to increase job utility. This amounts to a low cost form of research and development in job enjoyment technology.


8  Welfare

We argue above that and upward trend in job utility make it possible for work hours to remain approximately constant over time even if the income effect of higher real wages on labor supply exceeds the substitution effect of higher real wages. The question that immediately follows is: What are the welfare effects of such changes? In this section, we elaborate on the relationship between job utility and welfare, suggest ways in which theoretical relationships can be operationalized and give a numerical example for the potential welfare gains associated with secular changes in job utility. Under straightforward though far from certain assumptions, given constant work hours, an observed increase in consumption of 1% might be associated with an increase in welfare of 2%. In this case, at least half of these welfare gains are coming from increases in job utility.

8.1  Measuring Welfare

In our framework, changes in welfare induced by changes in exogenous parameters are well assessed via comparative steady-state analysis. In steady state, given $ r=\rho$, an individual's problem is equivalent to the static optimization problem

$\displaystyle \underset{C\text{, }H\text{, }H_{i}\geq0}{\max}\text{ }U(C)+\Phi(T-H)+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}J_{i} $

s.t

$\displaystyle C=rM+\Pi+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} W_{i}H_{i} $

and

$\displaystyle H= {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}$.

Given the multipliers $ \lambda$ and $ b$, let

$\displaystyle \mathcal{L}^{\ast}=\underset{C\text{, }H\text{, }H_{i}\geq0}{\max}\text{ }\{U(C)+\Phi(T-H)+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}J_{i}+b\left( H- {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}\right) +\lambda\left( rM+\Pi+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} W_{i}H_{i}-C\right) \}\text{.} $

Recall that the optimal choice of $ H_{i}$ yields two cases: $ H_{i}=0$ and $ J_{i}+\lambda W_{i}<b$, or $ H_{i}>0$ and $ J_{i}+\lambda W_{i}=b$. Therefore, $ b=B$, where, $ B$ denotes the economy's level of equilibrium marginal net job benefits.

Using the envelope theorem,

$\displaystyle d\mathcal{L}^{\ast}/\lambda= {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}dJ_{i}/\lambda+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}dW_{i}+d\left( \Pi+rM\right)$    . (8)

Above, each of the three terms on the right-hand side highlight distinct ways in which the economy's opportunity set becomes larger. Changes in welfare from changes in job utility are captured by the first term; changes in welfare from higher wages are reflected in the second term; and changes in welfare from changes in exogenous wealth appear in the last term. The first term $ \left( {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}\right) dJ_{i}/\lambda$ can be interpreted as the portion of the change in the maximized value of utility that answers the question of how much the worker would have to be paid per year in order to be willing to go back to working in yesterday's conditions.

8.2  Toward Pinning Down the Implied Increase in Welfare

To better understand the implications of the envelope theorem as laid out in equation (8) note that the second term on the right-hand side is the change in wages for narrowly defined job categories (for which, empirically, it should be possible to obtain a direct measure) and satisfies

$\displaystyle {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}dW_{i}=d\left( {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}\right) - {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} W_{i}dH_{i}$ .

Therefore, to gauge this component of welfare, we need to adjust the change in overall labor earnings by subtracting not only extra earnings from people working longer hours overall, but also extra earnings coming from people switching towards jobs that are more highly paid and have lower job utility. If $ \lambda W$ is moving down, then the overall trend should involve compositional shifts towards jobs with higher job utility and relatively lower pay than other available jobs. This means that the increase in labor earnings will tend to understate the true increase in welfare (leaving aside changes in overall hours, which obviously need to be adjusted for).

In terms of understanding the remaining terms for the change in welfare, note that

$\displaystyle B=J_{i}+\lambda W_{i} $

which implies

$\displaystyle \frac{dJ_{i}}{\lambda}=\frac{dB}{\lambda}-W_{i}\frac{d\lambda}{\lambda} -dW_{i}$ .

Thus, pinning down the first term in the right-hand side of equation (8) calls for looking at labor hours, consumption, and hourly wages. Substituting into equation (8) and rearranging yields

$\displaystyle \frac{d\mathcal{L}^{\ast}}{\lambda {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}=\frac{H}{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}\frac{dB}{\lambda}-\frac{d\lambda}{\lambda}+\frac{d\left( \Pi+rM\right) }{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}$ . (9)

The last term on the right-hand side-the value of extra non-labor income-is easy to understand. Hence, we will focus on getting measures for the first two terms on the right-hand side of equation (9).

