![]()
Skip to: [Printable
Version (PDF)]
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Sand in the Wheels of the Labor Market: The Effect of Firing Costs on EmploymentNOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/. Abstract: This paper examines the effects of firing costs in a dynamic general equilibrium model where firms face stochastic demand. It derives analytically two simple closed-form equations, one for the supply of labor, the other for its demand. These equations determine the comparative static effects of changes in firing costs on the labor market. When negative shocks are more likely to occur than positive shocks, and when the frequency of these shocks is high, firing costs have a substantial negative impact on aggregate employment. In addition, product market integration, as it has occurred in the formation of the European Union, induces firms to be more wary of future possible downturns and therefore intensifies the negative consequences of firing costs. Keywords: employment protection legislation, European labor markets. JEL Classifications: E24, L16, J50 *Staff economist of the Division of International Finance of the Federal Reserve Board. E-mail: Andrea.DeMichelis@frb.gov. This paper is an updated version of chapter 1 of my dissertation. I am extremely grateful to George Akerlof and Chad Jones for guidance, encouragement and patience. I received useful comments and suggestions from seminar participants at UC Berkeley, the ECB, Tilburg University, IIES (Stockholm), Warwick Univerisity, the Federal Reserve Board, Baruch College, Southern Methodist University and Florida International University. Special thanks to Andrew Figura, Johnathan Leonard and David Romer. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. Return to text 1 IntroductionEmployment in Europe has been stagnant for the last thirty years; unemployment has risen and participation in the workforce has fallen. These dramatic events have occurred against a backdrop of legislative efforts to make it more difficult for European firms to layoff workers. These high and rising firing costs are among the leading suspects as the reason for the poor performance of labor markets in several European countries.1There exists a large literature that analyzes the effects of job security regulations on the functioning of the labor market. Most available evidence indicates that firing costs have a negative impact on employment (Heckman and Pages, 2000). Yet, no consensus has emerged from the theoretical side of the debate. This disagreement is not surprising since the effect of firing costs on employment are deeply ambiguous. The first impact of job security provisions is to increase employment by discouraging layoffs when firms are hit by negative shocks. Conversely, the fear of high firing costs in the event of a future downturn acts as a hiring cost, effectively reducing the creation of new jobs when firms are hit by positive shocks. Which of the two channels dominates depends on the specification of the model and, in particular, on the nature of uncertainty. This paper will develop a tractable general equilibrium model that delivers a clear and intuitive understanding of how the labor market is affected by job security regulations. Specifically, we will spell out precise conditions under which firing costs reduce aggregate employment and will illustrate these results with simple comparative statics. We make three main assumptions. The first is that of monopolistic competition in the product market, which determines the size of the rent. The second is to represent uncertainty by letting demand for each product increase or decrease, according to a simple Markov process, in steps. The third is that of linear layoff costs, which yields partial but instantaneous adjustment. This approach allows us to derive analytically simple expressions that characterize firms' hiring and firing policies. At each level of demand, there is an upper threshold of employment above which firms are firing workers; and a lower threshold, below which firms are hiring workers. We can then solve for the steady-state probability of employment at all levels, and aggregate to derive an expression for the expected value of total labor demand. Finally, since demand for the firms' products depend upon the prices, we compute the optimal prices that the firms will charge for their goods, as well as the equilibrium wage rate that equates the supply of labor to the demand for labor. The model derives explicit expressions for the supply of and the demand for labor, and thus sheds light on the ambiguity of the effects of firing costs on aggregate employment. It shows that when the economy is ``depressed,'' these effects will be negative. Our notion of depressed economy refers to a situation in which the Markov process is such that the probability to move downward is greater than the probability to move upward, so firms are more likely to think that they will have to be firing workers than hiring them in the near future. On the other hand, firing costs will have a positive effect on employment when the economy is doing well, and firms are more likely to be hiring workers than firing them. Thus, the model yields the theory underlying the view that the poor performance of Europe's labor markets is the result of the interaction between ``bad'' labor market institutions and adverse shocks (Blanchard and Wolfers, 2000). In addition, comparative static exercises indicate that these negative effects become stronger when the economy is more ``turbulent''. Our notion of turbulence pertains to the frequency of the demand shocks. Thus, the model also provides rigorous foundation for the long-standing argument that when demand is stable and growing, the hiring policy of firms is not affected by job security provisions; while, when demand turns flat and volatile, severance payments and rules become