Skip to: [Printable
Version (PDF)]
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Growth-Led Exports: Is Variety the Spice of Trade?NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to International Finance Discussion Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at http://www.ssrn.com/. Abstract: Fast-growing countries tend to experience rapid export growth with little secular change in their terms of trade. This contradicts the standard Armington trade model, which predicts that fast-growing countries can experience rapid export growth only to the extent that they accept declining terms of trade. This paper generalizes the monopolistic competition trade model of Helpman and Krugman (1985), providing a basis for growth-led exports without declining terms of trade. The key mechanism behind this result is that fast-growing countries are able to develop new varieties of products that can be exported without pushing down the prices of existing products. There is strong support for the new model in long-run export growth of many countries in the post-war era. Keywords: export demand, international trade, product differentiation JEL Classification: F1, F4 I IntroductionFew people would be surprised to learn that there is a strong positive correlation between the growth rate of a country's exports and the growth rate of its economy. Indeed, there is an extensive body of theoretical and empirical research on the phenomenon of ``export-led growth,'' which focuses on the benefits for long-run economic growth of encouraging exports and openness to trade.2 Curiously, however, the standard empirical model of trade flows implies that fast-growing countries with fast-growing exports should be experiencing secular declines in their terms of trade. But there is little evidence for such behavior in the terms of trade. Figure 1 shows the positive correlation between long-run export growth and long-run economic growth in a sample of 64 countries over the period 1960-2000.3 Figure 2 shows essentially no correlation between changes in the terms of trade and long-run economic growth for these countries. Regression analysis presented in this paper demonstrates that this lack of correlation cannot be attributed to simultaneity bias and is unlikely to reflect omitted factors. To explain these empirical findings, this paper develops a new model of export demand based on the theoretical work of Helpman and Krugman (1985). The new model significantly and robustly outperforms the standard model. Unlike the standard assumption of one good per country, the alternative model allows for multiple varieties of goods to be produced in each country. In this model, economic growth allows a country to produce more varieties, and demand for a country's exports is directly tied to the number of varieties it produces. Thus, fast-growing countries can have fast-growing exports without a decline in the terms of trade. This finding carries important implications for empirical international macroeconomics. In most models of international macroeconomic linkages, permanently higher output tends to lower a country's trade balance through higher imports that are not matched by higher exports, at least not without a permanent decline in the terms of trade. For example, in the Fall 2004 Per Jacobsson Lecture, former Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers claimed that the sustained increase in U.S. economic growth since the mid-1990s was at least partly responsible for the widening of the U.S. trade deficit.4 This research questions that conclusion. The ``growth-led exports'' view of this paper is complementary to the traditional view of export-led growth. Deregulating, opening up the economy, and otherwise encouraging exports may indeed spur growth through technological transfer and more competitive producers. The model developed here helps to explain why such growth is all the more beneficial for a country's welfare because it is not offset by declining terms of trade. The evidence presented in this paper provides some support for a connection between changes in openness to foreign trade and economic growth. But even for countries with a relatively stable share of exports in GDP, faster economic growth tends to be associated with faster export growth. The next section of the paper demonstrates that there is no significant link between long-run rates of economic growth and the terms of trade; in particular, exogenous forces driving growth do not have significantly adverse implications for a country's terms of trade. Section III develops a theoretical model to explain this empirical regularity. Section IV estimates the model and explores the robustness of the key parameters. Section V is a brief conclusion. II Terms of Trade and Economic GrowthFigures 1 and 2 display a strong link between export growth and economic growth in the long run and essentially no link between changes in the terms of trade and long-run economic growth. The latter finding is not consistent with the standard Armington (1969) model of export supply and demand under the assumption that economic growth is exogenous with respect to the terms of trade. As shown in Figure 3, faster economic growth shifts out the export supply curve and the economy moves down the export demand curve from point A to a new lower price of exports at point B.5With exogenous economic growth, export demand shocks may add noise to the empirical relationship, but they should not bias the coefficient in a regression of the terms of trade on economic growth. However, if long-run economic growth is not exogenous with respect to the terms of trade, then the (negative) coefficient is biased upward because positive demand shocks will