Define $ \gamma=-CU_{CC}\mathbf{/}U_{C}$. (That is, $ 1/\gamma$ is the elasticity of intertemporal substitution.). Then $ d\lambda/\lambda=-\gamma dC/C$. Moreover, as discussed earlier, for any job $ i$ the Frisch elasticity of labor supply $ \eta_{i}$ and the fraction $ \zeta_{i}$ of the wage that is a compensating differential, $ \eta_{i}=\bar{\eta}/\left( 1-\zeta_{i}\right) $, where $ \bar{\eta}=\Phi^{\prime}\left( T-H\right) /\left( H\phi ^{\prime\prime}\left( T-H\right) \right) $ , it follows that

$\displaystyle dB/B=\left( 1/\bar{\eta}\right) dH/H\implies dB=\frac{\left( \left( 1-\zeta_{i}\right) \lambda W_{i}\right) }{\bar{\eta}}dH/H\implies dB/\lambda=\left( W_{i}/\eta_{i}\right) dH/H$ . (10)

Substituting the appropriate expressions into equation (9) and simplifying yields

$\displaystyle \frac{d\mathcal{L}^{\ast}}{\lambda {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}=\frac{\left( W_{i}/\eta_{i}\right) dH}{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}+\frac{\gamma dC}{C}+\frac{d\left( \Pi+rM\right) }{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}$ . (11)

The intuition for equation (11) is that in the additively separable case $ \gamma$ tells how many times bigger the income effect is than the substitution effect. If hours are relatively constant despite increasing wages, then there must be substantial increases in job utility to counteract the income effects associated with increases in consumption. On the other hand, if hours $ H$ move in the direction indicated by the income effect it gives less hint of improvements in job utility. (If $ \gamma=1$, income and substitution effects cancel, but increases in consumption still have the usual effect on welfare.).

8.3  Calibrating $ \gamma$ from Job Choices

In addition to evidence from the effects of interest rates on the path of consumption, in principle evidence about $ \gamma$ can be found from workers' job choices. Consider an individual working two jobs satisfying $ J_{2}>J_{1}$. Then, $ \lambda W_{1}+J_{1}=\lambda W_{2}+J_{2}$, meaning that

$\displaystyle \lambda=\frac{J_{2}-J_{1}}{W_{2}-W_{1}}\implies\frac{d\lambda}{\lambda} =\frac{dJ_{1}-dJ_{2}}{J_{1}-J_{2}}-\frac{dW_{1}-dW_{2}}{W_{1}-W_{2}}$ .

For any individual with $ dJ_{1}-dJ_{2}=0$, for example, $ dJ_{1},dJ_{2}=0$, then

$\displaystyle d\lambda/\lambda=-\left( dW_{1}-dW_{2}\right) /\left( W_{1}-W_{2}\right)$    ,

and using $ d\lambda/\lambda=-\gamma dC/C$ it follows that

$\displaystyle \gamma=\left[ \left( dW_{1}-dW_{2}\right) /\left( W_{1}-W_{2}\right) \right] /\left( dC/C\right)$    .

8.4  Illustrating the Calculation of Welfare Gains

The short-run elasticity of intertemporal substitution has been suggested by Hall (1988) to be approximately zero, and by Kimball, Sahm, and Shapiro (2011) to be 0.08. However, there are reasons to think the long-run elasticity of intertemporal substitution should be higher than its short-run counterpart. This includes taking account of full adjustment, new goods, habit formation, and "keeping up with the Joneses." In the context of our analysis, it is the long-run elasticity of intertemporal substitution that should be used. Suppose the long-run elasticity of intertemporal substitution is 0.5, in which case $ \gamma=2$. Using this value for $ \gamma$ along with equation % latex2html id marker 5571 $ \left( \ref{welfare 3}\right) $ implies that for $ d\Pi=0$, $ dM=0$, and $ dH=0 $, a 1% increase in consumption would be associated with a welfare increase of at least 2%.

A natural question that follows is what fraction of welfare gains are attributable to higher job utility. To see this, note that dividing equation (8) by $ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}$ and combining it with equation (11) yields

$\displaystyle \frac{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}dJ_{i}}{\lambda {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}+\frac{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}dW_{i}}{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}=\frac{\left( W_{i}/\eta_{i}\right) dH}{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}+\frac{\gamma dC}{C}\text{,} $

or

$\displaystyle \frac{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}dJ_{i}}{\lambda {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}+\underset{=1\%-1\%}{\underbrace{\left( \frac{d {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}-\frac{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} W_{i}dH_{i}}{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}\right) }}=\underset{=0}{\underbrace{\frac{\left( W_{i}/\eta _{i}\right) dH}{ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}W_{i}}}}+\underset{=\gamma\%}{\underbrace{\frac{\gamma dC}{C}}}$    , (12)

where the second term on the left-hand side reflects switching from relatively higher paid jobs to relatively lower paid jobs. If there were no changes in job utility or hours then a 1% increase in consumption is just a 1% increase in consumption. But, if consumption increases 1%, $ \gamma=2$, $ dH=0$ endogenously despite the income effect exceeding the substitution effect, then this equation implies an increase in welfare equivalent to the direct effect of a 2% increase in consumption. So, the difference, 1%, must be due to improvements in job utility from the two terms on the left of equation (12).


9  Conclusions

The paradox of hard work is this: for decades, work hours per capita among adults have remained roughly trendless, despite strong trends in macroeconomic variables, such as real consumption and real wages. In principle, the paradox of hard work can be rationalized in several different ways. Of these alternatives, we focus on the general equilibrium effects of secular changes that make work more pleasant. Economists have long understood that cross-sectional differences in job utility at a particular time give rise to compensating differentials. In this paper, we develop a theory that focuses on the less-studied long-run macroeconomic consequences of trends in job utility.