important obstacles to employment creation (Blanchard et al., 1986, Ljungqvist and Sargent, 2002). The model provides the answer to another important question. Besides the increase in firing costs, another major change has been the creation of the European Union. This historical event, together with globalization and privatization of public companies, is changing the economic landscape from a collection of small national protected markets to a single large competitive market. We attribute to this ongoing process a general fall in the market power of existing firms. The model allows an assessment of how high firing costs interact with deregulation in the product market to determine aggregate employment. The last part of the paper is devoted to the simulation of the model using plausible parameter values. As the aim of the paper is to explain the poor performance of Europe's labor market, we need to check how well the model can reproduce the experience of most European countries. Here, we need to keep in mind that employment and unemployment are not mirror images of each other. If workers' participation decisions are influenced by job protection policies (as shown by Lazear, 1990), a reduction in employment will be associated with a decline in participation rates. Thus, the unemployment rate is not the best indication of how institutional differences affect the functioning of the labor market. Figure 1 shows, instead, the ratio between employment and working age population for selected European countries and the US since 1973.2 One fact strongly comes out: a significant downward trend in most European countries, which is even more striking if compared with the experience for the US. ![]() Our model will deliver this downward trend. High layoff costs have a sizeable negative impact on employment when the economy is depressed and turbulent. In addition, we will show that a fall in the market power of firms, while it stimulates production and employment, also causes firms to be more fearful of possible future downturns and therefore increases the prospective costs of hiring workers. In other words, product market deregulations generate better results for employment when associated with low layoff costs. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the related literature. Section 3 sets up a simple model of an economy with both product and labor market regulations. Section 4 solves for the steady-state general equilibrium, in which both employment and the wage are endogenously determined. Section 5 presents numerical simulations to examine how the various dimensions of regulation affect the functioning of the labor market. Finally, section 6 discusses possible extensions of the basic model and summarizes the conclusions. 2 Literature ReviewThe goal of this section is to motivate our contribution by discussing the existing literature on employment protection regulations. Both theoretical and applied work have been carried out on this topic. On the theoretical side, we can identify at least three different approaches to the question of whether layoff costs have a significant impact on employment. Bentolila and Bertola (1989) analyze the case of a firm that faces uncertainty in the returns to labor in a dynamic partial equilibrium model. Assuming linear and asymmetric adjustment costs, they show that dismissal costs have a negligible effect on hiring decisions and, surprisingly, slightly increase average employment. These results are quite sensitive to different assumptions about the persistence of the shocks, the magnitude of the discount rate, and the cyclicality of voluntary quits. Thus, less persistent shocks and lower discount rates cause layoff costs to have larger negative effects on employment, because both factors reduce hiring relative to firing (Bentolila and Saint-Paul, 1994). In addition, allowing for a procyclical - rather than constant - quit rate increases the fear of dismissal costs as fewer workers leave their jobs voluntarily during downturns. In De Michelis (2003), we show that layoff costs can depress labor demand when quits are procyclical. Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993) develop a general equilibrium model that incorporates the structure presented by Bertola and Bentolila. Calibrating the stochastic process driving labor productivity to match US evidence on job creation and destruction, they find that layoff costs reduce the turnover rate and the overall efficiency of the economy, and have a sizable negative impact on aggregate employment. These results (however) depend greatly on the assumption of decreasing returns to scal: higher firing costs increase firms' size, and thus result into lower productivity, lower demand and lower employment. The search and matching framework by Mortensen and Pissarides has been adapted to study how job protection provisions affect the functioning of the labor market. Blanchard (2000) and various coauthors show that costly layoffs reduce workers' flows to and from employment. This causes longer unemployment spells, while the impact on unemployment is ambiguous. Ljungqvist and Sargent (2002), on the other hand, calibrate a search model to show that the combination of high severance payments with increasing economic turbulence can generate a significant fall in the rate of employment. On the empirical side, most available evidence shows a consistent, although not always statistically significant, negative impact of job security provisions on employment. This is true not only in the Western world (Lazear, 1990, Addison and Grosso, 1996) but in Latin America as well (Heckman and Pages, 2000). In contrast, the evidence regarding the impact on unemployment is ambiguous, but we suspect that there are conceptual reasons for such findings. Specifically, Bertola (1990), Blanchard (2000), and Nickell (1997) find no effect of job security regulations on unemployment, while Lazear (1990) and Scarpetta (1996) find positive effects. Yet, it should not be a surprise that a negative impact on employment is not always mirrored in a positive effect on unemployment. Lazear (1990) shows that job security policies affect workers' participation decision: thus, a reduction in employment will cause a decline in participation rates. One point on which the literature has converged is the