tend to raise both the terms of trade and economic growth. This is conventional simultaneity bias. It may be plausible to maintain that a country's long-run economic growth is determined by factors that are exogenous to the terms of trade, such as population growth and institutional characteristics that encourage or discourage the accumulation of human and physical capital. Nevertheless, the finding of no long-run correlation between changes in the terms of trade and economic growth is robust to the use of instrumental variables to isolate factors behind economic growth that clearly are exogenous with respect to changes in a country's terms of trade. Table 1 presents cross-country instrumental-variables regressions of long-run changes in the terms of trade on long-run economic growth rates and other variables. (Data are described in the Data Appendix.) Following a recent paper by Acemoglu and Ventura (2002), long-run economic growth is instrumented by the levels of three variables that are observed at the beginning of the sample: real per capita income adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP), the average years of schooling of the labor force, and the average life expectancy. All of these instruments are predetermined and thus exogenous with respect to subsequent changes in the terms of trade. Because the focus here is on total economic growth rather than per capita growth (as in Acemoglu and Ventura) population growth is added as a fourth instrument, under the assumption that population growth is exogenous to the terms of trade. However, the results are not sensitive to dropping the population growth rate. Acemoglu and Ventura argue that the human capital variables (years of schooling and life expectancy) may have independent effects on the terms of trade, so they are included in the second-stage regression here, though the results are not sensitive to excluding them. The regressions also include a dummy variable for countries that produced more than twice as much oil as they consumed in 1985.6 From the point of view of many oil exporting countries, changes in the price of oil represent major exogenous shocks to the terms of trade that may have had lasting effects on economic growth. Column (1) of Table 1 presents results of a regression of the change in the terms of trade between 1960 and 2000 on the growth of real GDP over the same period and on the oil exporter dummy. Neither coefficient is significant and the equation R is very low, despite a respectable fit of the first-stage regression. Column (2) adds the human capital variables, which are statistically significant, though it is difficult to understand why schooling should have a negative effect on the terms of trade and life expectancy should have a positive effect. Columns (3) and (4) break the sample into two 20-year sub-periods. The human capital variables are not significant in either sub-period. However, the oil dummy is significantly positive in the first sub-period, when oil prices were rising, and negative in the second period, when oil prices were falling in real terms. In neither sub-period is there a significant coefficient on GDP growth. Column (5) replaces total GDP growth with per capita GDP growth and drops population growth from the instruments. This is the specification in Acemoglu and Ventura.7 Here the results are almost identical to those for total GDP growth in column (2). Column (6) focuses on countries whose exports are primarily composed of manufactured goods and services, in order to minimize the effect of volatile commodity prices on the regression.8 Column (7) restricts the sample to industrial countries, for which the data quality is generally highest. In neither column (6) nor column (7) is there a significant coefficient on GDP growth. Altogether, the results shown in Table 1 are consistent with little or no effect of long-run economic growth on a country's terms of trade. III Theoretical ModelThis section derives a two-country model of export demand and supply based on tastes, technology, and labor in a setting with endogenous varieties of goods.9 Under plausible assumptions, the number of varieties grows in proportion to a country's total output.10 A key contribution of this paper is to show that allowing for endogenous varieties leads to an export demand equation that can be approximated by augmenting the standard Armington demand equation with a term for the relative size of the exporting country in the world economy.11 In this model, as shown in Figure 4, long-run economic growth in output shifts both the export supply and export demand curves out simultaneously, moving from point A to point C with minimal effect on the price of exports. DemandThe demand side of the model is taken from Helpman and Krugman (1985) who, in turn, based their work on the ``love of variety'' utility function proposed by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977).12 The utility of the representative household is displayed in equation (1). The budget constraint is equation (2). Here D represents domestic consumption of domestically produced goods and X* represents imports (exports from the rest of the world). Asterisks denote foreign variables. The subscripts denote individual varieties. There are N domestic varieties and N* varieties of imports. Prices of domestic goods are denoted by P. Import prices (in foreign currency) are denoted by P* and the exchange rate is R. Total expenditure is E. ``A'' is an exogenous variable that reflects taste for imports. Consumers are biased towards domestic goods if A is less than unity. The elasticity of substitution, , is assumed to be equal across all goods in order to obtain a closed-form solution for demand.