Our theory allows for the interaction of work hours (which stands in for all aspects of the job that interfere with leisure and home production) and effort (which stands in for all aspects of a job whose cost is in terms of proportionate changes in effective productive input from labor). We also consider the role of amenities (which we define to be job characteristics whose cost is in terms of goods) and the role of secular increases in job utility (that is, secular declines in drudgery, which can stem from changes in standard notions of technology, such as labor-augmenting technology, and also from changes in job-enjoyment technology). General equilibrium can be analyzed through two new theoretical objects: labor-earnings supply and labor-earnings demand.

Two main implications emerge. First, secular improvements in job utility imply that work hours can remain approximately constant over time even if the income effect of higher wages on labor supply exceeds the substitution effect of higher wages. Second, secular improvements in job utility can themselves be a substantial component of the welfare gains from technological progress. These two implications are connected by an equation flowing from optimal hours choices: improvements in job utility that have a significant effect on labor supply tend to have large welfare effects.


Bibliography

Abel, Andrew B. 1990. "Asset Prices Under Habit Formation and Catching Up With the Joneses." American Economic Review, 80(2): 38-42.

Alesina, Alberto F., Edward L. Glaeser and Bruce Sacerdote. 2006. "Work and Leisure in the U.S. and Europe: Why So Different?" In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2005, Volume 20, edited by Mark Gertler and Kenneth Rogoff. MIT Press.

Altonji, Joseph G. 1982. "The Intertemporal Substitution Model of Labour Market Fluctuations: An Empirical Analysis." Review of Economic Studies, 49 (5): 783-824.

Barsky, Robert B., F. Thomas Juster, Miles S. Kimball, and Matthew D. Shapiro. 1997. "Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Study." Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2): 537-579.

Basu, Susanto, and Miles S. Kimball. 2002. "Long-Run Labor Supply and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution for Consumption." Boston College and University of Michigan: unpublished manuscript.

Blundell, Richard, Pierre-Andre Chiappori, Thierry Magnac and Costas Meghir. 2001. "Collective Labor Supply: Heterogeneity and Nonparticipation." Institute for Fiscal Studies, London Working Paper 01/19.

Blundell, Richard and Thomas MaCurdy. 1999. "Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches." In Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, eds. Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 3A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Blundell, Richard, Costas Meghir and Pedro Neves. 1993. "Labor Supply and Intertemporal Substitution." Journal of Econometrics 59: 197-160.

Coulibaly, Brahima. 2006. "Changes in Job Quality and Trends in Labor Hours." International Finance Discussion Papers 882. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Epstein, Brendan and Ryan Nunn. 2013. "Taxation, Match Quality, and Social Welfare." International Finance Discussion Papers 1079. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Epstein, Brendan and Shanthi P. Ramnath. 2014. "Taxes and Long-Run Changes in OECD Work Hours Revisited." Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and United States Treasury Department: unpublished manuscript.

Faggio, Giulia and Stephen Nickell. 2007. "Patterns of Work Across the OECD." The Economic Journal, 117 (521): F416-F440.

Fang, Lei and Cara McDaniel. 2011. "Trends in Home Hours in the U.S. and Europe." Unpublished manuscript available at www.caramcdaniel.com

Francis, Neville and Valerie Ramey. 2009. "A Century of Work and Leisure." American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1 (2): 189-224.

Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. 2000. "Habit Formation in Consumption and its Implications for Monetary Policy Models." American Economic Review, 90 (3): 367-390.

Guner, Nezih, Remzi Kaygusuz and Gustavo Ventura. 2012. "Taxation and Household Labor Supply." Review of Economic Studies, 79 (3): 1113-1149.

Hall, Robert E. 1988. "Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption." The Journal of Political Economy, 96: 339-357.

Hansen, Gary D. 1985. "Indivisible Labor and the Business Cycle." Journal of Monetary Economics, 16 (3): 309-327.

Heston, Alan, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten. Penn World Table, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania.

Keynes, John Maynard. 1930. "Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren." Printed in Vol. IX of The Collected Writings of JM Keynes, 1973. London: Macmillan for The Royal Economic Society.

Kimball, Miles S., Claudia Sahm and Matthew D. Shapiro. 2011. "Measuring Time Preference and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution Using Web Surveys." Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and University of Michigan: unpublished manuscript.

Kimball, Miles S., and Matthew D. Shapiro. 2008. "Labor Supply: Are the Income Effects Both Large or Both Small?" NBER Working Paper No. 14208.

King, Robert G., Charles I. Plosser, and Sergio R. Rebelo. 1988. "Production, Growth and Business Cycles: I. The Basic Neoclassical Model." Journal of Monetary Economics 21: 195-232.

Krusell, Per, Toshihiko Mukoyama, Richard Rogerson and Aysegul Sahin. 2008. "Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor, Incomplete Markets, and Labor Market Frictions." Journal of Monetary Economics, 55 (5): 961-979.

Ljungqvist, Lars and Thomas J. Sargent. 2007. "Do Taxes Explain European Employment? Indivisible Labor, Human Capital, Lotteries, and Personal Savings." In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2006, Volume 21, edited by D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and M. Woodford, 181-246. The MIT Press.