formalization of the adjustment cost function. A series of studies
indicate that convexity à la Tobin's Summarizing, the assertion that job security does not have a negative impact on employment is based on indirect evidence concerning unemployment, not employment. However, this finding is not supported by a rigorous theoretical argument. The ambition of this paper is to fill this gap. We will show that high layoff costs significantly reduce employment when the economy is in a phase of depression and high volatility, but not when it is booming and uncertainty is small. This result offers an explanation for why, in the early 1970s, European labor markets began to perform poorly. In addition, we will also explain how the interaction of layoff costs and the degree of competition among firms is important to assess the impact of job security regulations on aggregate employment. It has been argued that product market constraints might significantly contribute to the poor performance of European labor markets. A recent and small literature attempts to formalize this idea in simple models3. In particular, Blanchard and Giavazzi (2001) develop a general equilibrium model to analyze how the interaction of product and labor market deregulations can give rise, in the short run, to lower real wages and higher unemployment and, in the long run, to a recovery of the labor share and a decrease of equilibrium unemployment. We follow Blanchard and Giavazzi in modeling product market regulations as determining the degree of market power of firms. But, while they identify labor market regulations with the bargaining power of workers, we focus our attention on the impact of employment protection regulations. As high firing costs are likely to strengthen the hands of workers in bargaining, leading to higher wages, one might be tempted to argue that our paper has nothing new to add. However, costly layoffs also affect labor flows - layoffs directly, hirings indirectly - and not only the bargaining strength of workers. Thus, our contribution to this literature is to explain how the interaction of product market regulations and firing restrictions affect aggregate employment in a stochastic environment. Unfortunately, there is little direct evidence on the size and importance of product market constraints. A rare exception is a paper by Goldberg and Verboven (2001) in which the authors examine the European car market from 1980 to 1993: while they document a significant price dispersion across country, their findings also suggest that price discrimination plays a minor and diminishing role. Since labor demand is derived from the behavior of firms, it seems reasonable that regulations in the product market might inhibit the redeployment of workers and hence affect firms' hiring and firing policies. Before we start spelling out the details of the model, we want to clarify what we mean by the term firing, in case the reader still had some doubt. In this paper, a fired worker is a laid off worker, not a worker fired with cause. This distinction is important because job security provisions can affect labor markets through two different channels. First, such regulations raise the costs that firms must bear in order to adjust their stock of employees. And this is what this paper is about. However, they also change the relation between employer and employee as it becomes harder to fire those workers who are not sufficiently productive. On this issue, see, among others, Kugler and Saint-Paul (2000). Anyway, for the remainder of the paper, we will use the terms ``fire,'' ``layoff'' and ``dismiss'' interchangeably to indicate a decrease in the employment level of a given firm. 3 The Model3.1 SetupDemand side. This is a discrete-time model with infinite horizon. At time 0, the representative agent's preference are given by: where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() The second term gives the effect of real money balances. Nominal
money balances, The third term gives the disutility from work; The budget constraint is:
All of the above is quite standard. Now, we introduce our first
new idea. We assume that there is a measure ![]()
Thus, the composite good The price index is also standard but for Uncertainty. Demand for each good
In section 4.2, we will show that this specification with taste shocks is perfectly equivalent to the standard assumption of productivity shocks. Thus, while our model attributes all uncertainty to shocks on the demand side, there is an alternative interpretation of the same structure in which the disturbances reflect supply shocks. Of course, the truth lies in the middle and both types of shock are important. The justification for these idiosyncratic demand/productivity shocks is a series of studies by Leonard (1987) and Davis and Haltiwanger (1992). These authors provide evidence that gross rates of job creation and destruction are remarkably large. For the US manufacturing sector, they amount to roughly 10 in a typical year. In this paper, we suggest that idiosyncratic shocks of significant size are the source for this observed heterogeneity of employment changes across firms. While these shocks occur at a micro-level, this setup provides a
simple framework to analyze the effects of macro shocks as well. If
Regulations. As we discussed in the
introduction, we (partially) follow Blanchard and Giavazzi (2001)
in their modeling product market regulation and assume that
governments can affect the elasticity of substitution.