The representative household chooses consumption of each variety to maximize (1) subject to (2) and taking prices, available varieties, and total expenditure as given.13 All domestic firms face the same production technology, which leads to equal prices of all domestic varieties, P, and thus equal quantities sold, D. Similarly, all foreign varieties sell at the common price P* with equal quantities X*. Aggregate demand for each type of good equals the number of varieties times the quantity demanded of each variety. The resulting aggregate demand system is given by equations (3)-(4). As discussed in Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), the share of spending on domestic goods equals 1/(1+A) and the share spent on foreign goods is A/(1+A). Solving the analogous system for the rest of the world, yields equations (5)-(6).14
Expenditure equals revenue from domestic production plus an exogenous transfer, T, from the rest of the world: equation (7). Foreign expenditure equals foreign production minus the transfer converted into foreign currency: equation (8). The transfer allows for unbalanced trade. T is assumed to be driven by macroeconomic factors such as fiscal and monetary policy that affect national saving and investment.
Now turn to the firms' decisions and aggregate supply. There are
a potentially unlimited number of varieties within each class of
good, but a firm must pay a fixed cost for each new variety as well
as a marginal cost for each unit of output. All costs and prices
are expressed in terms of units of labor. Equations (9) and (10)
are the total cost functions for each variety of domestic and
foreign good, respectively.15 Note
that each variety is both consumed at home (D) and exported (X). F
is the fixed cost and G is the marginal cost. Technological
progress tends to lower costs, and can thus be modeled as an
exogenous decline in F and G.
The profit-maximizing prices depend on the elasticity of
substitution and the marginal cost, as shown in equations
(11)-(14).16 These
are standard markup equations. (12)
(13)
(14)
Total production in each country exhausts the available
pool of labor, shown in equations (15)-(16), thereby determining
the number of varieties of goods produced. Aggregate labor supply,
L, is exogenous in each region. Free entry ensures that firm
profits are zero, driving revenue equal to cost for each variety:
equations (17)-(18). By Walras' Law, one of the last two equations
or one of the two expenditure equations can be dropped.
This sub-section derives an estimable version of equation (6)
for aggregate exports. The first step is to substitute the
(unobserved) number of varieties produced by a country with the
country's (observed) total output. Total output is defined as the
number of varieties produced times the quantity of each variety,
shown in equation (19). Inserting equations (11) and (12) into (17)
yields equation (20) for domestic output of each variety.
Substituting (20) into (19) and rearranging terms shows that the
number of varieties is a function of total output and the ratio of
marginal to fixed cost, equation (21).
The second step is to define the foreign expenditure price
as the weighted average of foreign and domestic prices, shown in
equation (22). Inserting (21) into (6), dividing the numerator and
denominator by P*,
and making use of (22) yields equation (23), where
Z=G/[(-1)F] for notational
simplicity. (22)
(23)
To obtain a linear equation in growth rates, take the
logarithm of equation (23) and totally differentiate. An appendix
(available upon request) shows that the change in log exports can
be expressed in terms of the log changes in other variables as
shown in equation (24). The simple form of equation (24) derives
from the assumed initial conditions that technology is the same
across the two countries (F=F* and G=G*) and there is no home bias
(A*=1). Equation (24) can be viewed as a linear approximation to
the demand function in a neighborhood around these initial
conditions. For identification, it is necessary that the unobservable
disturbances (the last two terms) are not correlated with the
regressors (the first three terms). Within the system developed
here, taste shocks (log A*) are
not correlated with prices, output, or expenditures.17 The underlying technology variables
(F, G, F*, G*) are correlated with prices, output, and expenditure.