Luttmer, Erzo F.P. 2005. "Neighbors as Negatives: Relative Earnings and Well-Being." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120 (3): 963-1002.

MaCurdy, Thomas E. 1981. "An Empirical Model of Labor Supply in a Life-Cycle Setting." Journal of Political Economy, 89: 1059-1085.

Mankiw, Gregory N., Julio J. Rotemberg and Lawrence H. Summers. 1985. "Intertemporal Substitution in Macroeconomics." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100 (1): 225-251.

McDaniel, Cara. 2011. "Forces Shaping Hours Worked in the OECD, 1960-2004." American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3 (4): 27-52.

Mulligan, Casey B. 1998. "Substitution Over Time: Another Look at Life-Cycle Labor Supply." In Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1998. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Mulligan, Casey B. 2001. "Aggregate Implications of Indivisible Labor." NBER Working Paper No. 8159.

Ohanian, Lee, Andrea Raffo and Richard Rogerson. 2008. "Long-Term Changes in Labor Supply and Taxes: Evidence from OECD Countries, 1956-2004." Journal of Monetary Economics, 55 (8): 1353-1362.

Patterson, Kerry D. and Bahram Pesaran. 1992. "The Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution in Consumption in the United States and the United Kingdom." The Review of Economics and Statistics, 74 (4): 573-584.

Prescott, Edward C. 2004. "Why do Americans Work so Much More than Europeans?" NBER Working Paper No. 10316.

Prescott, Edward C., Richard Rogerson and Johanna Wallenius. 2009. "Lifetime Aggregate Labor Supply with Endogenous Workweek Length." Review of Economic Dynamics, 12 (1): 23-36.

Prescott, Edward C. and Johanna Wallenius. 2011. "Aggregate Labor Supply." Staff Report 457, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

Rayo, Luis, and Gary S. Becker. 2007. "Habits, Peers, and Happiness: An Evolutionary Perspective." American Economic Review, 97 (2): 487-491.

Rogerson, Richard. 1988. "Indivisible Labor, Lotteries, and Equilibrium." Journal of Monetary Economics, 21 (1): 3-16.

Rogerson, Richard. 2006. "Understanding Differences in Hours Worked." Review of Economic Dynamics, 9 (3): 365-409.

Rogerson, Richard. 2007. "Taxation and Market Work: Is Scandinavia an outlier?" Economic Theory, 32 (1): 59-85.

Rogerson, Richard. 2009. "Market Work, Home Work and Taxes: A Cross-Country Analysis." Review of International Economics, 17 (3): 588-601.

Rosen, Sherwin. "The Theory of Equalizing Differences." 1986. Handbook of Labor Economics, 1: 641-692.

Shimer, Robert. 2009. "Convergence in Macroeconomics: The Labor Wedge." American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics. 1 (1): 280-297.

Smith, Adam. 1776. "An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations." Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976. Edwin Cannan, Ed.

Struck, Clemens C. 2013. "Habit Persistence and the Long-Run Labor Supply." Trinity College, Dublin: unpublished manuscript.

Vissing-Jorgensen, Annette. 2002. "Limited Asset Market Participation and the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution" Journal of Political Economy, 110 (4): 825-853.

Yogo, Motohiro. 2004. "Estimating the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution When Instruments are Weak." The Review of Economics and Statistics, 86 (3): 797-810.


A  Details for the Labor-Earnings Supply Derivation

Firms maximize net job benefits given the constraints they face. In particular,

$\displaystyle B_{i}=\underset{E_{i,}A_{i}}{\max}\left\{ \lambda\omega Z_{i}E_{i}+F\left( E_{i},\psi_{i}^{E}\right) +\left( A_{i},\psi_{i}^{A}\right) -\lambda A_{i}\right\}$    .

The envelope theorem implies that when $ \lambda$ changes

$\displaystyle dB_{i}=\left( \omega Z_{i}E_{i}-A_{i}\right) d\lambda=\left( \mathcal{W} _{i}-A_{i}\right) d\lambda=W_{i}d\lambda>0 $

whenever $ W_{i}>0$. Since this is true for all jobs, the maximum $ B_{i}$ over all $ i$ must also increase.

The fact that $ dB/d\lambda>0$ highlights an interesting role for amenities. Consider a decline in the marginal value of wealth. In the absence of amenities, in $ \left( E,\bar{J}\right) $ space the job utility function would remain fixed while isocost curves became less steep and job benefits declined. Yet, once amenities are considered, a lower marginal value of wealth shifts the net job utility function shifts up in $ \left( E,\bar{J}\right) $ space. Because of the logic of the envelope theorem job benefits must still decline, but not as much as they would in the absence of amenities. Thus, endogenous provision of amenities blunts the effect of lower $ \lambda$. In other words, changes in amenities serve as endogenous buffers to income effects on labor supply.


B  The Role of Technology

B.1  Competitiveness

Across firms, differences in job-enjoyment technology can counterbalance differences in labor-augmenting technology, and vice versa. To see this, consider firms 1 and 2 as shown in Figure A1, where $ \Psi_{2}<\Psi_{1}$, $ Z_{2}>Z_{1}$, and firms differ in their net job utility curves. As depicted, although firm 1 has lower labor-augmenting technology, given its higher job-enjoyment technology it is the one that would implicitly set the economy's equilibrium level of job benefits (recall that, all else equal, higher $ \Psi_{i}$ shifts the job utility curve up). Because workers take jobs with the highest $ B$, firm 2 is unable to attract workers--and therefore must shut down.