Specifically, we assume that the government sets We make the choice to identify labor market regulations with employment protection institutions which we formalize as state-mandated costs that a firm has to pay when it lays off an employee. We think of it as a cost to the firm-worker pair, rather than a transfer from the firm to the worker. This captures the fact that, in most European countries, firms consider legal and administrative costs associated with layoffs - due to notice periods, plant closing legislation, bureaucratic procedures - to vastly exceed the monetary value of the severance payments.4 In particular, we follow the recent literature and specify
asymmetric linear adjustment costs. The firm bears a layoff cost,
where ![]() ![]() ![]() While job security regulations impose a cost to the worker-firm
pair, we assume that they are not a deadweight loss to the economy
as a whole. We think that the related legal fees and administrative
duties are eventually spent to purchase goods ![]() This is a technical assumption to simplify algebra. Since total adjustment costs also enter the budget constraint through the expression for assets (the agent owns the firms), these two terms cancel each other out. Nonetheless, note that this simplification goes against the argument that costly layoffs negatively affect aggregate employment since we are ruling out any direct effect of firing costs on total income.6 Firms and technology. There is a
continuum of firms of measure
Thus, labor productivity is always ![]() Firms are placed in a monopolistically competitive market. We make the standard assumption that firms take the behavior of other existing firms as given. The firm chooses an employment and firing policy each period to maximize the present discounted value of expected net revenues over the infinite future:
and ![]() ![]() ![]() 4 Solution of the ModelDefinition of equilibrium. A
competitive equilibrium for this economy is a collection of
quantities
� taking
� taking
�
We proceed by solving first for the partial equilibrium, in which prices are exogenous. Specifically, in section 4.1, we characterize the behavior of the representative agent, in section 4.2 the behavior of firms, and in sections 4.3 and 4.5, we aggregate the individual behavior in the steady-state. Finally, in section 4.5, we solve for the steady-state general equilibrium in which prices are endogenous and markets clear. 4.1 The representative agent's problemAs the economy is in a stationary state, the value of aggregate assets for the whole economy is not time dependent: ![]() ![]() ![]() Since there are no intertemporal links, we can characterize the
behavior of the representative agent with a relation between real
money balances and aggregate demand, a demand function for each
product and a labor supply equation (see appendix A.1 for details).
Let
In equilibrium, desired real money balances are proportional to consumption expenditures. Demand for good As in a standard monopolistically competitive model, the demand
for each type of good relative to aggregate demand is a function of
the ratio of its price to the price index, with elasticity
Finally, aggregate labor supply is given by:
where ![]() 4.2 The firm's problemWe characterize the behavior of firms using dynamic programming.
All firms solve the same problem, thus, to simplify notation, we
omit the goods' index, Let the state variable be
where
The optimization problem defined in (10) is non-standard because
the derivative of the objective function changes with the sign of
The above system is analogous to the deterministic expressions
derived by Nickell (1986). The difference between
Recall that We set the values of structural parameters and exogenous
variables to ensure that
In appendix B, we report the details of the derivation of the
hiring and firing thresholds in the steady-state equilibrium, when
the probability mass over the employment is not time dependent.