However, they enter the demand equation directly only through a
function of their ratio (Z=G/[(-1)F]). Thus, identification requires only the
plausible assumption that technological progress lowers both fixed
and marginal costs proportionally. Under this assumption,
log Z=
log Z*=0, and
the fifth term of equation (24) drops out. This section presents estimates of the coefficients of equation
(24) using data on long-run growth rates of exports.18 A critical test of the growth-led
exports model is that the coefficient on the change in the ratio of
exporter GDP to world GDP should be significantly greater than zero
and not significantly different from unity. The equation is estimated across countries using one long-run
growth rate for each country. Using long-run growth rates
eliminates the need to model short-run adjustment dynamics. In
addition, the relationship between output and the number of
varieties is likely to be strongest over long time-horizons, as the
number of varieties may not move in proportion with output over the
business cycle. Table 2 presents estimates of equation (24) with
heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors (Huber/White).19 The first three columns of Table 2
display ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions. Column (1) is
based on growth rates over the period from 1960 through
2000.20 Columns
(2) and (3) are based on growth rates over the first half and
second half, respectively, of these 40 years. In all three samples,
the ratio of exporter GDP to world GDP is highly significant in
explaining export growth, lending support to the importance of
product varieties and growth-led exports. Column (4) shows that
these results are not sensitive to outliers in the data, as
estimates from minimum absolute deviation (MAD) regressions are
very close to the OLS results. Similar results (not shown) obtain
for the sub-sample periods. The coefficient on the relative export price is the negative of
the substitution elasticity ().
The estimate of this coefficient has the
correct sign but is rather close to zero in these regressions,
suggesting the possibility of simultaneity bias. Simultaneity bias
could also be present if exporter GDP growth responds positively to
shocks in the growth rate of exports in the long run. Columns (5)
and (6) explore these issues. Column (5) presents results of an
instrumental-variables regression in which the ratio of the
domestic to the foreign GDP deflator is used as an instrument for
the relative export price and the instruments of Table 1 (except
the oil dummy) are used for the ratio of exporter GDP to world GDP.
The first-stage fit is acceptable, but the instruments do not
improve the estimated elasticity of substitution. Indeed, the
estimated substitution elasticity now has the wrong sign;
nevertheless, the coefficient on the ratio of exporter GDP is
little changed.21 Column
(6) presents instrumental variables results under the restriction
that the coefficient on relative export prices is -2, representing
a much larger substitution elasticity than is typically found in
aggregate-level implementations of the Armington model.22 This restriction has only a small
effect on the parameter of interest-the coefficient on growth of
the ratio of exporter GDP to world GDP remains highly significant
and close to unity. Column (7) displays estimates over a sub-sample of countries for
which manufactured goods and services comprised more than 50
percent of exports in 2000.23 This
sample selection was made because the Helpman-Krugman model was
designed for differentiated manufactures and services, and thus it
may not be appropriate for trade in undifferentiated primary
commodities. Small countries that specialize in the export of a
particular primary commodity may experience growth in both GDP and
exports with little change in relative prices if their production
of the commodity is small relative to world consumption. This
phenomenon would lead to a positive coefficient on the exporter GDP
ratio for reasons other than those embodied in the Helpman-Krugman
model. Table A1 indicates which countries in the dataset do not
specialize in primary commodity exports. For the most part, these
are the traditional industrialized countries, especially when one
excludes countries for which data are not available in 1960. Thus,