For a higher value of $ \Psi_{2}$ (which would shift $ \bar{J}_{2}$ sufficiently high up) or a higher $ Z_{2}$ (which would make firm 2's isocost lines sufficiently steep) firm 2 could offer the exact same level of job benefits as firm 1--in which case both firms would be able to operate--or even higher job benefits--in which case firm 2 would be the one to implicitly establish economy-wide equilibrium $ B$, and firm 1 would be unable to attract workers.

Figure A1: A Difference in Job Utility Overwhelming a Difference in Labor-Augmenting Technology

Figure A1: Figure A1 consists of a single graph. The horizontal axis is labeled E for employment and the vertical axis bar{J} for job utility.  Two curved solid lines exist in the (E, bar{J}) space, $ \bar{J}_{1}$ and $ \bar{J}_{2}$.  Both lines are concave towards the origin with $ \bar{J}_{1}$ having relatively higher utility for less employment and $ \bar{J}_{2}$ with more employment for relatively less utility.
Points ${B}_{1}$ and ${B}_{2}$ exist on the vertical axis such that ${B}_{1}$ > ${B}_{2}$. Dotted lines extend from each ${B}_{1}$ and ${B}_{2}$ that are tangent to $ \bar{J}_{1}$ and $ \bar{J}_{2}$, respectively.  The line extending from ${B}_{1}$ has a slope of -λZ_1 ω and the line extending from ${B}_{2}$ has a slope of-λZ_2 ω.


B.2  Labor Earnings and the Marginal Value of Wealth

For the sake of intuition, throughout the remainder of this section we make four simplifying assumptions. 1) We revert to assuming that there is only one firm and therefore avoid $ i$ indexes. 2) For the effects of changes in the nature of work proper, $ \psi^{E}$, three possibilities emerge depending on whether $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}=0$, $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi ^{E}<0$, or $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}>0$. $ \partial F_{E}/\partial \psi^{E}=0$ means that changes in $ \psi^{E}$ do not affect how onerous extra effort is. $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}<0$ means that higher $ \psi^{E}$ makes extra effort more onerous. $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}>0$ means that higher $ \psi^{E}$ makes increases in effort less onerous. We focus on $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}\geq0$ since it is the most intuitively appealing possibility. 3) Base on another bit of intuition, we only consider cases in which $ \partial G_{A}/\partial\psi^{A}\geq0$. 4) We continue to assume the additively separable case $ J=F+G$. Relaxing these assumption leads to interesting analysis but not quite interesting enough to include here.

B.2.1  The Effect of a Rise in $ Z$ on $ \lambda$ and $ \mathbb{W}H$

Suppose labor-augmenting technology increases from $ Z$ to $ \tilde{Z}>Z$. The left panel of Figure A2 shows that, all else equal, higher $ Z$ leads to higher job benefits (meaning higher work hours) and higher effort, which leads to higher real wages because the effective wage is constant. These changes jointly imply higher $ \mathbb{W}H$. Now, consider the implications of higher $ \mathbb{W}H$. $ LE^{S}$ shifts out because at any given $ \lambda$ higher $ Z$ is consistent with higher labor earnings. This outward shift in $ LE^{S}$ implies a decrease in equilibrium $ \lambda$ and an increase in equilibrium $ \mathbb{W}H$ (the lower $ \lambda$ induces changes exactly opposite to those in the left panel of Figure 8 in the main text).

Figure A2: Effects of Increase in Labor-Augmenting Technology and Effects of Positive Innovation in the Nature of Work Proper

Figure A2: Figure A2 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix.

Left Panel - The solid line in the left panel is labeled by $ \bar{J}$ for job utility.  This line is concave about the origin. Two points, E and E^' exist on the horizontal axis, which is labeled E for employment, such that E^'  > E and there is an arrow beneath the axis pointing away from the origin, or from E to E^'.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from these two points upward to meet the solid line $ \bar{J}$. The vertical axis is labeled $ \bar{J}$.  There exists two points on the vertical axis labeled by $ \bar{J}$' and $ \bar{J}$ such that $ \bar{J}'$ > $ \bar{J}$ and there is an arrow next to the axis pointing upwards, or from $ \bar{J}$ to $ \bar{J}'$.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from $ \bar{J}'$ and $ \bar{J}$ horizontally to meet the solid line at the same points at which the dotted lines from E and E', respectively, intersect the solid line. Also on the vertical axis, there exist two points, B and B' such that B<B', or job benefits rise from B to B'.  A dashed line extends from each of these points that is tangent to the corresponding point on line $ \bar{J}$  at the points ($ \bar{J}$, E') for B' and ($ \bar{J}'$, E) for B.  The dashed line extending from B has a slope of -λZω and the line from B^' has a slope of -λZ^' ω, where ω stands for the effective wage and Z is for labor-augmenting technology.