Here, we just present and discuss the results. The firing threshold
in state
for ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() The hiring threshold in state
for ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Note that we have not discussed how 4.3 The steady-state distribution of firmsIn order to derive aggregate labor demand, we have first to
determine the distribution of firms over the employment line; that
is, for example, how many firms are employing
Recall that we set the values of structural parameters and
exogenous variables to ensure that
We are now ready to derive the probability distribution of firms
along the employment line. Let
![]() The first two equations form a system of two second order linear
difference equations in
where
4.4 The partial equilibriumAs the measure of firm is where ![]() Unfortunately, the expression in (14) is not convenient to
illustrate the qualitative effects of the key parameters,
where ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Finally, note that 4.5 The general equilibriumIn partial equilibrium, each firm sets its price, In appendix C, we show that all firms at any firing thresholds
charge the same price,
Since
Since
Secondly, in general equilibrium, aggregate demand,
In order to compare partial and general equilibrium, it is again convenient to carry the same approximation as in section 4.5 which yield:
and then put side by side expressions (15) and (20). If the economy is depressed and turbulent, that is if ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Finally, equilibrium aggregate employment is given by the
intersection of equation (19) with the labor supply schedule. Using
the expression (18) to substitute in for
and, with the usual approximation, we find:
The above expression makes clear that, for a depressed and
turbulent economy, aggregate labor supply is decreasing in
The intersection of equations (19) and (21) gives the
equilibrium wage, 5 Numerical SimulationsIn this section, we examine the effects of product and market regulations on the functioning of the labor market. We run numerical simulations using the exact expressions for labor demand and supply, equations (19) and (21), and plausible parameter values. The goal is to assess the quantitative effects of firing costs and the markup rate, and to see if we can replicate, at least partially, the downward trend in the employment-population ratio depicted in Figure 1. First, we present and discuss the several assumptions we need to make about the parameter values. The first two concern the size and the probability of shocks.
The problem is that there are no estimates of Furthermore, most European countries experienced substantially
higher productivity growth and substantially lower probability of
negative demand shocks in the 1950s and 1960s than subsequently. In
other words, the slowdown in the rate of productivity growth, the
increase in real oil prices, and the increase in real interest
rates and the fiscal cuts associated with the launch of the Euro
profoundly altered the macroeconomic environment where firms
operate. For this reason, we think we characterize as ``depressed''
most of the European economies in the last thirty years. In other
words, we will simulate an economy where firms are hit more often
by negative than by positive shocks, i.e. Another important assumption must be made about the elasticity
of labor supply with respect to the real wage. Equation (9) yields
an elasticity equal to
Finally, our last key assumption pertains to the degree of
competition among firms. The literature indicates that the markup
rate varies considerably across industries (Roger, 1995).
Unfortunately, our model does not allow for firm's heterogeneity
besides the level of demand. Thus, with this caveat in mind, we set
the markup rate
The value of the other parameters are: The benchmark case
![]() For a given set of parameters, we first compute the employment and the wage when firing costs are zero. Then, we use this employment level as a measure of the population for our simulated economy, and this wage rate as a reference for the size of the firing cost. Figure 2 shows the result of the simulation exercise. On the
horizontal axes, we report the firing cost as a fraction of the
reference wage level. On the vertical axis, we report the ratio
between equilibrium employment and the measure for population. The
message is clear: high layoff costs reduce employment. Even the
magnitude of this change is consistent with Europe's experience in
the past thirty years: an increase in the layoff costs from one to
two times the reference annual wage causes a fall in the
employment-population ratio of about We also need to comment on the convex shape of the line depicted
in Figure 2. Specifically, employment becomes slightly increasing
when firing costs are extremely high. Not surprisingly, if job
security provisions are very strict, firms stop firing workers: in
our model, Higher frequency ( ![]() Ljungqvist and Sargent (2002) show how an increase in economic
turbulence - which they measure as workers' income variability - in
conjunction with high unemployment benefits and layoff costs can
contribute to persistently high unemployment. In this paper, by