another benefit of this reduced sample is to focus on countries
with relatively high-quality data that account for most of world
trade in manufactures and services. As seen in column (7) of Table
2, the coefficient on the ratio of exporter to world GDP remains
highly significant in this smaller sample.24 Columns (8) and (9) explore the interaction between export-led
growth and growth-led exports. The sample of column (1) is split
into two equal-sized groups: those for which the share of exports
in GDP moved closely in line with the sample median between 1960
and 2000-column (8)-and those for which the share of exports in GDP
rose either more or less quickly than the median-column
(9).25 If
export-led growth were entirely responsible for the results of this
paper, one would expect that the coefficient on the ratio of
exporter GDP to world GDP would be strongly affected by this sample
split, as nearly all the identifying information would be in the
sample of column (9)-these are the countries for which exports grew
especially strongly or weakly. Indeed, the coefficient on the ratio
of exporter GDP is larger in column (9) than in column (8), but the
difference is not significant and the coefficient in column (8)
remains highly statistically significant. Thus, it appears that
economic growth spurs exports even in countries that are not
aggressively pursuing a strategy of export-led growth.26 In all columns of Table 2, the estimated effect of growth in the
ratio of exporter to world output is highly statistically
significant and generally not significantly different from its
predicted value of unity. These results provide strong support for
the role of product varieties in trade and for growth-led
exports. This paper shows how the Helpman-Krugman (1985) trade model can
be implemented empirically by augmenting the standard Armington
export demand equation with a term for the ratio of the exporting
country's output relative to world output. The augmented equation
is estimated using cross-country data on average export growth
rates between 1960 and 2000 for up to 89 countries. The effect of
the exporter output ratio is highly significant and robust to
alternative samples and specifications. These results imply that fast-growing countries need not
experience growing trade deficits or secular declines in their
terms of trade, as is implied by the Armington model. This finding
has important implications for international macroeconomic
analysis, including analysis of the effects of productivity shocks,
as most empirical macroeconomic models utilize Armington trade
equations. These results also support public policies that pursue
export-led growth by allaying concerns about immiserizing effects
on a country's terms of trade. (.207) (.170) (.238) (.205) (.168) (.169) (.231) (.001) (.002) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.001) (.011) (.017) (.018) (.012) (.014) (.030) (.005) (.006) (.013) (.008) (.005) ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent levels, respectively. First stage regression for real GDP growth includes initial years of schooling, initial life expectancy, oil exporter dummy, initial per capita PPP GDP, and population growth. Real GDP growth replaced by real per capita GDP growth. Population growth dropped from first stage regression.
Sample includes countries for which manufactured goods and services comprised more than 50 percent of exports in 2000. PY/RPY
(.21) (.29) (.19) (.34) (.67) (n.a.) (.61) (.39) (.24) (.08) (.11) (.20) (.18) (.18) (.12) (.13) (.13) (.11) (.26) (.28) (.21) (.36) (.52) (.40) (.25) (.38) (.33) Minimum
absolute deviation regression. Foreign expenditure term replaced by
a constant equal to average growth of foreign expenditure over the
sample. Instruments are the
same as in Table 1 (except oil dummy) plus the ratio of exporter to
foreign GDP deflator. First-stage R = .34 for the relative price of exports and .48
for the ratio of exporter GDP to world GDP. Coefficient on
relative prices constrained to equal -2. Instruments are the same
as in Table 1 (except oil dummy), with first-stage R = .44. Sample includes
countries for which manufactured goods and services comprised more
than 50 percent of exports in 2000. Sample includes
countries for which the change in the share of exports in GDP lies