Right Panel - The two solid lines in the right panel are labeled $ \bar{J}$ and $ \bar{J}'$ for job utility.  These lines are concave about the origin with $ \bar{J}$ closer to the origin than $ \bar{J}'$. Two points, E and E^' exist on the horizontal axis, which is labeled E for employment, such that E'  > E and there is an arrow beneath the axis pointing away from the origin, or from E to E'.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from points E and E' upward to meet the solid lines $ \bar{J}$ and $ \bar{J}$', respectively. The vertical axis is labeled $ \bar{J}$.  There exists two points on the vertical axis labeled by $ \bar{J}'$ and $ \bar{J}$ such that $ \bar{J}'$ > $ \bar{J}$ and there is an arrow next to the axis pointing upwards, or from $ \bar{J}$ to $ \bar{J}'$.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from $ \bar{J}'$ and $ \bar{J}$ horizontally to meet the solid lines at the same points at which the dotted lines from E' and E, respectively, intersect the solid lines. Also on the vertical axis, there exist two points, B and B' such that B<B', or job benefits rise from B to B'.  A dashed line extends from each of these points that is tangent to the corresponding point on lines $ \bar{J}$  and $ \bar{J}'$ at the points ($ \bar{J}$, E) for B and ($ \bar{J}'$, E') for B'.  The dashed line extending from B has a slope of -λZω and the line from B^' also has a slope of -λZω, where ω stands for the effective wage and Z is for labor-augmenting technology. The shift in the curve from $ \bar{J}$ to $ \bar{J}'$ results in the same slope of the tangent lines B and B'.

B.2.2  Effect of a Rise in $ \psi^{E}$ on $ \lambda$ and $ \mathbb{W}H$

Consider an increase in $ \psi^{E}$ to $ \tilde{\psi}^{E}>\psi^{E}$ (that is, a positive innovation in the nature of work proper). Start from the right panel of Figure A2, where $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}>0$ is assumed: all else equal, higher $ \psi^{E}$ is consistent with higher job benefits (meaning higher work hours) and higher effort (meaning--because the effective wage is an exogenous constant-- higher real wages). If $ \partial F_{E}/\partial \psi^{E}=0$ the new $ \psi^{E}$ effort remains unchanged but job benefits rise. In either case, labor earnings rise. All other changes are then analogous to those in Section B.2.1.

B.2.3  Effect of a Rise in $ \psi^{A}$ on $ \lambda$ and $ \mathbb{W}H$

If $ \partial G_{A}/\partial\psi^{A}>0$ and $ \psi^{A}$ rises (that is, a positive innovation in the nature of the work environment occurs), the optimal level of amenities rises as shown in the left panel of Figure A3. This induces an upward shift in the net job utility function akin to that shown in the right panel of Figure 8 in the main text, but without any accompanying change in the slope of isocost lines. Therefore, effort remains fixed. Because the effective wage is an exogenously determined constant, all else equal, higher amenities imply that real wages must decline. So, although job benefits are higher, the net effect on labor earnings, $ \mathbb{W}H$, is ambiguous. If instead $ \partial G_{A}/\partial\psi^{A}=0$ and $ \psi^{E}$ rises, as shown in the right panel of Figure A3 the level of amenities remains fixed, but the surplus from amenities rises. This induces an upward shift in the net job utility function, which is consistent with effort remaining fixed and job benefits rising. Because the effective wage must remain constant, real wages rise, and all other change are analogous to those in Section B.2.1.

Figure A3: Effect of Positive Innovation in the Nature of the Work Environment

Figure A3: Figure A3 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix. 
Left Panel - There exist two solid lines in the left panel.  These lines are concave away from the origin and curve downward toward the horizontal axis such that one line is completely beneath the other. There is an arrow pointing upward from one line to the line above it. Two points, A and A^' exist on the horizontal axis, which is labeled A for firm amenities, such that A^'  > A and there is an arrow beneath the axis pointing away from the origin, or from A to A^'.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from points A and A^'  upward to meet the two solid lines. The vertical axis is labeled G(A).  There exists two points on the vertical axis labeled by G' and G such that G' > G and there is an arrow next to the axis pointing upwards, or from G to G'.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from G' and G horizontally to meet the solid lines at the same points at which the dotted lines from A and A^', respectively, intersect the solid lines.  Straight, dashed lines that are tangent to these two points both have a slope of λ.

Right Panel - There exist two solid lines in the right panel.  These lines are concave away from the origin and curve downward toward the horizontal axis such that one line is completely beneath the other and the lines have identical shape. There exists an arrow pointing upward from one line to the line directly above it. A point, A_i exists on the horizontal axis, which is labeled A for firm amenities.  A dotted line extends from point〖 A〗_i  upward to intersect both of the two solid lines. The vertical axis is labeled G(A).  There exists two points on the vertical axis labeled by G' and G such that G' > G and there is an arrow next to the axis pointing upwards, or from G to G'.  Parallel, dotted lines extend from G' and G horizontally to meet the solid lines at the same points at which the dotted lines from A_i intersects the two solid lines.  Straight, dashed lines that are tangent to these two points both have a slope of λ.