contrast, we focus on the effect of job security provisions on the
labor demand side. Still, we reach a similar conclusion. An
increase in economic turbulence - here defined as the frequency of
shocks to products' demand - is associated with a more negative
impact of firing costs on employment. For example, in Figure 3, we
raise the transition probabilities (while keeping their ratio
constant), and we find that an increase in the layoff costs from
one to two times the reference annual wage now causes a fall in the
employment-population ratio of about Lower market power ( ![]() Martins et al. (1996) provide estimates of the markup rate over the period 1970-92, for 36 manufacturing industries in 14 OECD countries. Interestingly for us, they document a downward trend in all European countries they examine. Their results confirm the common belief that the ongoing product market deregulation - associated with the process of European integration - is reducing the market power of firms. In Figure 4, we reduce the markup rate from 6 ConclusionsWhile most empirical evidence links high firing costs to low levels of employment, no agreement has yet emerged about the proper way to model this effect. We have argued that a suitable model must solve five problems simultaneously. The first of these is that the modeling of firing costs involves establishing, for different firms, an upper threshold of employment. Above this threshold, firms fire workers. Second, such a model must establish a lower threshold of employment. Below this threshold, firms hire workers. Third, because the effects of firing costs involves the hires and fires that are made, demand must be represented as subject to shocks; otherwise there will be neither hires nor fires. Fourth, it is necessary to solve for the steady-state probabilities of employment at all levels, and aggregate to compute total steady-state employment. Finally, since aggregate demand depends upon the prices that firms will charge for their goods, it is necessary to solve for the optimal prices, as it is also necessary to compute the wage rate that will clear the labor market. We were able to accomplish all five of these steps using
standard modeling techniques. We assumed that uncertainty is
governed by a simple Our analytic solutions, instead, clearly show when firing costs have positive or negative effect on employment. The reasons for such effects are also clear. Job security legislation reduces aggregate employment when (i) negative shocks are more likely to occur than positive shocks, and when (ii) the frequency of shocks is high. In addition, we find that product market deregulation, with an associated fall in market power, induces firms to be more concerned about future possible downturns, intensifying the negative consequences of firing costs. 7 ReferencesAddison, J. and Grosso, J. (1996), `` Job Security Provisions and Employment: Revised Estimates,'' Industrial Relations, Vol. 35, N. 4. Akerlof, G., Rose, A. and Yellen, J. (1988), `` Job Switching and Job Satisfaction in the US Labor Market,'' Brooking Paper of Economic Activity, Vol. 2, pp. 495-582. Bentolila S. and Bertola, G. (1989), `` Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?,'' Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 57, pp. 381-402. Bentolila S. and Saint-Paul, G. (1994), `` A Model of Labour Demand with Linear Adjustment Costs,'' Labour Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 303-326. Bertola, G. (1990), `` Job Security, Employment and Wages,'' European Economic Review, Vol. 34, pp. 851-886. Blanchard, O. (1997), `` The Medium Run,'' mimeo, MIT. Blanchard, O. (2000), `` Employment Protection, Sclerosis, and the Effect of Shocks on Unemployment,'' Lecture 3, Lionel Robbins Lectures, London School of Economics. Blanchard, O., Dornbusch, R., Drèze, J., Giersch, H., Layard, R. and Monti, M. (1986), `` Employment and Growth in Europe: A Two Handed Approach,'' in Blanchard, O., Dornbusch, R. and Layard, R. (eds.), Restoring Europe's Prosperity; Macroeconomic Papers from the Centre for European Policy Studies, MIT Press, pp. 95-124. Blanchard, O. and Giavazzi, F. (2001), `` Macroeconomic Effects of Regulation and Deregulation in Goods and Labor Markets,'' NBER Working Paper, N. 8120. Blanchard, O. and Kiyotaki, N. (1987), `` Monopolist Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand,'' American Economic Review, Vol. 77, N. 4, pp. 647-666. Blanchard, O. and Wolfers, J. (2000), `` Shocks and Institutions in the Rise of European Unemployment. The Aggregate Evidence,'' Economic Journal, Vol. 110, N. 1, pp. 1-33. Burda, M. and Wyplosz, C. (1988), `` Gross Labor Market Flows in Europe: Some Stylized Facts,'' CEPR Discussion Paper, N. 439. Capdeviellle, P. and Sherwood, K. (2002), `` Providing Comparable International Labor Statistics,'' Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 6, pp. 3-14. Davis, S. and Haltiwanger, J. (1992), `` Gross Job Creation, Gross Job Destruction, and Employment Reallocation,'' Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, N. 3, pp.819-863. De Michelis, A. (2003), `` Costly Layoffs with Procyclical Quits,'' in Essays on the Macroeconomic