between the 25 and
75 percentile of all
available countries. Sample includes
countries for which the change in the share of exports in GDP is
either less than the 25 percentile or greater than the 75 percentile. Acemoglu, Daron, and Jaume Ventura (2002) ``The World Income
Distribution,'' The Quarterly Journal of
Economics 117, 659-694. Anderson, James E., and Eric van Wincoop (2003) ``Gravity with
Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle,'' American Economic Review 93, 170-92. Armington, Paul S. (1969) ``A Theory of Demand for Products
Distinguished by Place of Production,'' IMF
Staff Papers 16, 159-76. Barro, Robert, and Jong-Wha Lee (1993) ``International
Comparisons of Educational Attainment,'' Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 363-394. Dixit, Avinash, and Joseph Stiglitz (1977) ``Monopolistic
Competition and Optimum Product Diversity,'' American Economic Review 67, 297-308. Gagnon, Joseph E. (2003) ``Productive Capacity, Product
Varieties, and the Elasticities Approach to Trade,'' International
Finance Discussion Papers No. 781, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. Goldstein, Morris, and Mohsin Khan (1985) ``Income and Price
Elasticities in Trade,'' in Jones and Kenen (eds.) Handbook of International Economics, Volume II,
North-Holland, Amsterdam. Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman (1991) Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, The
MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Helpman, Elhanan, and Paul R. Krugman (1985) Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns,
Imperfect Competition, and the International Economy, The
MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Krugman, Paul (1989) ``Differences in Income Elasticities and
Trends in Real Exchange Rates,'' European
Economic Review 33, 1055-85. Marquez, Jaime (2002) Estimating Trade
Elasticities, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston. McKinnon, Ronald (1964) ``Foreign Exchange Constraint in
Economic Development and Efficient Aid Allocation,'' Economic Journal 74, 388-409. Pereira, Alfredo, and Zhenhui Xu (2000) ``Export Growth and
Domestic Performance,'' Review of
International Economics 8, 60-73. Senhadji, Abdelhak, and Claudio Montenegro (1999) ``Time Series
Analysis of Export Demand Equations: A Cross-Country Analysis,''
IMF Staff Papers 46, 259-73. Most of the data are obtained from the World Bank's World Development Indicators 2004 database. Initial
per capita PPP GDP and population are obtained from the Penn World
Tables version 6.1.27 Initial
human capital data are obtained from the Barro-Lee dataset.28 Terms of trade is defined as the ratio
of the export deflator for goods and services to the corresponding
import deflator. In Table 2, foreign data for each exporter are
calculated as world minus exporter data. Data definitions for
equation (24) are as follows:29 NX: Real exports of goods and services P: Export deflator E: Nominal gross national expenditures P: Expenditures deflator Y: Real gross output (GDP) P: GDP deflator Country coverage is described in the following table.
Countries for which
manufactured goods and services comprised more than 50 percent of
exports in 2000. Source: World Development
Indicators 2004. IMF definition. Take the logarithm of equation (23) and totally differentiate.
Make the following notational simplifications: P/R=PX, P*=PE*, P*=PD*. (1) (2) (3) dlog(NX) = -
dlog(PX/PE*) + dlog(E*/PE*) + dlog[Y/(Y+Y*)] (4) (5) (6) + (-1) dlog(A*) +
dlog[(Y+Y*)/Y*] + dlog(Z/Z*) (7) (8) + (1-dlog(PE*/PD*) - dlog{1 + Z Y [PX/(PD* A*)]/(Z* Y*)} Terms (1)-(3) above are the same as in equation (24) except that
``d'' is replaced by ``
''. Making use
of dlog(X)=dX/X, term (8) can be written: Term 8 -{Z Y (1-) PX [PD*
A* dpX - PX (PD* dA* + A* dPD*)]/[Z* Y* (PD* A*)] + [Z* Y*
(Y dZ + Z dY) - Z Y (Y* dZ* + Z* dY*)] /(Z* Y*)}/{1 + Z Y
[PX/(PD* A*)]/(Z*
Y*)} Use of initial conditions - A*=1, PX=PD*, Z=Z* - allows
simplification to -{Y (1-) (dPX -
PD* dA* - dPD*)/(Y* PD*) + [Y* Y (dZ - dZ*) + Z(Y* dY - Y dY*)]/(Z Y*}/(1 + Y/Y*) dividing both numerator and denominator by (1+Y/Y*) [Y/(Y*+Y)](1-)dA* - [Y/(Y*+Y)](1-)(dPX
- dPD*)/PD* - [Y/(Y*+Y)](dZ - dZ*)/Z - (Y* dY - Y dY*)/[(Y*+Y)Y*] Term 4 (-1)dA*/A* (A*=1) Combine with first term of simplified term 8 to yield (-1)[Y*/(Y+Y*)]dA*/A*