B.3  Real Wages and Trendless Work Hours

B.3.1  Unaltered Slope of Net Job Utility

Consider an initial equilibrium such as point $ A$ in the left panel of Figure A4, which corresponds to an isocost line with slope $ -\lambda Z\omega$. Then, if labor-augmenting technology rises, or there is a positive innovation in the nature of work proper and $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}=0$, or there is a positive innovation in the nature of the work environment and $ \partial G_{A}/\partial\psi^{A}=0$, as shown in Section B.2 labor earnings rise and the marginal value of wealth decreases. And, at lower $ \lambda$ amenities are optimally higher, and the surplus from amenities is also higher--which is consistent with an upward shift in the net job utility function (with no change in its slope) and less steep isocost lines. If there is no change in labor hours, then the new equilibrium must be at a point such as $ A$' in the left panel of Figure A4. There, effort is lower but the effective wage $ \omega=\left( W+A\right) /\left( EZ\right) $ is unchanged.15

Figure A4: Impact of Technological Changes

Figure A4: Figure A4 consists of two graphs presented in a 1x2 matrix. 

Left Panel - Two solid lines exist in the left panel.  They are concave about the origin and extend from the vertical axis to cross the horizontal axis.  They are curved such that they resemble the upper-right quadrant of the unit circle and one line exists directly above the other such that it is further away from the origin at all points but are relatively close together.  An arrow exists pointing upward from one line to the one above it. The horizontal axis is labeled E for employment and the vertical axis is labeled J ̅ for job utility. A point B exists on the vertical axis.  Two dashed lines extend from point B that lie tangent to the two solid lines at points A and A' that exist on each of the two solid curved lines. Point A corresponds to a higher level of employment and lower level of job utility relative to point A', and exists on the solid line closer to the origin.  The slope of the dashed line passing from point B to point A has a slope of –λZω.

Right Panel - Two solid lines exist in the right panel.  They are concave about the origin and extend from the vertical axis to the horizontal axis.  One line is curved such that it resembles the upper-right quadrant of the unit circle and is relatively closer to the origin than the other solid line. An arrow exists pointing upward from this line to the one above it, which has a relatively wider curve and is further away from the inner line relative to the outer line in the left panel. The second line is strictly further away from the origin than all points on the inner line. The horizontal axis is labeled E for employment and the vertical axis is labeled J ̅ for job utility. A point B exists on the vertical axis.  Two dashed lines extend from point B that lie tangent to the two solid lines at points A and A' that exist on each of the two solid curved lines. Point A corresponds to a lower level of both employment and job utility relative to point A'.  Point A exists on the solid line closer to the origin while point A' exists on the solid line further away from the origin.  The slope of the dashed line passing from point B to point A has a slope of –λZω.

Increase in Labor-Augmenting Technology  In the case in which $ Z$ rises, because effort declines and amenities rise, the real wage can only be higher after the increase in labor-augmenting technology if the product $ EZ$ is higher and proportionally greater than the increase in amenities. In mathematical terms, because the effective wage must remain constant, then a rise in $ Z$ triggers a rise in real wages only if

$\displaystyle d\ln Z>\frac{A}{W+A}d\ln A-d\ln E$.

Increase in Labor-Augmenting Technology  In such case, because after the rise in $ Z$ real wages are higher and so is job utility, then work hours remain constant as a result of the rise in job utility countervailing the income effect's outweighing of the substitution effect. So, an increase in labor-augmenting technology can indeed be consistent with higher real wages and trendless labor hours (and higher effective labor productivity).

Positive Innovations in Job-Enjoyment Technology  If labor-augmenting technology rises, or there is a positive innovation in the nature of work proper and $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}=0$, or there is a positive innovation in the nature of the work environment and $ \partial G_{A}/\partial\psi^{A}=0$, then, again, at point $ A$' effort is lower. Because amenities are higher and the effective wage must remain constant, then given that the product $ EZ$ is lower real wages must decline. And this decline must exactly satisfy

$\displaystyle d\ln W=\frac{W+A}{W}d\ln E-A\cdot d\ln A$.

So, all else equal, neither a positive innovation in the nature of work proper with $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}=0$ nor a positive innovation in the nature of the work environment with $ \partial G_{A}/\partial\psi^{A}=0$ are consistent with both trendless work hours and higher real wages.

B.3.2  Altered Slope of Net Job Utility

Consider an initial equilibrium such as point $ A$ in t$ -\lambda Z\omega$he right panel of Figure A5, which corresponds to an isocost line with slope . Then, given a positive innovation in the nature of work proper with $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}>0$, as shown in Section B.2.2 labor earnings rise and the marginal value of real wealth decreases. And, at lower $ \lambda$ amenities are optimally higher, and the surplus from amenities is also higher--which is consistent with an upward shift in the net job utility function (with change in slope as implied by $ \partial F_{E}/\partial\psi^{E}>0$) and less steep isocost lines. If there is no change in labor hours but the income effect outweighs the substitution effect, then the new equilibrium must be at a point such as $ A$' in the left panel of Figure A4--job utility must be higher. At point $ A^{\prime}$ effort is higher but the effective wage $ \omega=\left( W+A\right) /\left( EZ\right) $ must remain unchanged. Because amenities are also higher, real wages are higher only if

$\displaystyle d\ln E>\frac{W}{W+A}d\ln A$.