Effects of Labor Market Rigidities, Chapter 2, Ph.D. Thesis, U.C. Berkeley, pp. 40-61. Goldberg, P. and Verboven, F. (2001), `` The Evolution of Price Dispersion in the European Car Market,'' Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 68, pp. 811-848. Grimmett, G. and Stirzaker, D. (1995), Probability and Random Processes, 2nd edition, Clarendon Press, Oxford. Kugler, A, and Saint-Paul, G. (2000), `` Hiring and Firing Costs, Adverse Selection and Long-term Unemployment,'' mimeo, Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Hart, O. (1982), `` A Model of Imperfect Competition with Keynesian Features,'' Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 97, pp. 109-138. Hamermesh, D. (1993), Labor Demand, Princeton University Press. Hamermesh, D. (1995), `` Labour Demand and the Source of Adjustment Costs,'' The Economic Journal, Vol. 105, pp. 620-634. Hamermesh, D. and Pfann, G. (1996), `` Adjustment Costs in Factor Demand,'' Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34, pp. 1264-1292. Heckman, J. and Pages, C. (2000) `` The Cost of Job Security Regulation: Evidence from Latin American Labor Markets,'' NBER Working Paper, N. 7773. Hopenhayn, H. and Rogerson, R. (1993), `` Job Turnover and Policy Evaluations: a General Equilibrium Analysis,'' Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, pp. 915-938. Lazear, E. (1990), `` Job Security Provisions and Unemployment,'' Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 102, pp. 699-726. Leonard, J. (1987), `` In the Wrong Place at the Wrong Time: the Extent of Structural and Frictional Unemployment,'' in Lang, K. and Leonard, J. (eds.), Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Markets, Basil Blackwell, pp. 141-163. Leonard, J. and Van Audenrode, M. (1993), `` Corporatism run amok: job stability and industrial policy in Belgium and the United States,'' in Lang, K. and Leonard, S. (eds.), Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Markets, Basil Blackwell, pp. 141-163. Ljungqvist, L. and Sargent, T. (2002), `` The European Employment Experience,'' mimeo, Stanford University. Martins, J., Scarpetta, S. and Pilat, D. (1996), `` Markup Ratios in Manufacturing Industries. Estimates from 14 OECD Countries,'' OECD Working Paper, N. 162. Nickell, S. J. (1986),`` Dynamic Model of Labour Demand,'' in Ashenfelter, O. and R. Layard (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 1, Elsevier Science Publishers, pp. 473-522. Nickell, S. J. (1997), `` Unemployment and Labor Market Rigidities: Europe versus North America,'' Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 1, N. 3, pp. 55-74. OECD (1999), `` Employment Protection and Labour Market Performance,'' in Employment Outlook, Chapter 2, pp.48-132. Roeger, W. (1995), `` Can Imperfect Competition Explain the Difference between Primal and Dual Productivity Measures? Estimates for US manufacturing,'' Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103, N. 2, pp. 316-330. Scarpetta, S. (1996), `` Assessing the Role of Labour Market Policies and Institutional Settings on Unemployment: A Cross Country Study,'' OECD Economic Studies, N. 26, pp. 43-98. Shapiro, C. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1984), `` Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device,'' American Economic Review, Vol. 74, N. 3., pp. 433-444. A AppendixA.1 The derivation of each individual demand functions and each individual labor supplyLet us begin with the definition of the price index,
subject to ![]() ![]() Thus, the first order condition with respect to
where ![]() ![]()
Plugging (24) and (25) into (23), we get:
which is equation (3). Recall that we solve the model for the stationary equilibrium.
Thus, consumption, money holding and labor supply is constant over
time. The Euler condition then yields that We are now ready to solve the representative agent's utility maximization problem within each period. We do this into steps. First, each worker chooses the optimal composition of consumption and money holding for a given level of income. Setup the Lagrangian: ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Since (27) holds for all goods ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]()
Let
![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() Plugging the above expression into (28) gives the demand
function for good ![]() Hence, demand of the composite good for a given level of income is:
The second and final step is to determine labor supply, given the demand functions for money and the composite good:
The first order condition with respect to ![]() B The derivation of the hiring and the firing thresholdsWe set the values of structural parameters and exogenous
variables to ensure that
Recall the Bellman equation (10) and the first order condition
(11). The main issue is to compute
Let where
![]() Using this result in equation (30), we find that the one period ahead shadow value of the current marginal employee is equal to:
We used equation (11) to substitute in 0 for
![]()
Using equations (31) and (32) to expand the first order condition, we find:
for ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() We are now ready to find the hiring and the firing thresholds.