which is the fourth term in equation (24). Term 5 [Y*/(Y+Y*)][Y*(dY+dY*)-(Y+Y*)dY*]/Y* = [Y*/(Y+Y*)][Y* dY - Y dY*]/Y* = [Y* dY - Y dY*]/[(Y+Y*)Y*] which cancels out the fourth term of simplified term 8. Term 6 (Z*/Z)(Z* dZ - Z dZ*)/Z* (Z=Z*) = (dZ - dZ*)/Z Combine with third term of simplified term 8 to yield [Y*/(Y+Y*)](dZ - dZ*)/Z which is the fifth term in equation
(24). Term 7 Use the definition of PE* in equation (22), defining w = PD* D*/E* and (1-w) = PX X/E*. (1-) dlog{[w PD* +
(1-w) PX]/PD*} = (1-)[PD*(w
dPD* + PD* dW + dPX - w dPX - PX dW) - w PD* dPD* - PX dPD* + w PX dPD*]/PD* Substituting the initial condition: PX = PD*. (1-)(dPX - w dPX - dPD*
+ w dPD*)/PD* = (1-)(1-w)(dPX
- dPD*)/PD* Under the initial condition of no home bias (A*=1) the share of
imports in expenditures (1-w) equals exporter's share of world
output [Y/(Y+Y*)]. (1-)[Y/(Y+Y*)](dPX -
dPD*)/PD* which cancels out the second term of simplified term 8. 1. Assistant Director, Division of
International Finance, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System. (Mail Stop 19, 2000 C Street NW, Washington, DC 20551;
email: [email protected]) I would like to thank Jane
Haltmaier, Jaime Marquez, Andrew Rose, and Robert Vigfusson for
helpful comments. The views expressed here are my own and should
not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person
associated with the Federal Reserve System. Return to text 2. This research dates back at least
to McKinnon (1964). For subsequent work, see Pereira and Xu (2000)
and the references cited therein. Return
to text 3. Data sources and country coverage
are documented in the Data Appendix. Return to text 4. http://www.perjacobsson.org/lectures.htm.
Return to text 5. An alternative model consistent
with the lack of long-run correlation between export growth and the
terms of trade is that of a small open economy whose exports are
perfectly substitutable for foreign products. However, an extensive
literature shows that for most countries, exports are far from
perfect substitutes with foreign products. See, for example,
Goldstein and Khan (1985) and Marquez (2002). Return to text 6. This dummy variable includes all
OPEC members plus Cameroon, Rep. Congo, Egypt, Gabon, Malaysia,
Norway, Trinidad and Tobago, and Tunisia. Using an OPEC-only dummy,
as in Acemoglu and Ventura, does not affect the results. Source:
Energy Information Administration, International Energy Annual 2002. Return to text 7. Acemoglu and Ventura focus on the
effect of growth through capital accumulation on the terms of
trade. Their model allows for growth in population and technology
to increase exports without affecting the terms of trade, through a
mechanism similar to that described in the next section. They find
a negative and statistically significant effect of per capita
growth on the terms of trade using these instruments, which are
meant to proxy for the component of growth attributable to capital
accumulation. Their results do not carry through to the latest
vintage of World Bank data used here, even when the sample is
restricted to their 1965-85 period. This may reflect the broader
definition of the terms of trade-Acemoglu and Ventura use goods
trade only-as well as somewhat different country coverage and
possible revisions to the data. Within the original dataset used by
Acemoglu and Ventura (from Barro and Lee (1993)) the results are
sensitive to the selection of countries in the sample and the use
of total versus per capita GDP. Return to
text 8. The criterion was a share of
manufactured goods and services in total exports of more than 50
percent. Similar results obtain with a cutoff of 75
percent. Return to text 9. For simplicity there is no
capital stock. But labor can be interpreted as representing all
factors of production. Return to
text 10. Varieties refers both to
different types of goods-such as televisions, cars, and
toothpaste-and to different brands and models of the same type of
goods. Return to text 11. For a review of the theoretical
and empirical literature on the Armington export demand equation,
see Gagnon (2003). The well-known gravity model of trade is a
reduced form based on an Armington demand equation applied to
bilateral trade. See, for example, Anderson and van Wincoop (2003).