So, when positive innovations in the nature of work proper make effort less taxing, a rise in $ \psi^{E}$ can indeed be consistent with higher real wages and trendless labor hours (and higher effective labor productivity).

B.3.3  Technological Equivalence

Comparison of the left and right panels of Figure A4 along with results from Sections B.3.1 and B.3.2 imply that, in principle, the impact of an increase in labor-augmenting technology can be exactly equal to the impact of a positive innovation in the nature of work proper.


Footnotes

1.  The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. The authors are thankful, without implicating, for comments received by seminar participants at the University of Michigan and also during visits to the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Brown University, the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, and McMaster University.  Return to text

2.  Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (e-mail: [email protected]).  Return to text

3.  Professor, University of Michigan, and NBER ([email protected]).  Return to text

4.  See Prescott (2004), Alesina, Glaeser, and Sacerdote (2006), Rogerson (2006, 2007, and 2009), Faggio and Nickell (2007), Ljungqvist and Sargent (2007), Ohanian, Raffo, and Rogerson (2008), Shimer (2009), Fang and McDaniel (2011), McDaniel (2011), Guner, Kaygusuz and Ventura (2012), and Epstein and Ramnath (2014) for complementary work related to cross-country differences in hours worked per population. Return to text

5.  See also, for example, Altonji (1982), Card (1994), Patterson and Pesaran (1992), Fuhrer (2000), Vissing-Jorgensen (2002), and Yogo (2002). Return to text

6.  For additional discussion, see, for instance, Shapiro and Kimball (2008). Return to text

7.  See, for instance, Abel (1990), Fuhrer (2000), Luttmer (2005), Rayo and Becker (2007), and Struck (2013). Return to text

8.  It follows that our research is broadly related to many literatures. These literatures include, but are not limited to, work by MaCurdy (1981), Altonji (1982 and 1986), Hansen (1985), Mankiw, Rotemberg and Summers (1985), Rogerson (1988), Blundell, Meghir, and Neves (1993), Mulligan (1998), Blundell and MaCurdy (1999), Blundell, Chiappori, Magnac, and Meghir (2001), Mulligan (2001), Coulibaly (2006), Krusell, Mukoyama, Rogerson, and Sahin (2008), Francis and Ramey (2009), Prescott, Rogerson, and Wallenius (2009), and Prescott and Wallenius (2011). Return to text

9.  See Epstein and Nunn (2013) for a treatment of amenities in an environment with search frictions. Return to text

10.  The relative price of amenities can simply be thought of as being part of the overall technological component $ \Psi_{i}$. Indeed, think of production of firm $ i$s $ k$th ammenity as

$\displaystyle \mathcal{A}_{i}^{k}=\theta_{i}^{k}Y_{i}^{K}$,

where $ \theta_{i}^{k}$ is technology and $ Y_{i}^{K}$ is the amount of the firm's total output, $ Y_{i}$, devoted to producing the amenity. Then, the firm's total expenditure on amenity $ k$ is $ (1/\theta_{i}^{k})\mathcal{A} _{i}^{k}=Y_{i}^{K}$ and we define $ p_{\mathcal{A}_{i}}^{k}\equiv(1/\theta _{i}^{k})$. Thus, for instance, an increase in technology $ \theta_{i}^{k}$ decreases the relative price of the $ k$th amenity. Except when the real prices of amenities are visible in markets it might be impossible to distinguish between an improvement in job-enjoyment technology and a fall in the price of an amenity. Return to text

11.  We consider this to be the more intuitive case, although our results are unaltered by assuming that job utility is always decreasing in effort. Return to text

12.  The worker's problem would be dramatically different if it were possible to devote negative work hours to unpleasant, badly paid jobs. Return to text

13.  Consider $ U+\tilde{\Phi} +H\tilde{J}_{i}$ with $ \tilde{\Phi}^{\prime}\left( T\right) =\kappa$, where $ \kappa$ is a constant. Define $ \Phi\left( X\right) =\tilde{\Phi}\left( X\right) -\kappa X$ and $ J_{i}=\tilde{J}_{i}+\kappa$. Then, $ \Phi^{\prime }\left( T\right) =0$, and

$\displaystyle \mathcal{U}$ $\displaystyle =U+\tilde{\Phi}\left( T-H\right) + {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}\tilde{J}_{i}-\kappa T$    
  $\displaystyle =U+\Phi(T-H)+ {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i}J_{i}+\kappa\underset{=0}{\underbrace{(H- {\textstyle\sum\nolimits_{i}} H_{i})}}$ .    
 Return to text

14.  See the appendix for additional details. Return to text

15.  Note that

$\displaystyle d\ln\omega+d\ln E+d\ln Z=\frac{W}{W+A}d\ln W+\frac{A}{W+A}d\ln A $
 Return to text

This version is optimized for use by screen readers. Descriptions for all mathematical expressions are provided in LaTex format. A printable pdf version is available. Return to text

Home | Economic research and data | Publications and education resources
Accessibility | Contact us
Last update: June 23, 2014