Suppose that, in the last period, the firm ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() C The characterization of the general equilibriumWe start by finding the equilibrium prices. Recall from the first order condition of the consumer maximization problem:
where ![]() ![]() Thus,
![]() Using these results into the expression for the price index
Using the above expression and recalling that aggregate demand
is proportional to real money balances, we can express Therefore, in general equilibrium, the aggregate supply of goods
Using equation (37) to substitute in for ![]() Recall
![]() ![]() ![]() We now have all the elements to write down an expression for
aggregate labor demand in general equilibrium,
which the same as equation (19). The final step is to solve for labor supply in general equilibrium, equation (21):
D The benchmark case of no adjustment costsWhen layoff costs are equal to zero, the firm
It is easy to check that the case of zero layoff costs is yields
the same steady-state distribution of firms along the employment
line. Define with Given this, it is immediate to find an expression for
equilibrium aggregate employment without layoff costs. Let us begin
with deriving aggregate labor demand in partial equilibrium,
![]() In general equilibrium, we need to consider that all firms set
the same price
![]() Similarly, we need to adjust the labor supply equation. Thus, aggregate labor demand and aggregate labor supply without layoff costs are given by:
For the numerical simulations, it is also useful to compute
![]() Finally, aggregate labor supply in general equilibrium is given by: ![]() Summarizing, both
Footnotes1. Much of the current job security regulations were introduced between the 1950s and the 1970s. The recession following the 1973 oil shock gave an additional impetus to goverments to adopt various protective measures. Since then, the broad evolution has been towards deregulation, but at an extremly slow pace (OECD, 1999). Return to text 2. All employment figures in the paper are based on BLS data which put foreign countries on a similar basis as the US. See Capdeviellle and Sherwood (2002) for a detailed presentation of the BLS international data. In Figure 1, we normalized the employment-population ratios across country using 1973 as a base year. This is because social norms have a substantial impact on labor partecipation, especially for women and young individuals. By indexing our data with a base year, we want to direct the reader's attention to the change in the employment-population ratio that occured over time. Return to text 3. To the best of our knowledge, Leonard and Van Audenrode (1993) were the first to argue this conjecture. Return to text 4. Furthermore, the potential impact of severance payments could be undone by designing a wage contract that cancels out the effect of a transfer from firms to laid off workers. For example, as in the efficiency wage model of Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984), we could have workers post a bond of the value of the transfer which they would forfeit in case they are dismissed. Alternatively and more realistically, think of an employment package which pays rising wages over time. This is in fact equivalent to a constant wage, except that the firm keeps part of the early payments as a bond and returns it to the worker later if she is still employed. Return to text 5. The assumption of zero hiring cost does not affect the qualitative conclusions of the paper. It could be easily relaxed at the cost of longer and more cumbersome notation. Furthermore, note that as labor is homogenoeus, net and gross labor flows coincide. Return to text 6. In fact, this is the argument exploited by Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993): firing costs are equivalent to a less productive technology, and so reduce employment and welfare. Here, we want to show that firing costs can have a negative effect on employment through a different channel. Return to text 7. The value function depends on the lagged value of the demand shifter because today's adjustment costs depend on how a firm got to the current state, by firing or hiring workers. Return to text 8. Alternatively, we could think that it takes two or more consecutive positive (or negative) shocks to make the firm want to hire (layoff). However, this alternative assumption would just complicate notation without adding any new insight. Return to text 9. Recall that we have defined
10. See the Appendix D for a complete analysis of the benchmark case of zero layoff costs. Return to text 11. Irrespective of the initial
conditions, the stochastic process converges towards a steady-state
where the probability mass at any level of employment is not time
dependen. Formally, this result comes from the assumption that we
are considering a discrete time finite-state Markov chain which is
ergodic, i.e. irreducible with aperiodic, recurrent states. An
ergodic Markov chain converges to a distribution where the
probability of being in state 12. We check the accuracy of these approximation by carrying out simulations for both the exact case and for the approximate case. Return to text 13. As usual, the markup rate,
14. Note that
15. Note that in state
16. Note that in state
This version is optimized for use by screen readers. A printable pdf version is available. |