Time-series implementations of the gravity model share the property
of the Armington equation that increases in export supply drive
down the terms of trade. Return to
text 12. Grossman and Helpman (1991)
employ a similar demand system with a richer supply
side. Return to text 13. A well-known property of the
Dixit-Stiglitz utility function is that the household purchases a
positive amount of every variety available. Thus, it is best
considered a representative household rather than an individual
household. Return to text 14. Note that the elasticity of
substitution is assumed equal across countries. This assumption
aids in the derivation of a linear demand equation for estimation
and it is also implicit in the cross-country empirical work of the
next section. Return to text 15. Krugman (1989) employs a similar
cost function and obtains the same pricing equation. Return to text 16. These equations imply that
export prices equal domestic prices. Dropping the assumption of
equal elasticity of substitution across countries would allow for
differences between export and domestic prices. Return to text 17. The empirical section below
checks for robustness to the possibility that taste shocks may
affect export prices or output. Return to
text 18. Gagnon (2003) estimates a
related equation using bilateral U.S. imports of manufactures.
Gagnon (2003) also reviews other empirical tests of the effect of
product varieties on trade, most of which focus on direct measures
of product variety. Return to
text 19. Note that there is no intercept
term in the regressions, consistent with the specification of
equation (24) in growth rates. Moreover, the data do not permit the
addition of an intercept term, as growth of foreign expenditure is
nearly identical for all exporters, creating severe collinearity
between this term and an intercept. Dropping the intercept
introduces a bias in the coefficient on foreign expenditures coming
from taste shocks that are common to all exporters. From the point
of view of an exporting country, foreign taste shocks include
changes in trade barriers and transportation costs. To the extent
that trade barriers and transportation costs have fallen for all
exporters, the coefficient on foreign expenditure is biased upward.
The remaining coefficients are not affected by this
bias. Return to text 20. There are only 53 countries in
this regression (compared to 64 in Figures 1 and 2) because nine
countries lacked one or more of the needed series in dollar
terms. Return to text 21. An alternative instrument, the
trade balance, was associated with extremely poor first-stage fit
and yielded similar results for the coefficient on the ratio of
exporter GDP. Return to text 22. Senhadji and Montenegro (1999)
report a median price elasticity of export demand of -0.78 across
53 countries. See, also, Marquez (2002). Return to text 23. Similar results were obtained
using a criterion of 75 percent of exports. Return to text 24. Similar results obtain for the
industrial countries and over the two subsamples. Return to text 25. As described in Table 2, the
cutoff points for this sample split are the 25 and 75 percentiles of growth in export
shares. Return to text 26. An alternative sample split
based on countries with export shares growing either faster or
slower than the median yielded a higher coefficient on the
sub-sample with fast-growing exports, but the coefficient on the
slow-export-growth sub-sample remained positive and highly
significant. Return to text 27. Alan Heston, Robert Summers and
Bettina Aten, Penn World Table Version 6.1, Center for
International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania
(CICUP), October 2002. Return to
text 28. See Barro and Lee (1993). A link
to their dataset is at http://www.nber.org/data/. Return to text 29. All countries with available
data were used in the regressions except for Bulgaria, which had
strongly negative export growth in the second sub-sample that is
related to its transition from a socialist to a market economy. No
transition economy has data over the 40-year sample. Bulgaria,
China, and Hungary have data over the 1980-2000 sub-sample
period. Return to text This version is optimized for use by screen readers.
A printable pdf version is available. |